'71-" {‘74 “‘4“. "4 i? { )‘f p3,.,":’: Fir‘ l 1 . p J I l 9qu. I ' \dem I. n - may, .. sq.- v“.\-~ «'- ' m .. ' :55“ fr" ‘~‘*»T1»’.=m":‘f:-~7"‘ -". ‘5 ‘7 «’41.» 71%;}; “*3 - gr. 3:3; . W“ ‘ ‘ ~f§~ t M27. 5‘ '- 1.- " \ . o 1 . u'wy, K" ‘:‘ -.~-.r'.- , Ia " n ‘IIU‘W- . 1 Ya”. I -\ I I "1.: ‘fquw’fy A "f .I 3 .g 55.: o :1“, ; MN . ‘ ' ' ' . 1: ¢~ . . . thfi ( .jl‘ l‘ v' ‘ a ‘ ' 9’15‘ "1-334 “fifs. xx E. 13.5; - U . _.W§s ‘1‘ , "Q '. ‘ ‘ V ‘ .rv . -I ‘ u . . '1 ’ "r ,‘ ‘ 7ft .‘ kj‘§(fi{nw:}h‘n 5". g". "x. 2”. : .‘w L'. W. a \.'0 , Ull<0 , Uzz<0. ’Ci , 02 = Consumption in the first and second periods. 45 The models developed in this section consist of _twgJ utility:maximizing individuals with different degrees of intertemporal preference. Having two agents allows us to simulate a condition of general equilibrium. In the more limited first model, each agent will only choose the optimal level of savings and consumption. In the second model, we have added the option of direct investment in a productive process. ‘Now each household must allocate his endowment . 1mg among consumption, savings and direct investment. In both models, we try to find out how these allocations change as the rate of interest is reduced to zero. 1-A- W1 W1!- In this model, we ggnsider_two persons who can trade present and future goods with each other. First, in a regular capital market, the interest rate will be endogenously determined to clear the loan market. Each person maximizes his lifetime utility of consumption subject to his endowment constraint: Person A Max U(CIA,CZA) S.T. C1A + CzA/(1+r) = 010A + CzOA/(1+r) 46 Person B Max U(CiB,C29) S.T. C1B + CzB/(1+r) = C103 + CzOB/(1+r) Ci°A,C2°A Person A’s endowment in each period. 0103,0203 = Person B’s endowment in each period. r Rate of interest. The first order conditions are: UzA/UlA 1/(1+r) UzB/UiB = 1/(1+r) The loan market equilibrium is shown by: (CiA - 0104): -(C13 - C103). ‘ These three equations along with the budget constraint will solve for r,ClA,CzA,CiB andCzB . The solution is pareto optimal because the tangency conditions are satisfied. Under the Islamic restriction, individuals cannot earn ——____, any interest when lending money to each other. We assume that at zero interest rate the supply of loans will be restricted to whatever the lenders are willing to save at that rate. To find the solution, we will first find the optimal allocation for each person at zero rate of interest. If both were found to be net savers, no loans are traded and 47 their optimal allocations will be ~the market allocation under zero interest. If one is a saver and the other one is a net borrower, the market solution will be the same for the saver. For the borrower, the maximization is repeated subject to the quantity constraint on the amount that he can borrow. He can at most borrow what the other person is saving In the first stage we will have: Max UA(CIA , CzA) Max(U3(Cla , C23) S.T. CiA+CzA = Ci°A+Cz°A S.T. 013+023 = C1°3+CzoB If, for example, it was found that person A is a net lender: 010A-01A = ZA>0, then we must repeat the maximization for person B subject to a quantity constraint. Max UB(Ci*B , can) S.T. 01*3 + 02*3 = 0103 + C20B 01°3+ZA-Ci*B 2 0 (01*3,Cz*3) will be different from (013,023) if the inequality constraint is binding. The final allocations are ,/ // 48 CiA,CZA,C1*B,Cz*B. The equilibrium under perfect markets is demonstrated in Fig. 6. The equilibrium interest line is R1Rz. The: optimal allocation point is E. H represents the initial positions of persons A and B. The solution under no interest charge is shown in Fig. 7 by point F. _sisz is the zero interest line. Comparing the welfare of person A at E /and F, we see that as a net lender he is clearly worse off ::// under the Islamic regime. Person B could be worse off or better off depending on the amount that he can borrow. In Fig. 7, he is shown to be worse off: 023(013 . ’Again, _we cannot make a general statement on how the net savings changes. 9\ ¢ a s 6.A a. Figure 7 Figure 6 cfi_-_____-___ ————-c1 ‘49 l-B. - ' v t. In this part, we add production opportunities to the two-person model presented in l-A. Each person now has two options: to lend or to invest according to a concave nondecreasing production function. The production functions are 3 TA(K14,KzA)=0 T3(K13,K23)=0 K1<0 is the input and Kz>0 is the output. Fig. 8-A demonstrates how an agent allocates his resources between savings and investment. The production possiblities are shown by the concave curve 01°. 010 is his initial endowment. To maximize his utility, he will invest K1=-01°.X1 and save X’Y’. Then he will be able to consume 02 in the second period. C1 Figure 8-A 50 In our two-person model the equilibrium conditions are derived from each person’s maximization subject to the production and budget constraints. In a regular capital market with free movement of the interest rate, we will have: Max UA(CIA,CZA) S.T. C14+Czh/(l+r) 010A+th/(1+r)+K1A , TA(K14,K2A)=O Max UB(013,023) S.T. C13+CZB/(1+r) C10A+K24/(1+r)+K1A , T3(K13,K23) Using the Kuhn-Tucker method, the Lagrangians are LA: UA(C14,CzA)-q14.TA(K14,KzA) +q24.(K14+KzA/(1+r)-CiA-CzA/(1+r)+Ci°A) Ls: 03(013,023)-q13.TB(K13,K23) +qu.(K13+K23/(1+r)-CiB-CzB/(1+r)+0103) The first order conditions are: UiA-q14=0 , UzA-qib/(1+r)=0 q24.T14+q14=0 , q24T24+q14/(1+r)=0 U13-q13=0 , UzB-qIB/(1+r)=0 q23.T13+q13=0 , quTzB+q13/(1+r)=0 51 Simplication gives: UzA/U1421/(1+r) , U23/01321/(1+r) TzB/T13=-1/(1+r) , Tzh/T14=-1/(1+r) For equilibrium in the loan market, we have: CIA+KIA-CIOA=‘(C13+K13-C103) The above 5 equations plus the two budget constraints will solve for these seven parameters: r,ClA,Czfl,K14,C13,CzB,K13. This is the market equilibrium under perfect capital markets. We demonstrate the solution in Fig. 8.B. A is the lender and B is the borrower. The equilibrium in the loan market means YsstYAXA. Fig. 8.B Figure 8-B 52 Under the Islamic restriction, the interest rate is fixed at zero and the borrower faces a restriction on how much he can borrow. To find the new equilibrium, first we find the optimal solution for each person under zero rate of interest and no limitations on lending or borrowing. If it is seen that they are both lenders, the feasible solution will be same as what was found for each one of them. If they are both net borrowers, then to find the feasible solution we repeat the optimization for each person under the condition that no borrowing is allowed. Finally, if one person was a lender and the other one was a borrower, the allocation of the lender will be already feasible. To find the feasible solution for the borrower, his maximization problem will be repeated subject to the restriction that he can’t borrow more than what the other person is willing to lend. Formally in the first stage we will have: Max UA(CU\,Czh) S.T. TA(K14,K25)=0 01 A+C3A=C1OA+K1 A+K2A Max 03(013,CzB) S.T. TB(K13,K23)=0 C18+CzB=C103+K13+KzB 53 If they are both net borrowers, the feasible solution is obtained by the following optimizations: Max UA(Cih,CZA) S.T. TA(K14,K25)=0 ClA+C2A2C1OA+K1A+K2A C145C1°A+K1A Max U3(CIB,C23) S.T. TB(K18,K23)=0 cla+cgazcloa+xla+xza C13$C109+K18 Figures 9-A and 9-B demonstrate this situation. Figure 9-A 54 Under the positive market rate of interest, A is a lender and B is a borrower. Setting the interest rate at zero will rotate the interest rate line R1R2 to 8182 for both of them. Now if unrestricted borrowing was allowed, they would both be better off, achieving utility levels 02A and 023. But since they can’t borrow, the feasible optimal allocations are ZA and 28 . Both persons are worse off. If in the first stage one of them was a net lender and the other one was a net borrower, the lender’s allocation is feasible but we must repeat the borrower’s optimization problem. Assuming B is the borrower: Max U*B(Ci*B.Cz*9) S.T. T*B(K1*B,Kz*3)=0 clts+c2ts=clos+xlts+xzxa ZA-CI*B+C1°3+K1*320 where ZA=CI°A‘CIA+KIA. ZA is the amount that person A lends at zero interest. Then, the optimal allocations under Islamic restriction are C14,CzA,Ci*B,Cz*B,K14,K25,K1*A,K1*B. Figs. 10-A and 10-B show the feasible solutions and the welfare results in this case: 55 - C1 C1 f R; Fig. 10-A Fig. 10-B Under Islamic restriction, person A chooses Ya and person B wants to choose YB but, since he can’t borrow enough to reach YB, he borrows all that A,is willing to lend. Person B achieves the highest level of utility at we: Max UBIrzozUai. In Fig. 10-B, UsB>U1B implies that the borrower will be better off. But this is not a general conclusion. We could easily give other examples where UsB 0. Now that the signs of dXA/dr and dXB/dr have been determined, we can find the direction of change in X3 and XA when the interest rate is allowed to increase (starting from zero interest rate). As the interest rate increases, the highly risk-averse person is able to reduce his risk taking and the less risk-averse person can do the opposite. 6S dXA= dXA/dr . dr (-)(+)0 To find the impact on the utility of each person, we will first determine the signs of dEUA/dr and dEUB/dr. dEUA/droszUA/dCA.W1(l-XA)+dEUA/dXA.dXA/dro.(f—ro) +(dEUA/d5c43).2XA.dXA/dr.W1.Srz =dEUA/dCA.W1.(1-XA)+dXA/dr.[dEUA/dXA] =dEUA/dCA.W1.(1-XA). The second term is zero since we have dEUA/dXA Therefore we get: dEUA/drszUA/dCA.W1.(l-XA)=(+)(+)>O. The impact of moving away from zero interest on the welfare ~ ofthe more risk-averse person is: dEUA _ dEUA/dro.dro=(+)(+)>0. An increase in the rate of interest - improves his welfare. For the borrower we again have: dEUB /dr=dEUB /dCB . (1-Xs )2:an /dr. [anus /dX.B J; but since the borrower faces quantity constraint, we have dEUB/dXs #0. since for the borrower X3 is smaller than the desired dEUB/dXs>0. We also know that Xs>1. Therefore, dEUB/drszUB/dC?(1-Xs)+dXs/dr.[dEUB/dXs] <>o. The direction of change in the utility of the less risk-averse person is not clear. On one hand, the quantity of loans increases and, on the other hand, he must now pay a 66 positive interest. Whatever the impact on the welfare of the borrower may be, under the Islamic regime, the conditions of pareto optimality are violated. We explained this in Figs. 12-A and 12-B. 2-B. I] I ! E I J . E ! . !° . I ‘E . 1 In this model, we extend the model presented in 2-A to include savings/consumption decisions as well as portfolio choice. Each person has an initial endowment which must be allocated between consumption in two periods.The first period savings must be allocated between safe and risky assets as described in 2-A. In this model, the rate of return on the the risky asset is endogenously determined and it is a decreasing function of net savings by both persons. This rate of return is derived from a general stochastic investment function: Y*=Y(W1-014+W2-C1B,€) The only argument of this function besides the error term is the total investment of both individuals which is in turn equal to the total savings of both of them. The stochastic element reflects the uncertainty about the outcome of the investment project. We assume that €~N(0,1). For this general investment function, the stochastic, one- period rate of return is: 67 r*=(Y*-I)/I = r*(W1-C1A+W2-013,E) where I=(W1-C14)+(W2-C1B). We assume that the production function is concave such that dEY*/dI<0, then the expected rate of return is also a declining function of total savings. (dY*/dI-1).I - (T-I) d?/dI= < o. 12 Furthermore, dr/dI<0 2) dr/d(W1-C1A)<0 and dr/d(W2-C190; B and D are clearly positive. 71 **Sign of A** A=2d+2d.(1+ro)2+2d.xl.(E-ro).(1+ro)+ 2d.(W1-Cih).XA.(1+ro)(-e) We know that E>o, E:1-e.(W1-01A+Wz-cla) => 2) e2d+2a.(1+ro)2+2a.xi.(i-ro).(1+ro)-2d.xl.(1+ro). The sum of the last two terms is positive so the whole phrase is positive A20. **Sign of C** C=[2d.8r3.XAz.(Wl-CIA).2+e+2d.(1+r0+XA(;-r0)).(;-ro)+ 2d.(Wi-Cib).XA.(f-ro).(-e)+2d.(W1-C14).[l+ro+XA(;-ro).(-e)] Again we have: e<1/(W1-C1A) which allows us to claim: C‘)[4d.5r3.XA2.(Wi-Cih)+e+2d.(1+ro+XA(r-ro)).(r-ro)+ 2d.XA.(r-ro).(-1)+2d.(Wi-Cih).(1+ro)+2d.XA(r-ro).(-1))¢> 9.2.0. 72 **Sign of H** H=1-4d.(W1-C1A).(1+ro)-2d.(W1-CiA).XA.(1+ro).(-1-e.d(Wg-C;B)) -2d.(W1-C14).XA.(;-ro). dro If d and e are small enough, this statement is positive. This will happen if W1 and W2 are large numerical values. **Sign of G** G=(-1-e.d(flz -Q1.B_._).)-2d. (W1 -011), [1+ro+XA(r-ro )l. (-1-e-111E1.:§1_“_1) dro dro filflazfiiil Assuming that e<1/(Wz-C1B) and dro ==> (-1-e.diEz_-_Q1ll) < (-1-e. [d(W2 -C13 )/dro l/(Wz -CIB )) dro As a result Q59. Then we can write the system in the following form. [+ +1 [d(W1-Clb)/dro] [+} + + dXA/dro - The only remaining step is to find the size of the determinant [S]=AD-BC. Applying the formulas for B and D we get: )5]:A.2X1.2a.(W1-01A)2.sr3+ 2d.(W1-C1A).(Eero)[(;-ro).A-(1+ro).C] (10) After expanding the bracket in the second and collecting terms we get: 73 [(f—ro).A-(1+ro).C]= (f-ro).2d-4d.s:3.XA2.(W1-C1A).(1+ro)- e.(1+ro).[1-2d.(l+ro+XA(;-ro)).(W1-C1A)]. Then, by carrying out all of the mathematics in equation 10, we have: lSl=4d2.(f-ro)2(W1-Cih)-8d2.5r3.XAZ.(W1-Cifi)2.(1+ro).(;-ro)- 2d.e.(l+ro).(;-ro)).(W1-C1A)+ 4d2.e.(1+ro)2.(;ero)).(W1-C1A)2 + 4d3.e.(1+ro).(;-ro)).(W1-C1A)2.XA + 8d2.sr3.XA2.(W1-Clh)2+ 8d2.5r3.XA.(W1-C1A)2.(1+ro)2+ 8dz.srs.xlz.(W1-C:A)z.(1+ro).(E-ro)- 8d3.sr3.XA2.(W1-Clh)3.(1+ro).e After rearranging terms, we get: )8): 8d3.sr3.XA3.(W1-CIA)2.[-(1+r0).(;-r0).XA2+ (1+ro).(;-ro).XA3+(1+ro)2.XA-(1+ro)3.XA.e]+ 2d.(W1-C14).(;-ro)[(;-ro).2d+4d.s:3.XA2.(W1-C1A)/(;ero)- e.(1+ro)]+4d3.(W1-C1A).(F-ro).(1+ro).e.[1+ro+XA.(;-ro)]. The first and the third terms are clearly positive. The second term will be positive if e is small enough. Recall that e<1/(W1-C14). Therefore, if (W1-Cih) is large enough, 74 e will become small and this term will also become positive. Thus |S|>0. With a positive determinant, we can now determine the ++ signs of the elements in the inverse matrix 8'1. If S=l+ + and det(S)>0, then: 5.4:] And, finally, we will get: [d(W1-C1A)/dro] [+ -J[ + ] [ + dXA/dro - - + - - - 0 g; ;90; . 1.: ::f '7. ._gs_ ,3. :11. : “ no ; W W From the lender’s behavior we know that when the interest rate increases, the quantity of bonds increases. Next we find out how the borrower reacts to this increase in quantity of bonds and the rate of interest. The bond market equilibrium is given by: (l-XA)(W1-C1A)=-(1-Xs)(W2-C1B) (12) Totally differentiating the bond market equation (12) with respect to ro, we get: (1-Xa).d(W1-C1A)/dro- (Wz-C1B).dXA/dro= (l-XB).d(W1-C13)/dr0- (W2-C1B).dXs/dro 75 We can rewrite this equation as: (1-Xs).d(W1-C1B)/dro- (W2-C13).dXs/dro=K<0 d(W1-Cih)/dro>0 and dXA/dro<0 ==e K<0 (13) Besides equation 13, we need one more equation to determine the signs of d(Wl'C13)/dr0 and dXB/dro. To find the second equation, we look at borrowers’ optimization subject to the bond market constraint: Max EUB(C13,C2*3)=Ua(C13,623,Sch) Xs,C1B S.T. C2*3=(W1-013)(1+ro+Xs(;-ro)) 8c32= 5r2.X32.(W2-013)2 (1-XA)(W1-CIA)+(1-XB)(W2-C13)20 [EB :01 a -d‘c1 a 2 +02 9 -d'. C: a 2 -d'. 3:: a 2] The Lagrangian is: L 5U3+qz((1-XA).(W1-CiA)+(1-Xs).(Wz-C1B)) The first order conditions are: dL/dCi 1: :01 a 5623 . (1+ro +113 (E-ro )) -2.UaB.X32(Wz-C1B).sr3+qz.(Xe-1)=0 76 dL/dXBeUzB.(W2-C13)(f—ro)+2.U33.Xs[(W21-018).5r12-q2(W1-Cifi):0 dL/dq2=(1-XA).(WI-C15)+(l-XB).(W2-C13)20, q2.dL/dq2=0 Assuming that q2#0, we need one equation from above to solve for dXs/dro and d(W2-C1B)/dro. The best strategy is to combine dUh/dC1A and dUB/dXs into one equation by eliminating qz. dL/dxaéfiza.(I-ro)+2f§aa.xB(W21-01a).srz-qz =0 (14) dL/dC132 613-623(1+r0)‘XB.(dUB/XB)+q2.(XB-1) =0 dL/dC1B= U13-Uz3(l+ro)-X3.q2+q2.(XE-1) =0 : Uifl-U23(1+ro)-q2=0 (15) By combining 14 and 15, we get: Uza.(E-ro)+2.UaB.xB(W21-C1n).s.2- U1B+Uzn(1+ro)=o 2.UaB.XB(W21-C13).Sr2- U13+U23(1+r) =0 Expanding this equation for a quadratic utility function, we get: -4d’.(Wz-C13)2.an.5r3-1+2d’.CiB+ [1-2d’.(Wz-C13)(1+ro+Xs.(f—ro))].(1+;)=0 Totally differentiating this equation with respect to re gives: 77 d(Wz-Cifi)/dro.[-8d’.(Wz-C1B)2.X32.5r3-2d’-e+ e.2d’.(Wz-C19)(1+ro+Xs.(F—ro))+2d’.e.(W2-C19).(1+;)- 2d’.(1+ro+Xn.(§-ro)).(1+§)] + an/dro.[-2d’.(Wz-Cia).(;-ro).(1+r)-8d’.(W2-013)2.Xs.5r3]= 2d’.(W2-013)(1+ro+X3.(f—ro)).(-e.d(W1-Cih)/dro)+ e.d(W1-C1A)/dro)+ 2d’.(Wz-C1B).(1+;).(1+Xs.(-e.d(W1-C1A)/dro-1)). (16) Equations 13 and 16 give a system that could be solved for d(W2-C1B)/dro and dXB/dro Writing 13 and 16 in matrix form, we have [ ’ B’] [A’ B’ {d(Wz-C1B)/dro] [H’] 13* 8’: C’ D' ] G’ 16* c' D’ ' dXs/dro We must determine the signs of A’, B’, C’, D’, H’ ,G’ and IS’I. From equation 13, we know that C’<0, D’<0 and G’<0. Also Xs>1 , d(W1-C1A)/dr6>0 allow us to claim that BLEQ: **Sign of A’** A’: [-ed'.(W2-Czn)2.Xn2.s:3-2d'-e+ e.2d’.(W2-C13)(1+ro+Xs.(;;r0))+2d’.e.(W2-C13).(1+;)- 2d’.(1+ro+Xs.(;-ro)).(1+;)] 78 If e is small enough, we can safely argue that A’ is negative. A. < 0 **Sign of H’** H’=(-e.d(W1-C1A)/dro).[-2d’.(Wz-C13)(1+ro+Xs.(P-ro))+1]+ Zd’.(W2-C1B).(1+3).(1+Xs.(-e.d(W1-Cih)/dro-1)). Since person B is less risk-averse, d’ will be very small. H’ will be positive if d’ and e are small enough. Assuming a to be sufficiently small, we claim that 8:29. The final step is to find the determinant of S’. IS’le’D’z-(Wz-C1B).A’-(1-Xs).B’ After expanding A’ and B’, we get: 13'): 2d’.(W2-C1B)+ e.[-2d’.(Wz-Cia)(1+ro+Xs.(r-ro))+ 1].(Wz-CiB) + 2d’.(Wz-CiB).(1+;).(1+ro)+ 2d’.(W2- CIB)3.XB.(4Sr3'e.(1+;)) 131129 The determinant will be positive for sufficiently small values of e. Now the system of equations 13 and 16 could be written as: [- - d(W2-C13)/dro + ].[ I: J and IS’|>0. dXs/dro 79 The inverse of S’ is: Wt w1=1 t) + Then: [d(W2-C13)/dro] [- +J [ - I dXB/dro . + - - + d(W2-Cifi)/dro<0 and dXs/dro>0 As the interest rate increases (being zero originally), the borrower’s saving and risk-taking behavior changes in the following directions: d(W2-C1B)=d(W2-C1B)/dro.dro = (-)(+)<0 dXs = dXs/dro.dro = (+)(+)>0 ,: : c :3"; r. ‘: 0: .2 :.: 1,0 ; ‘. ._qo :_ :._ :_ Next, we will look at the welfare results of Islamic restriction. For the lender we have: 11611 /dro :31 A .dC1 A/dro +521) .dCzA /dro +3111 .dscn /dro =U1A.(-1).d(W1 -C1A )/dro +dXA/dr0 . [5211. (W1 -C1A ) . (F-ro )+ 2U35.5r3.XA.(W1-C1A)3] + 621 .d(W1 -C1A )/dro . (1+ro +x11+ . (5-1-0 ) )+62A . (W1 -C1 A ). (1+ xA.(d§/aro-1))+201A.sra.xAz.(W1-C1A).a(W1-C1A)/dro After collecting terms, we get: 80 dUA/droz-d(W1-CiA)/dro.[dUA/dC1]+dXA/dro.[dUA/dXA]+ 62A(W1-C1A).(1+Xx.(d§/dro-1)) However, we know that dUA/dC1A=0 and dUA/dXA=0, therefore, ‘ dUA/droz UzA(W1-C1A).(1+XA.(d;/dro-1)) (17.A) similarly for the borrower we have: dUB/dro=-d(W2-C1B)/dro.[dUB/d01]+dXs/dro.[dUF/dXs]+ U23(Wz-C1B).(1+Xs.(d;/dro-1)) (17.B) For the borrower, however, dUB/d01B <0 and dUB/dXs>0. The direction and size of change in the utilities depends on dE/dro. We will first expand dE/dro and determine its sign. From the optimization problem of the borrower we obtained the system of equations 13 and 16. Solving this system we get: d(W2-C13)/dro=[D’H’+B’G’J/IS’I (17.0) From the bond market constraint equation 13, we get: 6’: (Xx-1).d(W1-C1A)/dro+(W1-Cih).dXA/dro Putting this in equation 17.0, we will get: 81 d(W2-CIB)/dro={D’H’+B’(XA-l).d(W1-C14)/dro+ B’.dXA/dro(W1-C14)}/IS’I d(W2-C13)/dro+d(W1-C1A)/dro={D’H’+[B’(XA-1)+ lS’I].d(W1-CIA)/dro+B’.dXA/dro(W1-CIA)}/|S’I (18) In equation 18, we have added d(W1-C1A)/dro to both sides of equation 17.0. Further, we have lS’le’D’-B’C’ which gives: R.H.S. = {D’H’+B’[(XA-l).d(Wl‘ClA)/dr0+dXA/dr0.(Wi-ClA)' (1-Xs).d(W1-01A)/dro]+ A’D’.d(W1-C1A)/dro}/|S’l We will use the following breakdown to find the sign. R.H.S. = {D’H’+A’D’.d(W1-014)/dro+B’(Xa-l).d(W1-C14)/dro+ B’.[dXA/dro.(W1-C1A)-(1-Xs).d(W1-C1A)/dro]/|S’I The denominator was already shown to be positive. We should only be concerned with the numerator. In the numerator, the last term is clearly positive because B’<0 and dXA/dro.(W1-C1A)-(1-Xs).d(W1-C1A)/dro. The second inequality is the result of the following inequalities: d(W1-014)/dro>0, dXA/dro<0 and XA<1. Our next step is to determine the sign of: 82 D’H’+A’D’.d(W1-C1A)/dro+B’(XA-l).d(W1-CTA)/dro We have: H’+A’.d(W1-C1A)/dro= -8d’(Wz-CTB).X32.sr3.d(W1-C1A)/dro-2d.d(W1-01A)/dro- e.d(W1-C1A)/dro.[1-2d’.(Wz-CzB)(1+ro+Xs(r-ro))]+ e.d(W1-C1A)/dro.2d’.(Wz-CzB).(1+f).Xs-2d’.(1+ro+ Xs(;-ro)).(1+?).d(W1-C1A)/dro+e.d(W1-CTA)/dro.[1- 2d’.(Wz-C.B)(1+ro+Xs(;-ro))]-e.2d’.(Wz-CTB)(1+ E).Xs.d(W1-CTA)/dro+2d’.(W2-013)(1+;)(1-Xs). Some of the terms cancel each other out and afterwards we get: H’+A’.d(W1-C1A)/dro= _ -ea'(W2-C1B).Xn2.513.d(W1-C1A)/dro-2d.d(W1-C1A)/dro ~2d’.(1+ro+Xs(r-ro)).(1+r).d(W1-014)/dro+ 2d’.(Wz-C1B)(1+r)(1-Xs) Also, remember that D’=(W2-C1B).(-1) and 3': 2d'.(Wz-C1a)(1+E)(E-ro)-8a'.(W2-C1B)2;xx.sra Then, D’H’+A’D’.d(W1-C1A)/dro+B’(Xa-1).d(W1-C1A)/dro = 2d'.(Wz-C1a)(1+?)(}-ro).a(W1-C1A)/dro+ 2d’.(Wz-C1B)(1+;)(1+ro).d(W1-C1A)/dro+ Bd’.(W2-013)2.xs.sr3.d(W1-C1A)/dro+ 2a'.(W2-C1B).d(W1-C1A)/dro+2d'.(Wz-C1B)2.(1+§).(1-Xn). 83 Every term in the above phrase is positive. Therefore, D’H’+A’D’.d(W1-CTA)/dro+B’(XA-l).d(W1-CiA)/dro>0 Overall, we have shown that the numerator of the fraction in equation 18 is positive, so the whole fraction is positive and we have: d(W1-C1A)/dro+d(Wz-013)/dr020 dE/droz-e.(d(W1-01A)/dro+d(W2-C1B)/dro)<0 We can now estimate the direction of change in net savings and return to capital when moving away from the zero interest rate. d(Net Savings)=d(W1-C1A + Wz-C1B) =dro.(d(W1-C1A)/dro+d(Wz-CTB)/dro)=(+).(+)>0 The net savings increases. d(Return to Capital) = d? = [df/dro].dro = (+)(-)<0 The return to capital declines. We can now elaborate on the welfare effects of Islamic restriction based on the results of our model. Equations 84 17.A and 17.3 give formulas for dUA/dro and dUB/dro. For the more risk-averse person, A, the change in utility depends on the sensitivity of the expected return on risky assets to changes in the interest rate. If df/dro is a large negative number, the return to capital (the risky asset in our model) falls rapidly as the interest rate rises. This reduction in r will offset part of the welfare gain from the increased interest payment on the bonds that person A holds. Compared to the one-period model of 2.A, the welfare gain of person A will be smaller. The welfare results for the borrower is undetermined because, as the interest rises, the cost of borrowing increases but, at the same time, the quantity of bonds increases also. If he did not face any quantity constraints, we would have had: dUB/dro=UzB.(Wz-Cifi).(1+(d;/dro-1).Xs) Xs>1 and aE/drow => dUB/dro <0 Therefore dUF=EdU3/dro].dro indicating that the borrower would have been better off under Islamic regime. It is the shortage of credit that could change the results. The net impact on the welfare of the borrower is not clear. In addition to the above results, we must also point out that, similar to the one-period model, we observe that the interest-free system is non-pareto optimal. Under a 85 competitive regime with no restrictions on the interest charge, we have: dUA/dCM: U1A-UzA.(1+ro).-.o => U1A/U24=1+ro dUB/dC1Bz UiB-U23.(1+ro)=0 z: U1B/U23=1+ro 0111/02!) = 018/1328 Equation 19 is the condition of pareto optimality and it no longer holds under Islamic regime. Wen The models that were analyzed in 2-A and 2-B gave us approximate indications on how the savings and risk-taking behaviors of the investors changed as a small positive rate of interest was introduced into an Islamic economy. All that was needed was to reverse the results that were found above. 1. For the highly risk-averse individual who was a net lender, a switch from regular to Islamic regime was welfare reducing. He saved less and had to take more risk than before. 2. For the less risk-averse person who was a net borrower, the welfare impact was not clear. He saved more and had to take less risk because he couldn’t borrow as much as he wanted to. 19 86 3. The net saving of the economy declined. As a result, the rate of return on capital was higher under the Islamic regime compared to the regular regime (which lead to less investment). 87 Notes 1) In a recent article, M. Hassan Imam studied the welfare cost of interest rate ceilings in developing nations. His study has shown that interest-rate suppression causes significant distortions in the capital markets of lesser developed nations. CHAPTER 3 THE CONSEQUENCES OF ISLAMIC BANKING IN A MACRO-ECONOMIC FRAMEWORK In this chapter, we focus on the macro-economic consequences of the Islamic economic system. We are primarily interested in three questions: 1) What are the effects of interest-charge elimination on the volume of real investment and output? 2) How can we conduct monetary and fiscal policy in the absence of a government bond market? 3) How do policy multipliers compare between regular and Islamic economies? The only Islamic regulation which is studied here ,is the glimingtion of an interest charge on financial transactions. In Chapter 1, we showed that the other views of Islam on the economic structure did not substantially vary from those of a regulated market economy. The abolition of an interest payment will primarily affect the financial sector of the economy. Financial assets in a modern economy can be divided into- debt__and equity instruments. Equity instruments, such as stock . shares, do not have a fixed return. They are simply claims on a certain productive asset and receive a portion of the 88 89 profits as a dividend. Debt instruments such as private and (government bonds have a pre-assigned rate of interest which is realized if the debtor does not default on his debt. By forbidding an interest charge, Islam effectively eliminates the debt instruments. Consequently, the only financial instruments available in an Islamic economy are in the form of equity. The only other remaining asset will be money. The elimination of an interest charge does not necessarily lead to the elimination of the depository institutions such as banks. Instead, it will cause certain reforms. Banks will provide credit to the public on the basis of equity arrangements such as the profit- and loss- sharing contracts. They will raise credit by offering PLS accounts and demand deposits. (Savings and time deposits will not be permitted.) Demand deposits will be the only debt instruments in an Islamic economy. They are tolerated because no interest charge is involved. The existence of banks allows the public to divide their money holdings into currency and demand deposits. They can also divide the risky portion of their portfolios between equity stocks and PLS accounts. (For reasons that were explained in Chapter 2, it is not necessary to differentiate between direct equity and PLS accounts in our model.) The Islamic economy, therefore, retains many features of a regular market economy with the modification that government and private bonds as well as the interest- paying bank deposits are eliminated. In the following 90 sections, we introduce a Keynesian macro-economic model which has been modified to reflect these differences. Section 1 I] C E I ! ! B ! El° . !' . The elimination of an interest charge leads to the elimination of three types of debt assets: private loans, government bonds and bank savings deposits. It will be too difficult to study the effect of eliminating all three assets simultaniously. If the interest rate on bank deposits are eliminated, they will be transformed into demand deposits. Similarly, government bonds are transformed into money. The public will continue to hold money and demand deposits because, to a large extent, they trust the government and the banking system. Besides, these assets provide some utility to the households as stores of value and means of exchange. Private loans, on the other hand, will no longer exist if the lender is not allowed to charge interest. The reason is that these loans carry a high risk of default and no one will assume this risk when there is no reward. So the elimination of the interest charge will eliminate the private loan market altogether. Since our main analytical method is comparative statics, we will ignore private loans and government bonds at first and concentrate on bank deposits. At the end, we will demonstrate how the results will change if the elimination of government bonds and private loans are also 91 taken into account. Our model will consist of the equilibrium conditions for the real and financial sectors of the economy. _The real sector will be in equilibrium if the aggregate supply of real output is equal to the aggregate demand. In the absence of the government sector, which is the case in this model, we can show the equilibrium by equating savings and investment.1 The savings and investment functions of our ___.— 4‘. _—___—..____ __,._1-—-*——' model are described as follows. ’We_assume that there is a single homogeneous capital good that is being utilized by alluhfirms. Firms can increase their capital by investment in new capital at low cost. But it is more costly to buy or sell a used capital good. As a result, there are two separate markets for capital. There is one market for the newly produced capital good and another market for claims on the existing stock of capital. The F§?§_S£_iEXE§PmepB wwill depend on theJ price differentials between these markets. When the value of equity claims is more than the cost of new capital, firms are encouraged to invest. On the other hand, ‘if the price of new capital (also called the replacement cost of capital) increases relative to the equity price of capital, new investments will decline. This approach to the investment behavior follows Tobin(69), Tobin-Brainard(17) and Benavie(15) among others: - Theappropriate investment function is: -._._-—q_._ I=(V,P) 11)Ofl and” lg 0 92 I = The rate of real investment. P = The price of output. (In our one sector model, the consumer and capital goods are the same commodity.) V = The value of the equity supply. VzPexE where Pezthe price of equity and E = the equity claims on the stock of capital. Since we assume that E is constant, the choice of V instead of Pa will not affect the results. The rate of savings by households is assumed to be \ _# ___,_ positively related to real income and to the rates of return on financial assets. It is negatively related to the level of wealth. + + - S= S(q.r.W)xY q = The rate of return on equity. The rate of return on saving deposits. Real wealth. Real income. Then Afor the equilibrium condition in the real sector, we have: + + - S( q ,r , W)x Y = I(V ,P) 1.1 There are three assets in the financial sector of our model. These are equity ,saving deposits and money. Each household must allocate its wealth among these three assets. Savings deposits are offered by the banks. Banks will keep a portion of these deposits as reserve and invest the rest in the equity markets. The equilibrium conditions for these 93 markets are given by the following equations: + - - + (1-K).B/P + h1(q.r,Y,W)= V/P Equity (1.2) - - + + K.B/P + h2(q,r,Y,W)= M/P High-powered money (1.3) - + - + h3(q ,r ,Y ,W)= B/P Savings deposits (1.4) B = Saving Deposits; M = Money; K = The reserve requirement ratio on demand deposits h1,h2,h3 = The household demands for equity, currency and savings deposits, respectively. This model has a Keynesian structure where, due to insufficient demand, the economy is operating at less than full employment level. As a result, the price level is assumed to be fixed. Any increase in demand will stimulate output without putting an upward pressure on prices. We rely on these (assumptions as well as the static nature of our model to ignore the question of inflation altogether. We assume that the interest rate on savings deposits is fixed below its equilibrium value by the monetary authorities. As a result, the banks accept all the deposits that they can get at any level of the interest rate ceiling. Equation 1.4 indicates that the equilibrium value of the savings deposits is always the quantity demanded by the households. The derivative signs of the asset-demand equations indicate that the demand for each asset is positively related to its own rate of return and negatively 94 related to the rate of return on other assets. An increase in income will increase the public demand for money because of the transaction needs. Since income is not a component of real wealth, we have h13 + has + h33=0. We also know that hza implies that the increase in income must reduce the total demand for other assets: h13 + haaz-hza <0 Finally, the asset demand functions are positively related to changes in real wealth.The wealth constraint is W=V/P + M/P. Since savings deposits are a liability of the private sector to itself, they do not appear in the wealth constraint. We will modify the model further to reflect the dependence of dividends on the value of equity and income. While the model itself does not include the supply side of the economy, we will make a brief reference to the commodity and labor supplies in order to explain this dependency. On the supply side of the economy, the production function is: Y = F(L,K°) F1>0 & Fz<0 C" II Quantity of labor demanded. K0 = The supply of capital which is assumed to be fixed in the short run. Since equity represents claims on the stock of capital, the return on equity will depend on the share of capital in national income. 95 q»..— q=[P. F2(L,K0). KOJ/V F2(L,K°)=Marginal product of capital. (An increasing function of labor demanded.) The demand for labor is a positive function of demand for Output. + L=L(Y) +.. Replacing for L in F2(L,K0), we get q=[P.H(Y,K°).K°]/V. Since K0 is fixed, any increase in output will increase the marginal product of capital. Therefore, we can write the +'+ - rate of return to capital asz: q(P, Y, V). The real q=++q- wealth could also be written as W = W(V, M, P). Replacing for q and W in equations 1.1-1.4, we get: + + - - + - S(Y,P,V,M).Y = I(V,P) Commodities (2.1) ? ? - 7 + (1-K).B/P + f1(Y,P,r,V,M) =V/P Equity (2.2) ?--++ K.B/P + fz(Y,P,r,V,M) = M/P High-powered money (2.3) - - + + + f3(Y,P,r,V,M) = B/P Savings deposits (2.4) As we can see, the dependency of the equity rate of return on income and the value of equity leads to indeterminacy in some of the derivative signs. To study the impact of interest rate control, we will first combine the asset market equations into a single equilibrium condition for the financial sector. From 2.4, we replace for B/P in 2.2 and 2.3. The wealth constraint allows us to ignore one of the two resulting equations. We 96 will keep the money market equation and drop the other .one. Then the IS and LM equations of our model are: + + + - - + - S(Y,P,r,V,M).Y = I(V,P) 3.1 IS - - + + + ? - - + + K.f3(Y,P,r,V,M) + f2(Y,P,r,V,M) = M/P 3.2 LM The endogenous variables are Y and V. M and r are exogenously determined. Our objective is to see how the endogenous variables change as the rate of interest is reduced to zero from its original positive value. Since the method of comparative statics is only applicable for the study of relatively small changes in the exogenous variables, we analyze the problem from a different point of reference. We assume that the rate of interest is originally fixed at zero, then we observe the direction of change in the endogenous variables as the rate of interest is slightly increased. These changes will approximately reflect the opposite of what will happen if the interest rate is reduced from an original small positive value to zero. The equilibrium conditions 3.1 and 3.2 hold for any nonnegative rate of interest including zero. Totally differentiating these equations with respect to V, Y, and r we have: Sa.Y-I1 SI.Y+S dV -Sa.Y '[ = odr 4.1 K.fa4+f24 K.f31+fz1 dY -K.faa-f32 System 4.1 could be written as: 97 , dV A. = B.dr 4.2 dY By defining the signs of the elements of A and B, we would like to determine the signs of dV/dr and dY/dr . From the derivative signs of 3.1 and 3.2 it is clear that: A11<0, A12>0, A21>0, Bll<0 A22 and B21 are apriori indeterminate. To determine their signs, we must make certain assumptions about the elasticities of asset demands. If we assume that the demand for money is more sensitive to variations in income than to variations in return to equity, then f12 will become positive, and since K is very small, we would have A22=k.f31+f21>0. Also, we assume that the savings deposits are the primary substitutes for money. This assumption implies that fzs is significantly different from zero and as a result: Bziz-K.f33-f32>0 These two assumptions could be combined into a single assumption which says that in a regular economy bonds are strong substitutes and equity is a weak substitute for money. This requirement does not weaken the results because both intuitively and empirically appear to be true. Using these signs, we write 4.2 as: 98 1.1.1: I] l: :l det(A)<0 I” H dY = + . dr 4.3 3;;gil = [; :][;i= [7] : dv/dr>0 , dy/dr:0. We can now interpret these results to say approximately the following: Eganlt_1: The suppression of interest payments on savings deposits will reduce the value of equity assets and cause a drop in the rate of investment. The net change in real output, however, is indeterminate. The reason for the second result is that the reduction in the interest rate reduces the size of investment but at the same time increases the level of consumption. Thus, the aggregate demand could increase or decrease. So far, we have seen the impact of Islamic regulation if the only existing debt instruments were savings deposits. In most nations, however, we find several other debt instruments such as private bonds and government bonds. The regulation will eliminate these instruments as well. We will now briefly describe what happens when these instruments are eliminated. First, consider the case of private bonds that are used for investment. ‘ We assume that firms are originally issuing bonds and equity. Under Islamic regulation, these bonds must be liquidated. Whether the liquidation takes place gradually or suddenly, the net result is that the firms must pay back the value of bonds or replace them with equity. At the 99 aggregate level, we assume that the entire stock of capital is owned and employed by the firms. Then it must be the case that the market value of the stock of capital equals the value of the equity and bonds that firms have issued. Pk°.K= Pa .Eo+Bp 1* Pk0 = The price of physical capital before change. K = The stock of physical capital (assumed fixed.) Pa = The price of equity. E0 = The stock of equity shares before change. Bp The nominal value of private debt issued by the firms to the public. Due to the possibility of default, the private loans are risky; but since in every firm bonds have the first claim on earnings, they are less risky than the stocks. When the interest payment on bonds is eliminated, households will eventually transfer the funds that were invested in bonds into money and equity. This transfer will generate a new demand for equity. At the same time, the firms must raise funds to pay back the loans and they do so by selling stocks or by PLS borrowing. Therefore, we would have a rise in the supply and demand for equity at the same time. If private bonds and equity were perfect substitutes, households would have replaced equity for their entire bond holdings and no funds would have been pulled out of the private securities markets; but since equities are generally riskier than bonds, risk-averse investors will not replace each bond with 100 an equal value of equity. Instead, they will replace it with a combination of equity and money. The allocation will depend on each person’s degree of risk aversion. In this case some funds will be pulled out of the private claims market and held as money. Because the total demand for securities of private firms has declined, both sides of equation 1* will decline. We will have: PR1 . K = Pe1 . E1 2* Pol . E1 < Pa . E0 3.A* PR1 . K < PRO . K 1?’ Pk1 < Pko 3.B* Pkl =Price of capital after the elimination of bonds. Pal =Price of equity after the elimination of bonds. Inequalities 3.A* and 3.B* indicate that: ,Besnlt_z: The elimination of private investment bonds, as a result of the Islamic regulation, will lead to a decline in the value of physical capital as well as the value of claims on capital (equities). The drop in value of capital will reduce people’s incentive to invest. Next, we consider the removal of the government bonds market. The Islamic restriction will forbid any interest payment on these bonds. Under zero interest, the public will prefer money and demand deposits to the government bonds because the latter are less liquid while they all pay the same nominal zero interest and carry the same level of risk. The government will have to retire all of its debt. The 101 needed funds could be raised either by increased taxation or by increasing the money supply. Since the effects of tax increases have already been extensively studied in the literature, we ignore this option and concentrate on the case where the government pays back the debt by increasing the money supply. If the debt is large, this proportional increase in the money supply could be significant, leading to an increased demand for commodities and equity. As a result, the price of equities rises leading to a rise in the value of equity and encouraging more investment. At the same time, the price level will also rise; both investment and consumer goods will be more expensive. These higher prices, on the other hand, will discourage investment. The net effect on investment depends on whether the economy is at full employment or not. If the economy is at full employment, the price level will rise and the net effect of this policy will not be clear. 0n the other hand, if there is unemployment, prices will remain stable and both investment and output will increase. In brief, we will have: ,Resnlt__§: To eliminate the interest payment by the government, all the existing government bonds must be liquidated. In order to retire its debt, the government must raise funds by means other than public borrowing. The remaining options are taxation and increasing the money supply. Refinlt_5: If the government prints additional money to 102 buy back its bonds, the money supply will rise leading to an increase in demand for equities which will in turn stimulate investment. We see that elimination of the interest charge will result in several institutional changes. Each of these changes has a clear impact on the level of output and the rate of investment. The direction of change however is not the same for all of them. Unlike savings deposits and private investment bonds, the elimination of government bonds will not necessarily lead to a drop in investment. Thus, we will arrive at the final result of this section: Bgsult_5: In the short run, the impact of interest- charge elimination depends on the existance and relative magnitude of private loans and government bonds: a) In the absence of government bonds, the elimination of interest charges will reduce the aggregate demand for equities and adversely affect the rate of investment. b) If government bonds already exist in the economy, their liquidation (which is assumed to be financed by an increase in the money supply) will have an opposite effect on investment. In this case, if the volume of government bonds is significantly larger than private loans, interest- rate elimination will lead to an increase in demand for equity and investment. Otherwise, the net demand for equity declines and leads to a drop in the rate of investment. 103 Section 2 Wen):- In this section, we concentrate on developing a macro model for an interest-free economy in order to study the conduct of fiscal and monetary policy in such an economy. With the elimination of the bond market, the remaining financial assets in the Islamic economy are money and equity. Thus, any monetary policy must be conducted within these asset markets. The tools of monetary policy which depend exclusively on debt instruments such as open-market operations on government bonds and various interest-rate controls (such as regulation Q and the discount rate) will no longer be available. Instead, there will be two major tools of monetary control. These are open-market operations on equity markets and control over the reserve requirement ratio of the demand deposits. The monetary authorities could intervene in the stock market in the same manner that the central banks intervene in the bond market in a regular economy. In priori we expect the open-market sale and purchase of stocks to be contractionary and expansionary, respectively. These will be further investigated in the analytical model that will follow. The elimination of government bonds implies that the government can only borrow from the central bank. In response, the central bank has two options, it can monetize the deficit by increasing the money supply or it can keep 104 the money supply unchanged and finance the deficit by sale of equity. The second option is limited to the maximum- equity ownership of the central bank. If the government debt continues to grow, eventually the central bank will have to monetize it. (We have analyzed the debt financed fiscal policy in appendix A to this chapter.) To study the impact of these fiscal and monetary policies, we will use the same model that was developed in section one after making the necessary modifications. WW2. We consider a one-sector economy were the same output is used for consumption and investment. There are three sources of demand for the real output of the economy: private consumption, private investment and government expenditure. The equilibrium in the real sector is demonstrated by: + - - + + - C(Y,q,P,W)+I(V,P)+G = Y 5.1 G = The government expenditurea. There are three assets in the financial sector: High- powered money, demand deposits, and equity. The banks use demand deposits to purchase equity after satisfying the reserve requirements. The equilibrium conditions for the asset markets are: + — + (1-K).D/P + h1(q,Y,W) + Vg/P = V/P 5.2 105 K.D/P + h2(q.Y,W) = M/P 5.3 h3(q,Y,W) : D/P 5.4 D = The supply of demand deposits. ha 2 The demand for demand deposits. K = The reserve requirement ratio on demand deposits. Vg = The value of equity held by the central bank. Since the demand deposits do not receive any interest, banks accept all the demand deposits that they can get and, thus, equilibrium is given by equation 5.4. Without loss of any generality we can combine the demands for high-powered money and demand deposits into a general demand function for money when analyzing monetary and fiscal policy.4 The financial sector then will consist of two assets: money and equity. The complete model of the economy becomes: + - — + + - C(Y,q,P,W)+I(V,P)+ G ; Y 6.1 + - + h1(q,Y,W) + Vg/P = V/P 6.2 - + + h2(q,Y,W) = M/P 6.3 Before starting the comparative static analysis, we will incorporate the following additions and modifications. In section one, we already showed that: + - + q: q(Y,V,P) and W=V/P + M/P Furthermore, we also know that a change in government equity holding through an open-market operation will change the money supply. A change in government debt will also 106 change the money supply if the central bank chooses to monetize it. Therefore, we have: + + M/P= M(Vg,G)/P Real wealth then will also be a function of V: and G. The change in Vg, however, does not change the real wealth of the private sector because we will always have: dW = - dVg/P + dM/P. Consequently, we have: + +:— W(V,G,P) i: ll After adding these changes to the equilibrium conditions 6.1-6.3, we will get: —?++ +- . C(P,Y,G,V) + I(V,P) + G = Y Commodities 7.1 +?+? Vg/P + f1(P,Y,G,V) = V/P Equities 7.2 - 7 + + “t + f2(P,Y,G,V) = M(G,Vg)/P Money 7.3 The asset market equilibrium conditions are connected together by the wealth constraint and we can ignore one of the markets in our analysis. To derive the fiscal and monetary multipliers for the Islamic economy, we totally differentiate 7.1 and 7.2 with respect to V, Y, G and Vg. Writing the results in the matrix form we have. c4 + I1 02-1 dV 03+1 dV¢ [ f14-1/P 112 ]. [dY ] -- li/P 111] [as i8 8.1 could be written as: dV dVg At[ J =-Bx [ ] 8 2 dY ° dG 107 From 7.1 and 7.2, we can easily see that A11*=04+I1>O and A12 = C2-1<0. A21 2 f14 - 1/P From the wealth constraint, we know that f14+f24=1/P. We also know that f24>0. Combining these two facts, we have f14-1/P=- f24 <0. So A21<0. A22 is indeterminate. B* has the following signs: The determinant of A* is dependent on the sign of A22=f12. ‘+ -‘ ? if f12>0 A* = - ? det(A*)=D* = 9 - if f12<0 f12 -A12 ? + A""1 =1/D*. = 1/D*. -A21 A11 + + Solving for dV and dY, we have: dV dVg ? + 0 + dVg ‘ : - A*-1 , B*'1 : -1/D*. , : dY dG + + + + dG +/-D* (?+(+))/-D* st +/-D* +/-D* dG The multipliers have the following signs:5 dV/dG=?/D* dV/dV¢:-/D* dY/dG=-/D* dY/dV¢=-/D* The results depend on the sign of the determinant. We apply the correspondence theorem to find the sign of D* which is required for stability. We assume that the time rates of change in V and Y are increasing functions of excess demands for equity and commodity. dV/dt=n(Va-V) n’>0 & n(0)=0 dY/dt=m(C+I+G-Y) m’>0 & m(0)=0 108 Applying a Taylor expansion to these differential equations around the equilibrium values we get: [dV/dt] [m’.(04+l1) m’.(Cz-1)]. {V- V0]:Q Q{V—Vo dY/dt n’.(f14-1/P) n’.f12 Y- Yo Y-Yo The characteristic equation is lQ-z.I|=0. For stability, the Eigenvalues (the 203) must have negative real parts: The determinant equation is: 22-(m’.(04+I1)+n’.f12).z + m’.(04+li).n’.(f12)- n’.(f14-1/P).m’(Cz-1)=0 We must have: m’.(04+11)+n’.f12 <0. m’.(C4+I1).n’.(f14-1/P) - m’.(Cz-1).n’(f14-1/P) )0 The first inequality implies that f1: <0. Furthermore, f12<0 is a sufficient condition for |D*l <0. Therefore, we, see that, for the system to be stable, an increase in income must lead to a net reduction in demand for equity. Originally, an increase in income had two offseting effects on demand for equity. On the one hand, it raised the return on equity leading to an increase in demand for equity, and on the other hand, it increased the transaction demand for money and, since equity is the only substitute asset for money, the public increased their money holdings at the 109 expense of equity. We require the second effect to be stronger in magnitude, even if the dividend effect of a change in income is stronger than the substitution effects, such that f12 is positive, we will still get the above results as long as f12 is sufficiently small.7 For the condition that was stated, the open-market operation multipliers have the expected signs. dV/dVg >0 and dV/dG<0. The government purchase of equity is expansionary. It increases the demand for equity leading to a rise in investment and output. The fiscal policy multipliers are dY/dG >0 and dV/dG (>0. A money-financed government deficit increases the real output but the net impact on investment is not clear. In algebraic terms, we have: dV/dG = -1/D* .[f12.(03+1) + (1- 02).f13]. By further manipulation of this formula, we will be able to identify the direct and indirect effects of G- on V. The bracket could be written as: ' (1-02).[f13 + f12.(Ca+1)/(1-Cz)] f13 is the direct impact of, increased G on equity demand via the wealth effect. The indirect effect is given by the second term inside the bracket. The increased government spending increases the aggregate demand and Y will increase to restore equilibrium. The net effect of these actions is shown by fraction (Ca+1)/(1-02). The increased income affects the demand for equity f12 but, unfortunately, the direction of change is not clear. 110 Therefore, the direct and indirect effects could reinforce or offset each other. The impact of a monetized deficit on output is expansionary because the feedback from the equity market into the real sector reinforces the direct effect. dY/dG=-1/D*.[(1/P-f14).(03+1) + (C4+I1).f13] Factoring out (1/P-f151 we get: dY/dGz-l/D*.(1/P-f14).[03+1+ f13.(C4+I1)/(1/P-f14)] C3+1 is the direct impact of G on Y and is clearly positive. The feedback from the equity market is shown by the second term in the bracket. A rise in G has a wealth effect on the equity demand, causing an excess demand for equity. To restore equilibrium, V must rise as shown by (1/P-f14). The increase in V will further increase the aggregate demand. Both direct and indirect effects are positive. 111 Section Three WWW. Now that we have developed the tools of monetary and fiscal policy for an equity-based economy, the next question is how do these differ from similar policies in a regular economy in the size and direction of their effects. To demonstrate a regular economy, we must add two additional markets to our model of an interest-free economy. These are the markets for private and government bonds. The policies that we are concerned with are open-market operations on government bonds and fiscal policy. Since none of these require any direct interaction with the private bond market, we choose to ignore this market as we did in the model of section 2. Therefore, in the macro model of the regular economy, there are three assets markets for government bonds, equity and money. In this model, government does not hold any equity because the equity market is not used for monetary intervention. Instead, we have introduced the conventional method of monetary intervention that is practiced in the Western economies. The equilibrium conditions for the regular economy are: + - - - + + - C(Y,q,b,P,W)+I(V,P)+G = Y 10.1 Commodity + — - + f1(q,b,Y,W) : V/P 10.2 Equity - - + + f2(q,b,Y,W) = M/P 10.3 Money f4(q,b,Y,W) = S/(b.P) 10.4 Bonds 112 b = The rate of return on government bonds. (Endogenously . determined) S = The nominal supply of government bonds. f4 = Real demand for government bonds. The wealth constraint for this model is W=V/P+M/P+S/(b.P). Changes in government deficit and open- market Operations by the central bank will change the money supply and we have: . M/P=M(S,G)/P We also have the following function that was explained in section 2. + - q=q(Y.V.P) An exchange of bonds for money does not change real wealth. An open-market operation changes the supplies of bonds and money by the same magnitude in opposite directions. When replacing the wealth parameter in model 10.1-10.4, we demonstrated this neutrality by writing: W=W(G,V,b) G appears in the wealth function because we have assumed that the government deficit is monetized.8 Thus, as G changes, the money supply changes and causes the real wealth to change. Replacing for q and W in equations 10.1-10.4, we have: +— +I(V,P)+G Y 11.1 t? 3.6. 2.1.3 21+- "<1-o- §:1e. ll V/P 11.2 113 f2( ) ) ? 1Y1 M(G.S)/P 11.3 Y 671-1-04- 4. 1V: + V Cr-OO‘ I P f4(P S/(b.P) 11.4 3 I ’ Since by the virtue of the wealth constraint one of the equilibrium conditions for the asset markets is redundant, we choose to ignore the bond market. To analyze the impact of fiscal policy and open-market operations, we totally differentiate equations 11.1-11.3 with respect to b,Y,V,S,G. 'C4+Ii 02-1 05 'dV 0 03+1 l ‘f24 £22 £25 . dY =- -M2/P fza -M1/P . l tf14-1/P £12 £15 _db 0 £1 12.1 In matrix form, 12.1 could be written as: A. 3[dY =-B.{ db We must determine the signs of the elements of‘x and B in order to derive the signs of the multipliers. Based on the derivative signs in system 11.1-11.4, the signs of the following elements are obvious: A11=C4+I1 >0 , K12 = 02-1 <0 , X1 = Cs<0 A21 = £24 >0 , A22 = ? , A23 = f25<0 A71 = f14- 1/P(o, £172 2 ? , A. = f15<0 Only two elements of A are a priori undetermined: Xzz=f22 , Z23=f12.f22 is the derivative of demand for money with respect to income. The only reason that fzz might be negative is that an increase in Y will increase the dividend rate and encourage people to increase the ratio of equity in their portfolio. We call this the dividend effect. This 114 tendency is in conflict with the transaction demand for money which rises with income. However, in the presence of bonds, equity will be a weak substitute for money. Thus, we assume that the transaction demand for money dominates the dividend effect and an increase in income raises the demand for money. A22 = fzz >0. f12 is the derivative of equity demand with respect to income.An increase in income will have two opposite impacts on equity demand, the dividend effect increases the equity demand while the substitution effect reduces it. In the equity-based model, we argued that, since equity was the only substitute for money, the substitution effect was fairly strong. This leads to the assumption that f12 <0. In this model of the regular economy, we assume that bonds are the primary substitutes for money. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that the net effect of a change in income on equity demand is more likely to be positive than negative. We carry out the analysis conditional on the sign of £12 In matrix B, the signs of the elements are easily 0 -+ B: + -] 0 + We have already shown that K has the following signs. determined. — + - - A = [+ + -] F011 021 031 71-1 =1/f). 012 022 012 = 1/1') .0' _01 a 023 033 115 av q dS’ dY =-A-1.B. db as D = det(A). O = The matrix of cofactors for matrix A. The signs of A15 allow us to determine the signs of most of the elements in 0 under the assumption of f12 >0. O11 - + ' O’ = + - 023 + 023 + The indeterminate elements are: 011 =f12.f15 - f12.f25 13.A 023 =e[(04+I1).f12 - (02-1)(f14-1/P) 13.3 032 =-[(C4+11).f25-Cs.f24] 13.0 The solution to the system is: av '011 - + ' 'o -' '+/B [(-)-011]/B _ as _ _ as‘ dY =1/D. + - 032 . - + . l: +/D [(-)-032]/D . J dG _ _ as db _+ 023 + ,0 - ,-023/D [(~)+023]/D The multipliers are: dV/dS = +/B dV/dG = [(-)-011J/B _ _ 14 dY/dS = +/D dY/dG = [(-)-01z]/b The signs of these multipliers depend on the sign of the determinant which in turn depends on f12. It could be shown that f12wis a sufficient condition for D < 0. It is also clear from basic monetary theory that dV/dS and dY/dS must be negative. This requirement is satisfied when D<0. Unfortunately, even when f1®0 is given the proper sign, the 116 government deficit multipliers are still indeterminate. This indeterminacy is caused by two factors: first, the reaction of equity demand to changes in income is not clear and second, the presence of a bond market causes a negative feedback from the financial sector to the real sector. Consider an initial increase in G which leads to an increase in income. The rise in Y will cause a drop in demand for equity which could be partially offset by the wealth effect £34. Nevertheless, the net effect could very well be negative causing an excess supply in the bond market. To restore equilibrium in the bond market, the bond rate must rise. The rise in bond rate will have a negative impact on consumption demand. The initial increase in G will also increase the demand for equity (increase in money supply will have a wealth effect on equity demand); but at the same time, the higher bond rate will have an opposite effect on the equity demand. As a result, the net change in equity values is not clear. This indeterminacy causes an indeterminate change in the investment demand. Consequently, the net change in the aggregate demand is not clear because the increase in government spending could be offset by reductions in private consumption and investment. Based on the multiplier formulas in 14, we can present sufficient conditions which, if met, will make the fiscal policy expansionary. dY/dG would be positive if 031 > 0, and from 13.c, 032 will be positive if (C4+Ii).f24-05.f24<0. 117 Finally, this last condition will be satisfied if the aggregate demand for output is more sensitive to changes in equity return compared to the bond rate9 and, at the same time, the demand for money is more sensitive to the bond rate compared to the equity return: (C4+I1)>Cs & |f25|>lf24| Both parts of this condition are expected to be true. The second part, however, depends on the degree of substitution between money and other assets. dV/dG will be positive if 011=f22.f15 - f12.f25>0. A sufficient condition for this inequality to be satisfied is for the money demand to be less sensitive to income than to bond rate and the equity demand to be less sensitive to the bond rate than to income. f25>f22 and lf12|>|f151 It is not clear if these conditions are satisfied in the real world. 118 Section Four 0 ' ffect 0 he Re u a and E ‘t - Wines. To compare the impact of fiscal and monetary policies in the regular- and equity-based economies, we have develOped separate models for each economy. The basic difference between these models is that the equity-based economy does not have any bond market. Before going into the comparison of these two regimes, we must point out that the macro model of regular economy that is develOped here differs from the standard textbook macro models. In these textbook models, money and bonds are the only assets considered. The implicit assumption is that bonds and equity are perfect substitutes. They are combined into a single bond market. The bond rate is the same as the rate of return on equity. In this type of two-asset models, there is more confidence about the impact of fiscal policy. For example, consider a pure increase in government expenditure which initially will increase the output. At the same time, it could cause an excess supply in the bond market leading to an increase in the bond rate. the rise in bond rate will feed back into the consumption and investment demand and put a downward pressure on output. This decline can, at most, offset the initial increase in output but it cannot cause a net decline. (If the feedback effect is large enough to 119 cause a net decline in output, the model will be unstable.) Therefore, a fiscal policy in this case will be expansionary or at worst neutral. In a three-asset model like the one that was developed in this chapter, however, the presence of a third market for equity could cause a net decline in output in response to a fiscal policy. The main feature of the three-asset models, which is partially responsible for this added uncertainty about the impact of fiscal policy, is the fact that the net effect of a change in income on demand for equity is not clear. We will now turn our attention to comparing the regular and the equity-based economic systems. The comparative static analysis of several policy instruments shows that, while the policies in general have similar effects, there are some differences in the performance of these two regimes. As one would expect, these differences are explained by the fact that one model includes a bond market and the other one does not. The policies that we studied are: 1) Open-market operations. 2) Monetized fiscal deficit. 3) Bond (Equity) financed fiscal policy. In an appendix to this chapter, we have also analyzed the impact of two other policies: 1) pure fiscal policy and 2) a pure increase in the money supply. Because of the 120 governments’ budget constraint, these policies can never be implemented alone. They are only analyzed to aid us in understanding the original three policies. The qualitative effect of these policies is presented in Table 1. A. Win):- This policy consists of an autonomous increase in government expenditures without any equivalent change in the supply of bonds or money. Such an increase will increase the commodity demand but it will not have a wealth effect on the asset demands: BESULI_1: A pure fiscal policy will be expansionary under Islamic and regular regimes. BESQLI_2: A pure fiscal policy will increase (decrease) investment if the demand for equity is positively (negatively) related to variations in real income, dV/dY>0 and (dV/dY<0), under both regimes. The first result comes as no surprise. When the economy operates at less than full employment, an autonomous increase in expenditures will stimulate more production. The explanation for the second result is that an increase in income has two offsetting effects on the demand for equity. On one hand, it leads to higher dividends which will increase demand for equity and on the other hand, it causes a shift from equity to money because of the increased transaction demand for money. This second effect might seem 121 Pure Pure Increase Bond Money Open Fiscal In Money Financed Financed Market Policy Supply Deficit Deficit. Operatign Equity + + (>0 + + Based Economy <>0 Apriori (>0 ----------- - ()0 + if f12<0 <>0 <>0 Apriori Apriori + --------- (>0 -------- + + + Regular conditional conditional <>0 <>0 Economy Apriori Apriori (>0 ----------- (>0 ---------- + + + Conditional Conditional TABLE 1 122 strange but it is a direct consequence of the fact that income is not a component of wealth. Therefore, if a change in income leads to a change in the asset demands, these changes must offset each other. Since an increase in income increases the demand for money, it must cause a decline in all or some of the other asset demands. In the Islamic economy, equity is the only substitute for money and any increase in demand for money as a result of rising income is offset by a decline in equity demand. Therefore, at the same time that Y increases, investments could increase or decrease; but investments will never decline sufficiently enough to cause a net reduction in aggregate demand. To see this, consider the following possibilities: a) If dV/dY<0, the increase in G will increase Y and cause a drop in V which will reduce I and C, so we have had a decline in C and I. The net effect on Y could be positive or negative. A reduction in Y, however, will be inconsistent. This is because, if Y declines, V will increase . That will increase 0 and I, then we will have an increase in Y which is contradictory; b) If dV/dY>0, the increase in G will increase Y and that in turn will increase 0 and I. Consequently, Y can only increase. 123 B) Wank. BESHLI_3: A pure increase in the money supply under the Islamic regime will increase output. Investment will also increase if equity demand is positively related to income, dV/dY>0. BESULI_A: A priori, in a regular economy, the impact of a pure increase in the money supply on output and investment is indeterminate. (The sufficiency conditions for an increase in output and investment are given in results 6 and 7.) RESQLI_5: The existance of the bond market in a regular economy will reduce our confidence about the impact of an increase in the supply of money on the aggregate demand. The explanation for result 3 is same as the one given for results 1 and 2 with the single difference that this time the process starts with an increase in the money supply rather than G. The increase in the money supply will have a wealth effect on consumption which will increase output. At the same time, it will have a positive wealth effect on equity demand, but this might be offset by the income effect which could be negative. The lower degree of confidence under the regular regime compared to the Islamic regime (Results 3 & 4) is due to the 124 feedback from the bond market into the equity and commodity markets. Consider an initial increase in the money supply which_ will have a positive wealth effect on the demand for all three assets. It will cause an excess supply in the money market and an increase in the consumption demand. The increased consumption will increase the transaction demand for money at the expense of a demand for bonds. Therefore, there are two conflicting forces on the bond market. On one hand, the increase in money supply will have a positive wealth effect and, on the other hand, the increased transaction demand for money will reduce the demand for bonds. If the net effect of these two forces is a reduction in bond demand, the bond rate must increase to restore equilibrium. The rise in the bond rate will then feed back into the consumption demand and equity demand, offsetting the initial increase that was brought about by the original increase in the money supply. This is only a possibility and the outcome also depends on how sensitive the consumption and equity demands are to changes in the bond rate. We can give sufficiency conditions that will make the increase in the money supply expansionary: BESQLI_6;A: Under a regular regime, a pure monetary policy will be expansionary if the aggregate demand is more sensitive to changes in return to equity compared to the interest rate and, at the same time, 125 the demand for money is more sensitive to changes in the interest rate compared to the equity return. RESQLI_6;B: A second sufficient condition for an increase in output is the zero-interest elasticity of consumption. BESULI_1;A: Under a regular regime, a pure increase in the money supply will increase investment if the money demand is less sensitive to changes in income than changes in the bond rate and, at the same time, equity demand is less sensitive to changes in the bond rate compared to changes in income. BESULI_Z;B: A second sufficient condition for an increase in investment is for the elasticity of the equity demand, with respect to the bond rate, to be zero. To explain these results, we refer to the money-supply multipliers that were developed in Appendix B. dV/dM=(-011-(-))/B 011=f22.f15 - f12.fzs dY/dM=((-)-032)/D 032=-[(C4+Ii).f25-Cs.f24] We have already shown that D <0. These multipliers will be positive if 011 and 012». Results 6 and 7 simply present sufficiency conditions for Ch1>0 and 032>0, respectively. Note that these sufficiency conditions are independent of the units of measurement. For 126 example, in 011 a change in the unit of measurement for income will change f12 and fzz by the same proportion without changing the sign of 011. C) W91 BESQLI_§: In an equity-based economy, a money-financed fiscal policy will clearly increase output. The investment level will increase if equity demand is positively related to income, dV/dY>0. BESQLI_9: The a priori impact of a money-financed fiscal policy on output and investment in a regular economy is not clear. The policy will be expansionary if the conditions that were listed in results 6 and 7 are met. This policy is a combination of a pure fiscal policy and a pure increase in the money supply. Accordingly, the not impact is a mixture of these two policy effects. Even though we are less confident about the effects of this policy in a regular economy, a careful look at the conditions that were stated in Result 6 reveals that they are very likely to be met. Recent studies have shown that consumption in the United States is not significantly sensitive to the interest rate. Overall, under both regimes, the response to this policy depends on how changes in income affect the demand for equity. In case of the regular regime, another factor is the sensitivity of 127 consumption and equity demands to changes in the interest rate. If they are insensitive, the policy will be expansionary. D) W191. BESQLI_19: A bond (equity) financed fiscal policy will have an indeterminate effect on output in a regular (an equity-based) economy. BESQLI_11: An equity-financed fiscal policy will reduce investment in an Islamic regime while a bond-financed fiscal policy will have an indeterminate effect on investments in a regular economy. The justification for these results is that the original increase in G could be offset by a possible reduction in investment and consumption demands. These reductions are caused by an increase in the interest rate in the regular economy and a reduction in equity values in the equity-based economy. Under the equity-based regime, the added deficit is financed by the sale of government-owned equity. This sale will reduce the value of equities and cause a drop in investment. The impact on investment under a regular regime is not clear because the debt is financed by the sale of bonds rather than equity. There will be two opposing pressures on equity demand. The increased bond rate will have a negative effect while the increase in government expenditures could have a positive effect. Thus, 128 the net result is not clear. E) Whigs;- In an equity-based economy, the open-market operations are conducted in the equity market instead of the bond market (which no longer exists). BESULI_12: The open-market operations are effective under both regimes, and the policy multipliers have the expected signs. In both economies an open-market purchase will increase both output and investment. Overall, we see that the elimination of government bonds does not dramatically alter the ability of the central bank to conduct monetary and fiscal policy. Both monetary and fiscal policy are effective. The surprising result is that in no case did we observe the impact of a policy on the equity-based economy to be more uncertain than the impact of the same policy on the regular economy. To the contrary, for some policies we have more confidence about the response in the equity-based economy compared to the regular economy. 129 NOTES In this section, we are not concerned with policy analysis and as a result, the government sector is not included. The reason we ignore the capital gains is that, in this short term model, expectations are exogenous. Sargent- Henderson also use this assumption in their model. Other variables have the same definitions that were given in Section 1. With this action, we exclude the banking sector altogether. Consequently, we can no longer study the impact of changes in the reserve-requirement ratio, K. The policy impact of changes in K, however, are straight forward. An increase in K is contractionary. The exact formulas for these multipliers are: dV/dV¢=(-1/D*).(1-Cz)/P dV/dG =(-1/D*).[f12.(C3+1)+(1-C2).f13] dY/dG =(-1/D*).[(1/P-f14).(C3+1)+(C4+I1).f13] dY/dV¢=(-1/D*).[(C4+Ii).1/P] By dividend and substitution effects, we are referring to the components of the following derivative: df1/dY=(df1/dq).(dq/dY) + dfi/dY We can derive an upper bound for f12 which results in D*<0. Another type of fiscal policy involves a debt-financed government deficit. In an equity-based economy, this will be equivalent to financing the government deficit by the sale of equity (that the central bank owns). We will compare the effects of debt-financed and equity- financed fiscal policies in a separate appendix. There is a significant body of evidence that consumpton in the United States is not sensitive to the rate of return on financial assets, especially bonds. For a survey of this evidence, see Chapters 3 and 6 of Evans, M.K., Macro Economic Activity New York, Harper & Row, 1969. CEMHER‘Q ISLAMIC BANKING IN PRACTICE Currently in the Muslim world, there are two distinct and parallel approaches to Islamic Banking. Two Muslim countries, Iran and Pakistan, have eliminated their conventional banking systems in favor of complete Islamic banking. In contrast, many other Muslim nations have introduced individual Islamic banks while allowing the conventional banking system to continue. We will review the progress of these competing approaches separately. 4-A. INDEPENDENT ISLAMIC BANKS The first experiments on Islamic banking began in the mid-1950’s. Before that time, the post-colonial leaderships in ‘the Middle East were so preoccupied with secular modernization that Islamic concerns about the interest charge were brushed aside. Most 'of_ these nations had already established Western-style banking institutions. In addition, foreign banks were also active in more developed countries of the region. In Egypt, for example, the British-owned banks began operation as early as 1856. The 130 131 first Egyptian-owned bank (Bank Misr) was established in 1919 by a Cairo financier named Mohammed Talat Harb.1 Similarly, at the same time, financial development was underway in other nations as well. The first attempt to create an Islamic bank was made in Pakistan. Since Pakistan was originally established as an Islamic nation, the religious leaders called for abolition of interest in the early years of independence.2 In that time, the idea was rejected by the leadership because of economic considerations. After a few years, however, a small experimental Islamic bank was established in rural Pakistan. The initial capital was provided by a group of small local land owners who deposited funds in the institution primarily for religious reasons. No interest or profit was paid to these depositors. The bank provided interest-free loans to the poorer land owners for a small administrative charge. Unfortunately, this venture did not survive for long. After a few years, the original enthusiasm diminished and the bank was closed down. A major Idifficulty facing the bank from the start was the shortage of funds. Without paying any interest or profit, it was difficult for the bank to attract depositors. At the same time, the low administrative earnings prevented the bank from paying competitive wages and keeping the staff motivated. 132 The second initiative towards Islamic banking was taken in Egypt in 1963. In this case, a small savings bank was founded by a man named Ahmed Al Nagar in a rural town near Cairo. Originally, the bank had about 1,000 depositors but very soon it gained the trust of the conservative local community and the number of depositors grew to more than 60,000 in three years. While conventional banks were successful in larger towns, they were received with suspicion in rural communities. The success of Mitr Ghams Savings Bank was based on its appeal to the devout Muslim population of these communities. Persons who were hoarding funds or accumulating real assets (because they found the conventional banks un—Islamic) willingly deposited funds in the Mitr Ghams Savings Bank. The operations of this bank were similar to the Islamic Savings Bank of Pakistan. The bank did not charge any interest on loans and did not pay any interest on deposits either. While a portion of loans were borrowed for investment purposes, the bank did not share in the borrowers’ profits. Instead, they only charged a small administrative fee. The bank operated for almost three years.3 These two early attempts in Islamic banking were not investment or profit oriented. Their main objective was to provide interest-free loans to the low income and poor individuals. The lack of a clear alternative to the interest charge was the primary reason for their inability 133 to survive beyond a few years. Their shortcomings were one of the reasons that Islamic scholars proposed profit and loss sharing as the basis of Islamic banking. During the 1970’s, development of Islamic banking took a different direction. Unlike the two savings banks that were described above, the new Islamic banks were oriented toward profitable investments. In 1972, Ahmed Al Nagar, the founder of Mitr Ghams Savings Bank, established a new Islamic bank called Nasser Social Bank. This bank continued to offer many of the services that were offered by the Mitr Ghams Savings Bank. In addition, the Nasser Social Bank allocated a portion of its resources to direct equity investment. While no profit was shared with the depositors, they enjoyed an implicit benefit by having the privilege to borrow funds at no interest charge. The initial capital of nearly 32m was provided by the Egyptian government which has remained the sole owner of the bank. The state support has continued and the paid-up capital of the bank is much larger today.‘ The progress of the Nasser Social Bank was a major source of encouragement for Islamic banking in other countries. Through frequent contacts with other Arab leaders and financiers, Ahmad Al Nagars encouraged them to establish commercial Islamic banks. Be motivated a group of Dubai merchants to establish the Dubai Islamic Bank in 1975.6 He also convinced Prince Mohamad Bin Faisal (son of 134 the late King Faisal of Saudi Arabia) to help establish other Islamic banks in Sudan and Egypt. In 1977, the Faisal Islamic Bank of Egypt and the Faisal Islamic Bank of Sudan were established. The Saudi Arabian private citizens provided 40% of the initial capital for the Faisal Islamic Bank of Sudan and 49% of the initial capital for the Faisal Islamic Bank of Egypt.7 The operations of these banks were much closer to the model of Islamic banking that was described in Chapter 1. Unlike the Mitr Ghams and Nasser Social Banks, they distributed a portion of their profits among depositors and shifted their lending and investment activities from interest-free assistance loans to profitable equity investment and PLS loans. They offered two basic types of accounts: savings accounts that are fully insured but earn no profits and investment accounts that share in the profits and losses of the bank. The investment operations of these banks are very similar to items that were described in Chapter 1. These three banks have been able to survive and compete with regular banks for depositors. The Dubai Islamic Bank has become the largest national Islamic bank with $13 million in paid up capital and nearly $100 million in deposits in 1980.8 Ever since 1975, new Islamic banks similar to the Dubai Islamic Bank have been established in almost every Islamic country and their presence has been accepted by the 135 financial communities of these nations. As expected, Islamic banks have appealed to the devout Muslims more than other groups and their operations have reduced hoarding in money and jewelry. The operation of independent Islamic banks along with regular commercial banks has increased the efficiency of financial systems by adding new and diverse assets without eliminating any of the already existing assets. The negative effects of Islamic banking that were demonstrated in our analysis will only arise when the entire financial system is modified and all interest-paying assets are eliminated. Development ofglgterngtiongl Islamic Banks. During the 1970’s and 80’s, Saudi Arabia provided moral and financial support to Islamic banks more than any other nation. This support went beyond establishing and assisting the independent Islamic banks. The more important contribution of Saudi Arabia was the establishment of two international Islamic banks: The Islamic Development Bank and Dar al-Mall Al-Islami. The Islamic Development Bank (IDB) was established in 1975 by the approval of the 38 participating nations of the Islamic conference. The main objective of this bank was to provide financial capital for industrial and agricultural projects in Islamic nations. A second goal was to promote international trade among Muslim states. The activities of the bank were limited to 136 mechanisms that are allowed in Islam, primarily equity participation and interest-free loans. The original capital for IDB was provided by several oil-exporting Islamic nations; Saudi Arabia contributed 25%. Other major contributers were Libya, United Arab Emirates and Kuwait. In 1981, IDB had more than $1.5 billion in paid- in capital. During its first five years of operation, IDB financed many development and trade projects throughout the Muslim world. Several nations, including Turkey, Pakistan and Sudan, received interest-free loans to finance the import of petroleum products and other commodities (from other Muslim nations).9 Other activities of the IDB included equity participation and leasing. To encourage Islamic banking, IDB invested in national Islamic banks. It also invested in equity projects in many Islamic nations. Leasing out industrial machinery was another scheme used by IDB. The bank leased out refining equipment to Pakistan and machinery to the Turkish Electrical Company. Overall, the Islamic Development Bank played a significant role in popularizing Islamic Banking and providing assistance to low income Islamic nations.1° Dar Al-Mall Al-Islami (Islamic House of Funds) is the second international Islamic bank that was established by Saudi Initiative in 1981 with a paid-in capital of $300 million. The stated objective of the bank was to support 137 development projects in Non-Arab Islamic states such as Malaysia, Sri Lanka, Turkey, Pakistan and others. Most of the depositors and shareholders were attracted from the oil- rich gulf nations. (Nearly 80% of the liabilities of DMI, Dar al-Mall al-Islami are owned by the Arab nations of the Persian Gulf area.) DMI has tried to reduce its dependency on Persian Gulf capital by opening branches in other Muslim states. So far, the operations of DMI have been profitable. The performance of the bank during the 1984-85 financial year, in particular, was impressive. To achieve further diversification, DMI targeted the Muslim nations of Africa and Southeast Asia for future investment. Besides the Islamic Development Bank and Dar al-Mall al-Islami, there were several smaller international banks as well. Some of these banks were headquartered in European capitals, particularly London and Geneva. They were primarily involved in equity investment and foreign trade financing among Arab and European nations. Overall, there are more than 30 Islamic banks currently operating throughout the Muslim world. Many of them have been able to offer attractive profits to their depositors and compete against conventional banks for people’s savings. Their operations have pleased a large number of devout Muslims who were reluctant to use the conventional banks. However, at the same time, some conservative Muslims have 138 raised concern about the long-term effect of these banks. According to these critics, the operation of individual Islamic banks inside the conventional financial system could delay the total transformation of the financial system from regular to Islamic. It was for similar fears that plans for the creation of a pilot Islamic bank in Pakistan (in the late 1970’s) were rejected in favor of a complete Islamization of the entire banking system.11 In the following section, we will review the progress of the Islamic banking systems (as opposed to independent Islamic banks). 4-B. ISLAMIC BANKING SYSTEMS So far only two states, Iran and Pakistan, have established complete Islamic banking systems. The idea, however, is popular in the religious circles of many Islamic states. In Pakistan, the process began in 1981. In the first phase, special corners for Islamic financial transactions were established in every bank. This was followed by the removal of interest-paying assets. The reforms were completed in 1985. The modification of Iran’s banking system began in 1984 and it is expected to be finished within 5 years. Since the Islamic banking systems of Iran and Pakistan are very similar, it would be redundant to review both of them here. Several reviews of the Pakistani Experience have already been published. In 139 contrast, the Islamic banking system of Iran is mostly unknown; therefore, it would be appropriate to briefly review the progress and structure of Iran’s Islamic banking system. The Islamic Banking System Of Iran. In the few years before the 1979 revolution, the Iranian economy was experiencing very rapid growth. The main reason for this expansion was the sudden increase in the oil revenues. The financial system was also growing very rapidly in the same period. The banking institutions of this era, however, were entirely secular. Despite religious opposition, banks were issuing loans and accepting deposits on the basis of interest. After the 1979 Islamic revolution, the new government decided to abolish any economic and social institutions that were unacceptable to Islam. In the economic sector, the banking system became the first target of this reform. At the same time, under popular spressure, the government nationalized the entire banking industry. Having direct control made it easier for the government to implement any future reforms. (In Pakistan also the banks are nationalized.) With regard to the banking system, the goal was to abolish any institutions that involved interest charge and introduce new arrangements that were acceptable to 140 Islam. Since there was no prior experience in Islamic banking, it was clear that the design and implementation of the new system would take some time. To avoid any kind of financial collapse or loss of public confidence in the banking system, it was decided to continue with the old banking institutions until the new program was ready for implementation. Within the central bank, a special task force was established to design the new code of banking laws. Because of the social and political instability that existed in those early years of the revolution. the work of the task force was delayed. The first set of Islamic banking laws were submitted to the Parliament by this task force in 1982. Gradually, the complete codes of Islamic banking were passed within two years. The Islamization process began in the summer of 1984. The interest-paying time and savings deposits were replaced with investment accounts. On the investment and lending side, all the new transactions were based on nonusurious arrangements. Banks continued to receive interest on long-term loans that were issued earlier. It is expected that all of these contracts will and within five years. We will describe the structure of the Iranian banking system below. 141 Depository Accounts. Banks offer two types of depository accounts: 1) The interest-free current accounts and interest- free savings accounts. 2) Short-term and long-term investment accounts. The interest-free deposit accounts are technically the same as demand deposit accounts. They are fully insured and are redeemable upon request. Even though these deposits are not entitled to any regular interest or profitsharing, the banks can occasionally offer prizes to the account holders. The prizes could be cash or durable goods such as radios or irons. The account holders will also be given priority in using other banking services such as receiving loans. The investment accounts are similar to the PLS accounts that were described in Chapter 1. However, no profitsharing is specified. Instead, the bank announces a dividend rate on these accounts. The rate is variable and is supposed to fluctuate with the overall profits of the banking system in each period. The same rate of dividends is paid by all banks. This rate is determined by a special commission within the central bank. The minimum time for short-term accounts is three months and for long-term accounts is one year. In 1984, which was the first year of operation for Islamic Banks, the short- and long-term accounts paid 7.5% and 93 dividend rates, respectively.12 142 Even though the investment accounts are fully insured, the central bank authorities have argued that the return on these accounts is not interest because no fixed rate of dividend is declared in advance. The dividend for each six- month period is declared at the end of that period. The exact method of dividend measurement is not clear. It is unlikely that dividends are linked to the banking profits in the same manner that was described in Chapter 1. It is interesting to note that the dividend rates offered on these accounts are very close to the interest rates that were paid on short- and long-term time deposits by the commercial banks of Iran in years prior to the revolution. (In 1975, the interest rates on savings and time deposits were 7% and 9%, respectively.) On religious grounds, these accounts might be questionable because the principal is fully insured. It was explained earlier that these risks face the possibility of losses. Since the holders of investment accounts do not face any risk of loss, their dividend is equivalent to a variable interest. Indeed, if the dividend rate stays above a certain level for a long period, the public would perceive it as a safe interest with a minimal rate. Such accounts may not be Islamic by this standard, but they would be more efficient than a purely Islamic account which is not fully insured. Since the principal is insured, these accounts will be considered riskless. By offering 143 these accounts, banks can attract the savings of risk—averse individuals. One could expect the public to treat these accounts in the same way as the savings and time deposits that existed before. The Lending ang Investment Activities. To make the lending operations of Islamic banks nonusurious, it was necessary to replace the interest-paying loans with other arrangements. Some of these new mechanisms are derived from the business customs that were common in the early years of Islam. Others were developed over the centuries to circumvent the prohibition of interest. The lending and investment mechanisms of the Iranian Islamic banking system are: l) Interest-Free Loans. These loans are provided to the needy and poor at no interest for necessary expenses such as the treatment of illness or repair of damaged property. These loans are also granted to small businessmen in small towns and villages. The primary criteria for interest-free loans is proof of need. There is, however, an upper limit on the size of these loans. The maximum amount of interest-free loans for business and industry is 5,000,000 Iranian Rials. The upper limit for personal need is 500,000 Rials. Another limitation is that, collectively, the interest-free loans should not constitute more than 10% of the assets of the banking industry. This sum should also 144 be less than or equal to the interest-free deposit funds that banks receive from the public. This implies that all the funds collected by banks from investment accounts will be invested in profitable projects. No part of these funds is used for interest-free loans. 2) TheAAgguity Partnership. Banks are allowed to provide short- and long-term credit to businesses on an equity basis. There are three different types of equity arrangements available to the banks: a) Direct partnership between bank and businesses. b) Equity stock ownership in corporations. c) Direct investment by banks without any partners. The partnership between the bank and businesses is specially designed for short-term projects. It could only be used in cases where the project is expected to be completed within one year. Only in special cases could the time limit be extended to three years. Under a partnership, the bank can at most provide 80% of the capital that is needed for a project. The equity stock partnership is designed for longer term projects of existing corporations. Banks can provide capital to these corporations by purchasing up to 49% of their total outstanding stocks. The 49% upper limit is designed to curtail any bank control of corporations. The banks can sell the stocks to the public at a future date. In this function; Islamic banks are operating similarly to the investment banks in the West. 145 They purchase the newly issued stocks of corporations and then gradually sell them to the public. 3) Advance Purchase. In this arrangement, the bank purchases the product of a productive unit before it is ready. The unit then can use the funds to pay for the required working capital. The bank can resell the product after receiving it. 4) Price Mark-up Resale. If an industrial unit needs funds for the purchase of machinery and equipment, the price mark-up mechanism is used. In this scheme, the bank purchases a particular tool that was requested by the unit and resells it to that unit at a higher price. In exchange for the profit, the bank allows the unit to pay the cost on an installment basis. A similar mechanism could be applied to the sale of existing houses where the bank buys a house on behalf of a costumer and resells it to him for a higher price on an installment basis. 5) gent To Own. Banks can buy productive equipment and structures and rent them to the public on the condition that the renter will assume ownership of the item after paying rent for a certain period. 6) Crop Sharing. In the area of agriculture, besides the above-mentioned financing schemes, banks can own land and enter into crop-sharing agreements with peasants. In addition to land, banks can provide other items (such as 146 fertilizers and transportation) which are needed for farming. Overall, the profit-oriented lending operations of Islamic banks fall under two categories. a) The equity arrangements (Items 2 and 6 in above list) b) Price mark-up schemes (Items 3,4 and 5) The equity-based arrangements are truly nonusurious. In these schemes, the bank does assume some degree of risk as required by religion. In practice, both profits and losses are possible. However, to avoid bad investments, banks can only invest in projects that are expected to generate profits above a minimum rate that is determined by the central bank. While encouraging the banks to be efficient, this law ignores the possibility that more profitable projects might also carry higher risks. If the minimum profitability rate is too high, the bank might be forced to acquire a highly risky portfolio. A better approach would be to put limits on an expected risk as well as the expected profit rate of acceptable projects. While no explicit interest charge is involved in the price mark-up schemes, they are implicitly usurious. The mark-up on the resale price of a tool, when it is resold by the bank to a buyer, can only be explained as the financing cost which is equivalent to the interest charge. The difference between the purchase and resale price will 147 determine the implicit rate of interest. Therefore, from a religious point of view, these schemes will be questionable. On one hand, trade is permited in Islam and the exchange price is a matter of agreement among parties involved. This view makes the price mark-up mechanism acceptable. But, on the other hand, if the interest charge is forbidden, one might expect the price of a commodity to be the same regardless of the method of payment. The price mark—up mechanism contradicts this principle by charging a higher price for deferred payment. Thus, it could be seen as a usurious act. This conflict, however, is purely religious. From an economic efficiency point of view, the mark-up price is justified because the financial capital is productive and there is an opportunity cost to receiving the payment in the future. The availability of price mark-up options will make the Iranian Islamic banks more productive by offering risk- free and low-risk investment channels. Banks can use these options to offset their high-risk equity investments and create diversified portfolios. Indeed, some banks might even prefer these low-risk options to equity investments.15 The experience of Islamic banks in Pakistan reveals that most banks prefer price mark-up schemes to equity-based investments. This has led some officials to question the Islamic nature of that country’s banking system.16 1) 2) 3) 4) 5) 6) 7) 8) 9) 148 NOTES (Chapter 4) This bank was owned by a small group of wealthy merchants and land owners in Cairo. It attracted a large group of depositors from middle and low income classes as well. (See Rodney Wilson page 29.) There was a debate in Pakistan in that time on whether the banning of interest charge should be included in state constitution or not. The proposal was not included. (Maxime Rudinson page 154.) One major reason for its failure was the low salaries that bank employees recieved. The rural location of the bank was also a disincentive to the staff members who prefered to live in larger cities. By 1980 the paid-in capital was $14.3 million. The total assets for the same year were $330.0 million. Source: Wohlers-Scharf, table 12, page 164. The founder and first general manager of Nasser Social Bank. Dubai is a small Arab nation in the Persian Gulf area. See Rodney Wilson page 85. The multinational Islamic banks such as Islamic Development Bank and Dar Al-Mall Al-Islami have much larger financial resources. Islamic Development Bank, for example, has more than $1.5 billion in Paid-in capital. (Wohler5*Scharf, Table 12, page 164.) Islamic Development Bank, Fourth Anual Report, Jaddah 1979, Page 34. 10) 11) 12) 13) 14) 15) 16) 149 In recent years IDB has paid special attention to the African developing nations. Actvities include a leasing conract with a Tunisian-Saudi company for Small projects in Tunisia. The country of Benin has also recieved $5 million in loan and technical assistance from IDB (Source: Arabia, June 1985 page 76.) See ”Report of the Council of Islamic Ideology (Pakistan) in Money and Banking in Islam by Ziauddin Ahmed, Munawar Iqbal, and F. Fahim Khan. Reported in Keyhan Havai, "Negahi-Be Vaz-iatt-e Faaliatha-E Banki" Page 14, July 12, 1985. Ibid. Source: Banking Structure and Sources of Finance in the Middle East, page 15. During the first year of Islamic Banking in Iran (1984) almost 44% of the resources of Islamic Banks were invested in Hire Purchase and Price Mrak-Up contracts while 37% were allocated to various equity arrangements. (Keyhan Havai July 12, 1985, page 14.) Arabia, September 1984 pages 48-49. CONCLUSION In this concluding section, the analytical findings of the previous chapters will be put into perspective, then the implications of these findings for the field of Islamic Economics in practice will be analyzed. Finally, several suggestions for further research on Islamic banking will be offered. The objectives of this research project were two fold. The first goal was to analytically study the consequences of switching from a conventional to an Islamic banking system. This investigation was conducted within two distinct models: one macro-economic model and one micro-economic model. The basic results of these analyses were that at the micro-level elimination of the interest charge will adversely affect the welfare and resource allocation of households. In particular, the more risk-averse persons are forced to assume more risk while the less risk-averse persons are not able to take as much risk as before. The reason behind these adverse developments is that clearly money and risky assets are weak substitutes for the interest-paying riskless asset. So when the interest rate 150 151 is reduced to zero, the risk-averse investor will transfer a fraction of his funds from the riskless to the risky asset. Thus, his total investment in risky assets will increase. At the same time, since the more risk~averse investor will lend a smaller amount at zero interest, the borrower cannot borrow (and consequently take risk) as much as before. The analysis shows that the relatively more risk-averse persons will save less while the less risk-averse individuals will do the opposite. Since each expected rate of return is associated with a higher level of risk under the zero interest rule, for the more risk-averse individual, the opportunity cost of consumption is smaller. Therefore, he is expected to increase his consumption at the expense of savings. The less risk-averse person is not as concerned about risk and under zero interest rate, his borrowing cost will be smaller so, to him, savings and investments will be more attractive under the zero rate of interest. While the savings of the lender and the borrower change in different directions, the net effect on aggregate savings is negative. When switching from positive to the zero interest rate, the net savings is expected to decline. This decline will increase the marginal productivity of capital which leads to a higher rate of return on capital. Similarly, in the macro economic analysis, we were able to demonstrate that aggregate real investment will decline as the interest rate is reduced to zero. In the absence of 152 government bonds, it was assumed that banks invested the funds available to them in the equity market. At the zero interest rate, the savings deposits will become demand deposits. When the interest payments on savings deposits are stopped, people will transfer a portion of their funds from the original savings deposits to equity and money. The total demand for equity declines by the amount of funds that have been transferred from savings deposits into money. The bank demand for equity declines while the direct demand for equity increases. The net effect, however, is a decline in the total demand for equity. Consequently, the level of aggregate investment will decline. The second objective was to gain some insights on the structure and the performance of the Islamic economy itself. The institutions of Islamic banking were described in Chapter 1. We demonstrated that in the absence of the interest charge, Islamic banks will operate similar to mutual funds. The new banking institution to replace interest-based lending is profit and loss sharing. Using Mean/Variance analysis and portfolio theory, we have shown that PLS lending was inferior to lending at zero interest and PLS borrowing was preferred to borrowing at zero interest. 'These findings indicate that, even though there will be many investors who like to borrow PLS loans, they would face a severe shortage of credit because savers are reluctant to lend on the PLS basis. Therefore, with the 153 regular bonds prohibited and the PLS loans rejected by the lenders, the only mode of transaction remaining is equity. Even if banks choose to operate based on the PLS mechanism, the competitive pressure will make these arrangements very similar to equity contracts. Therefore, based on the above reasoning, we did not find it necessary to include the PLS account as an independent asset in the macromodel of the Islamic economy. Also, since all types of bonds are eliminated, the model does not include any bond markets either. The three financial assets included in our model are equity, high- powered money and demand deposits. A unique feature of this model is that the central bank is allowed to hold equity and use equity transactions to alter the supply of credit in the same manner that Western central banks use open-market operations in the bond market. We introduced several tools of monetary and fiscal policy for an Islamic economy. The three basic tools are: l) Open-market intervention in the equity markets by the central bank. 2) The control of the required reserve ratio on demand deposits. 3) A monetized and equity-financed fiscal policy. We have assumed that government debt in an Islamic economy is either monetized or financed by the sale of government-held equity. The reason is that government 154 cannot pay any interest on its debt and the public will be reluctant to purchase the bond at no interest. The only remaining option is for the government to borrow interest- free loans from the central bank. To analyze the effect of these policy instruments, we have applied the method of comparative statics. First, the equations of the model are reduced into two equations representing equilibrium in real and financial sectors, then we totally differentiate these equations with respect to the policy instruments and the endogenous variables. The endogenous variables of our model are real output and the value of equity stocks. The results of the analysis were as expected, the purchase of equity and the reduction in reserve requirements are both expansionary and they increase the level of output and investment. An increase in monetized debt is also expansionary but the effect on equity values is unclear. To further understand the nature of the economic policy in an Islamic economy, we developed a similar model for a regular economy by adding an additional equation for government bonds to our original model of the Islamic economy. After applying a similar comparative static analysis to this model, we were able to compare the effects of these policy instruments on regular and Islamic economies. The results were summarized at the end of Chapter 3. We observed that open-market operations had the 155 expected effects under both regimes (an open—market purchase will increase investment and aggregate demand). A money- financed deficit will be expansionary under Islamic regime. The impact of the same policy under a regular regime will depend on the interaction between the bond market and other markets. If the sensitivity of commodity and equiy markets to the interest rate is relatively small, the policy will be expansionary. A bond-financed deficit will have an indeterminate effect on output under both regimes. Overall, it appears that open-market operations in the equity market are the most effective tools of monetary policy in an Islamic economy. Under an Islamic banking system, the equity market is used for open-market intervention. In practice, however, the central bank could use the PLS accounts of Islamic banks for intervention. As was described earlier, these accounts are similar to mutual fund shares in the Western world. One advantage of using PLS accounts instead of direct involvement in the stock market is that bank portfolios are highly diversified and any change in demand for the PLS accounts (which are related to these portfolios) will have minimal effect on the relative prices of different equity assets. Therefore, using PLS accounts allows the government to control the money supply without any distributional effect in favor of any particular industries or stocks. 156 The welfare effects of interest-charge elimination could be deduced from a basic knowledge of optimization. At the micro level, we know that in a utility maximization problem, imposition of a new restriction will either reduce the maximum utility available or give the same result as before. Since Islamic restriction primarily affects the lenders by eliminating the interest they can receive on loans, they will be clearly worse off. The welfare effect on the borrowers is not clear because, on one hand, they face a quantity restriction on loans and, on the other hand, the rate of return on their investments will be higher. When talking about the welfare effects of Islamic banking however, we must not ignore the impact of religious faith on the preferences of individuals. It could very well be the case that, to the believers the existance of interest-paying assets is disturbing because it indicates disobedience from the commands of Islam. In that case, the elimination of these assets could even increase the utility of this group of Muslims. Some authors such as Rafi Khan have indicated that, under a regular banking regime, some devout Muslims might shy away from the banks which are considered usurious institutions. Be estimates that devout Muslims are hoarding as much as $80 billion in Saudi Arabia. Once an Islamic system is established, these funds will be deposited in banks and channeled into productive investment projects. 157 Therefore, he argues that the level of savings and investment might actually be higher under an Islamic banking regime. This argument could be criticized on several grounds. First of all, there has never been a formal scientific investigation on this issue. Secondly, there is evidence that the majority of people in Muslim nations use the services of the conventional banks without any hesitation. As demonstrated in Rudney Wilson’s book on Middle Eastern Banking, conventional banking in the Arab middle east has been expanding more rapidly than any other region in the world during the past two decades. This growth indicates that a substantial number of people find it acceptable to interact with commercial banks. Most likely, therefore, the number of investors who shy away from regular banks and the size of funds that are hoarded this way is minimal. Besides, the act of hoarding currency and precious metals is a portfolio allocation decision, not an intertemporal one. The monetary authorities could easily offset the effects of hoarding by increasing the supply of credit to the commercial banks. It is the intertemporal decisions of households that affect the rate of investment most significantly. Nevertheless, the issue of religiously motivated hoarding could be an interesting topic for further research in the field of Islamic banking. 158 Our theoretical analysis has led to a number of predictions about the consequences of Islamic banking which were reviewed earlier. How closely these predictions apply to the operation of Islamic banks throughout the Muslim world depends on how similar they are to our theoretical model. The basic assumption of our model is that, under an Islamic banking system, all of the interest-paying assets are eliminated and the remaining financial assets are risky. The negative impact of Islamic banking in our model was a direct result of this assumption. Obviously, in those nations that have established independent Islamic banks without eliminating their regular financial systems, the predictions of our model will not be applicable. This rules out all nations accept for Iran and Pakistan. Iran and Pakistan are the only nations that have modified their entire banking system. The banking systems of these countries, however, do not operate according to the basic assumptions of our model. In these countries, banks can insure the principles of investment accounts (PLS accounts). They also have the right to request insurance and guarantees from their loan customers. In addition, the price mark-up schemes are, to a large extent, risk free. The result is that the Islamic banks of these nations are similar to the conventional banks in many aspects. In contrast to the assumptions of my model, the Islamic banks of Iran and Pakistan are able to arbitrage risk. 159 Consequently, these banking systems are not as inefficient as predicted in our model. The closer they comply with the Islamic requirement, the greater would be the level of inefficiency. This inefficiency, however, might appear tolerable to an extremely religious people. To them it would be a small price to be paid for obedience to Islam. Alternatively, a Muslim people (or their leadership) might be concerned about efficiency in the financial markets and choose a semi-Islamic banking system. Finally, the single most important policy recommendation of this dissertation is that establishing independent Islamic banks without the elimination of conventional banks is more efficient than switching to a complete Islamic banking system. The direction of Islamic banking in the future depends on the performance of these experiments with Islamic banking which are currently underway in Iran and Pakistan. It is also dependent on the political will of the Muslim population in each nation. While certain reforms in the furture are likely, there is no doubt that the notion of Islamic banking itself enjoys considerable support. There are still many unresolved issues and additional research will surely be welcomed. Suggestions For Future Research. Clearly, the volume of research on Islamic economic systems has significantly increased over the past six years. 160 However, there are still many important questions to be analytically investigated. With regard to the impact of Islamic banking on savings and investment, which was the main topic of my research, there is more work to be done. First of all, my research was limited to theoretical analysis. It must be followed by empirical tests. Within a few years, sufficient volume of data on the banking systems of Iran and Pakistan will be available, making such tests feasible. My micro-economic analysis could be improved by replacing the quadratic utility functions with more general, functional forms which do not suffer from the weaknesses attributed to quadratic functions. The results of my model might be sensitive to the choice of the utility function because the quadratic utility function leads to increasing degrees of absolute risk aversion. It must be noted, however, that if a general utility function is used, the comparative static method will be fruitless. The reason is that we will not be able to determine the signs of the parameters which are needed to indicate the direction of change in savings and risk taking. Therefore, with general utility functions, a different method of analysis is required. One possible direction for improving the macro model is to specify the equity and bond markets in more detail in order to capture their differences better. We have already 161 shown some of these differences by specifying the dividend as a function of income while the interest rate is independent of income. Another major difference that could be included is the risk structure. Bondholders have the first claim on a firm’s earnings, thus they are less risky compared to equity. To capture this difference, we must formally incorporate uncertainty in our model. Doing so, however, will make the model more complex. Aside from the topic of this dissertation, there are other issues which are worthy of consideration. The large scale use of PLS arrangements will lead to a number of difficulties. If the lender and the borrower have assymetric information about the concerned project, the borrower might under-report his profits to minimize the lender’s profitshare, Also, one could perceive a situation where a borrower conceals the actual risks of a project in order to make it look more attractive. These questions of moral hazard and adverse selection should be studied empirically to see how Islamic banks deal with these issues. A second interesting topic is the difference between economic stability of a regular and an Islamic economy. Some authors (M. Khan for example) have argued that an Islamic economy would be more stable than a regular economy because savings and investment would be better synchronized. This important issue could be a rich area for further research. APPENDIX A (CHAPTER 2) The Impact of Zero Interest When the Loan Market Fails In this appendix, we study the impact of interest- charge elimination under the assumption of complete loan market failure. The microeconomic analysis of Chapter 4 is based on the assumption that even at zero interest the savings of risk-averse investors are transferred to the less risk-averse individuals by the intermediaries. Therefore, the bond market still exists even though it is in disequilibrium. While I believe that this assumption of partial lending is a realistic description of how the financial system of the Islamic nations will operate, the total failure of the loan market is also worth considering as a possible alternative outcome. We will briefly review the outcomes of the certainty and uncertainty models of Chapter 4 under the assumption that at zero interest no one will agree to lend. The public will keep their savings in the form of idle cash in the safe boxes and there would be a strong demand for loans but no supply. 162 163 A) The Loan Market Failure in the Certainty Framework. The failure of the loan market imposes no new constraints on the risk-averse savers. They will simply keep their savings in a safety box instead of placing it in a bank deposit (which will no longer pay any interest). The failure of the loan market will change the constraint that the borrowers face. The two-person models of sections l-c and l-d will be modified to reflect the no—lending constraint. In model l-C (where no investment option is included), each person must maximize his utility subject to no interest-charge and no borrowing. For person A: Max UA(Ci‘,Cz‘) S.T. C1‘+C2A = C1°A+C2°A 01mm“ For person B: Max U°(C13,Cza) S.T. 013+02° = C1°3+CZ°B C133C1°B Figure A-l shows the allocation under regular regime and the Islamic regime (with no lending). Persons A and B are lender and borrower, respectively. Point E is the equilibrium under regular regime. When the interest rate is suppressed to zero, the optimal allocations must lie on 164 $132. The lender chooses point F. Person B (the borrower) is deprived of any loans so he remains at his original position at point H. He is obviously worse off as is the lender. (Under the partial lending assumption of l-C, the welfare impact on the borrower is indeterminate.) B S! R.‘ ‘- CI B Cl 1 + 6? Figure A-l When the investment opportunities exist but the loan market fails at zero interest, the optimization problem of the saver is the same as the one given in section l—D, but for the borrower, we would have: Max 03(013,C23) S.T. 013+023 = C1°3+K13+K2B C13_<_C1°3+K1B 165 c,B Fig A-Z In figure A-2, the borrower chooses the consumption and investment pattern shown by points E and J. Under zero interest, he wishes to borrow up to point G and invest at point K; but since no borrowing is allowed, he is forced to produce and consume at point F. In this case, the borrower is clearly worse off (compared to a regular capital market). B) The Loan Mgrketgfigilurgggnder Uncertainty Framework. To analyze the general uncertainty model which allows for investment as well as consumption, we will look at the behavior of the risk-averse saver in more detail. In the partial lending model of Chapter 4 (section 2-B), we assume that the risk-averse investors will deposit their savings in the bank even when the interest rate is zero. The banks, in turn, invest these funds or lend them to other investors. In 166 other words, the total savings of both persons is eventually invested. There are no idle savings in this model as demonstrated by the loan market clearing condition (equation 12). Here, we assume an alternative behavior by the savers. They can now put their riskless savings in money or bank deposits which are both risk free (inflation is ignored). As the interest rate on bank deposits declines, the demand for these deposits diminishes until it reaches zero at a zero rate of interest. (This implies that the loan market fails completely at a zero rate of interest.) These investors will substitute money and risky assets for the bank deposits. Figure A-3 compares the supply of loanable funds under partial lending and complete loan market failure. Suer 03> LOANS ro Fig. A-3 167 g1 is the supply of loanable funds when all savings is kept in banks. There is a positive supply of loans at zero interest. g2 is the supply of loanable funds under the alternative assumption. In this case, the loanable funds are not the same as savings. At zero interest rate, the riskless savings of original lenders is positive but the supply of loanable funds is zero. We define two types of savings: idle and active. The portion of savings that is placed in banks is active and the rest which is kept in currency is idle. The active savings are: ZA(W1-Ci‘) Zx = The fraction of total savings kept in the bank deposits. ZA=ZA(FO). This fraction falls to zero as the rate of interest goes to zero. Now the bond market constraint facing the borrowers is: ZA(W1-Ci*)=-(l-Xs)(Wz-C13) 12* The maximization problem of the lender that was given in section 2-B still holds. For the borrower, we have: 168 3’“ ' ’ Max EU9(C1,C23)=Max UB(013,023,3c2) -8 _— S.T. C2=(W2’Cla)(1+FO+XB(P‘FO)) Sc2= (Wz-C13)2.st.5r2 ZA(W1‘CIA)+(1‘XB)(Wz-CIB)Zo When the constraint is binding, ZA=0 and Xa=l. To study the impact of interest-free banking on the behavior of the borrower, we must go through the same procedure that led to the derivation of equations 13 and 14 in section 2-B. Equation 14 will essentially be the same, but since the bond market constraint has been changed, we must derive a replacement for equation 13. Then we will have a two-equation, two-variable system to solve for d(Wz- C1°)/dro and an/dro Totally differentiating equation 12* with respect to re, we get: (l-Xa).d(W2-C13)/dro- (Wz-Cis).dXs/dro= -dZA/dro.(Wi-Ci‘)-ZA.d(W1-C1*)/dro 13‘ From the lender’s behavior, we know that: dZA/dro>0 and d("l‘ClA)/dl‘0>° 169 Therefore, the right hand side of this equation is negative. Then we get: (l-Xs).d(W2-C13)/dro-(W2-C13).an/dro= K’. Since K’0 Moving away from zero interest (in a positive direction) will encourage the (less risk-averse) borrowers to take more risk and reduce total savings. In section 2-B, it was shown that the lender will have lower utility under a zero interest rate. The same result is valid when the loan market fails at zero interest because for him the financial opportunities have not changed. We also saw that the direction of change in the utility of the borrower was unclear. One expects that, under loan market failure at zero interest, the borrower will be worse off compared to the regular loan market. This, however, is not true because there are still two conflicting forces in action. The change in the utility of the borrower is: 170 dUB/dro=an/dro.[dUB/an]- d(Wz—C1B)/dro.[dUB/dC13]+ Eza.(w2-CIB).dF/dro We know that dUB/dC13=0 but dUB/an>0 because X3 is constrained below its optimum value. dUB/dro=an/dro.[dUB/dxa]+U23.(W2-C13).[dF/dro] dUB/an>0, dXs/dro>0 and dFVdro dUB/dro = (+)+(—)=? The direction of change in the utility is unknown because, on one hand, the investor can no longer borrow any funds and, on the other hand, the rate of return on the risky assets is higher. We can only argue that because the borrowing restriction is stronger under the assumption of total market failure, the borrower is more likely to be worse off in this case. APPENDIX B (CHAPTER 2) The P.L.S. Arrangement According to Muslim economists, the Islamic banks will use profit- and loss-sharing arrangements as their main mode of financial transactions. In this appendix, the reaction of lenders and borrowers to the P.L.S. arrangement will be briefly analyzed. As an investment asset, a PLS loan is very similar to equity and the two could be close substitutes for each other. Indeed, every PLS loan is borrowed for investment in a risky project (or a portfolio that consists of several risky projects). As a result, the expected return and variance of a PLS loan is linked to the risk/return characteristics of the project for which it is borrowed. Let’s assume a PLS borrower has 3W of his own and wishes to borrow 3B on a PLS basis to invest in project A that is risky. The expected return and risk of A are K’ and ox, respectively. Let 0o 3.2 X120 173 (The results will not change if a continuous function is used.) Equation B.2 shows that the expected return with PLS borrowing will be larger than without it. The degree of increase in an expected return depends on the profit share of the borrower, q . We must also derive the variance of X. Var(X6 )=2(X1- X)Z.f(X;). After expanding this equation and collecting terms, we get: Var(x')= Var(X)+(qB/W)2.(2X21.f(Xi)-e2)+ [2qB/W].[ZX21.f(Xi)-eX] 3.3 Xi>0 Now we can compare the expected return and risk of PLS borrowing to regular borrowing at zero interest. When borrowing at PLS, the investor is entitled to q% of the profits on the borrowed funds. Therefore, an equivalent portion of profits is obtained by borrowing qB$ from a regular bond market at zero interest. Then the expected return and risk on his profit will be: Xo=(1+qB/W).X and oo=(1+qB/W).ax 3.4 Comparing expected returns, we can see that: e=2X1.f(X1) :9 .2i. Therefore, since X’=X+[qB/W].e and X0=X+[qB/W].X iizfi 3.5 174 To compare the standard deviations, we note the following inequalities: N- 2X21.f(X1) g 2X21.f(Xi) B.6 szo i=1 ‘e>)—( :> e2 > i2 B.7 N - Therefore: 2Xl.f(Xl)-e2 < [2X21f(X1)-X2] = Var(X) B.8 X1>0 F) Similarly: .2 g i2 => zxzi-ei 5 [zxzif(xi)-izj = Var(X) 3.9 From B.4, we have: 020=ozx + [quz/Wz].ozx + [2qB/W].ozx B.10 Using inequalities B.6 and B.7, we can compare the variances of X and X as given by equations B.3 and B.10 . Clearly, we can see that: Var(X')5Var(Xo) 3.11 Inequalities B.5 and B.11 demonstrate that PLS borrowing is more advantageous to regular borrowing at any rate of interest even Zero. Using similar procedures, we can compare the characteristics of PLS lending and regular lending. As explained before, the way PLS loan transactions work is that, if there is a loss, it will be born by the lender; but if there is a profit, it is shared between the lender and the borrower. If Y is the random rate of return on the 175 lended funds and those funds are invested by the borrower in portfolio A which was described earlier, then Y and X will be related by the following equation. (l-q).X if X>0 X if X50 Let T and 0y denote the expected return and risk of random variable Y, respectively. Then we have: - N _ Y: 2Yi.f(Xi) = X-qe B.12 i=1 After rearranging terms and simplification, the variance of Y could be written as: day = Var(x)+q2.[ZX21f(X1)-e2]-2q.[EX21f(X1)-e.X] B.13 X120 10,0 For sake of comparison, assume that the investor wants to use an alternative portfolio which would have the same expected rate of return as PLS lending. If this portfolio consists of dividing the original funds between direct investment in portfolio A and safe cash which does not pay any interest, then his expected return will be ‘T*=(l-p).X where p is the portion kept in cash. With the expected return being the same under both cases, we have: X“ = "Y- => (1-p).X = X‘ 15 and we get szqe => p)q and p=qe/X B.14 176 The variance of Y* is (1-p)202x. We like to compare the variances of Y and Y*. 02y*=02x+p2.02x-2p02x 8.15 To compare 02y* and day as given in equations B.13 and B.15, we use inequalities B.8, B.9 and B.13. Let: H: [ZXzif(Xi)-ez], G: [ZXzif(Xi)-6.X] X G>H 02y* - oz, =q2H-2qG-p2.ozx+2pozx Ozy* - oz, =q2H-2qG+2q(e/X).azx-q2(e/X).02x 02,. - ozy =qz[H-(e/i).02x1+2q[.on-G)1 We know that HgGgon, leading to: l(e/X).ozx-G))g IH- (e/X).ozx| and q2<2q. We conclude: 02" - 03! 5 0 Therefore, PLS lending is an inferior strategy. The above analysis indicates that, under conditions of perfect capital markets, the market for PLS loan transactions will fail. The PLS lender can always do better by investing a portion of PLS loans in the same project for which the funds were borrowed and keeping the rest in cash. Only when small investors face prohibitive transaction and information costs will the PLS loans appear attractive. APPENDIX A (CHAPTER THREE) Debt (Equity) Financed Fiscal Policy in a Regular (Islamic) Economy In this chapter, we studied the fully monetized fiscal deficit. Another option available to the policy makers is to finance the increased government expenditure without increasing the money supply. In a regular economy, the government can finance its deficit by the sale of bonds. In an Islamic economy, the government can borrow from the central bank. The central bank, in turn, could raise the needed funds by the sale of equity. In this appendix, we will derive the multipliers of a debt-financed fiscal policy in a regular economy and an equity-financed fiscal policy in an Islamic economy, respectively. In an equity-based economy, an increase in the deficit without any change in the money supply will require an equivalent sale of government-held equity. Therefore, we will have dG=(-dV¢/P). V; will change every time that G changes: V¢=Vg(G). Since G is measured in real output and V: is measured in nominal money value, we have dVg/dG = P, 177 178 or for every 1 unit increase in equity, $P worth of equity must be sold. An equity-financed deficit will have a wealth effect because at the same time that public equity holdings rise, the central bank gives the money that is raised by the sale of equity to the government for spending, and the money supply stays the same. We will have: W = W($,G,P). Incorporating these changes in the original model of an equity-based economy that was given by equations 6.1-6.3, we get: -?++ +- C(P,Y,G,V) + I(V,P) = Y +?+? V¢(G)/P + f1(P,Y,G,V) = V/P -7... f2(P,Y,G,V) = M/P Totally differentiating the first two equations of this model with respect to Y, V and G gives: dV Ca + 1 A*. dY = -1+f13 . dG A* was given in equation 8.2. We showed that A*'1 had the following signs: 7 +' A*'1 = (l/D*). + + We claim that f13-1<0 because: f13+f23 = 1, f23>0. Then we will have: ( )(?)+ ( )+ dY =1/D*. (+) ?+ G = 1/D*. ( + ) (+)(+) 179 D*0 A. dY ‘ - f13 .dG f13>0 db f2: f23>0 A is given in the left hand side of equation 12.1. In section 3, we showed that: + - .. + + - - f12 - IA}.- A was found to be dependent on f12. We have already developed ALI in Section 3. Solving for the endogenous values, we have: dV C3+1 011 - + + dY = -A-1 £13 .dG= -1/5. + — 032 + .dG db £23 + 023 + + dV _ 011 + (-) + (+) dY = -1/D . (+) + (—) + 032 .dG db (+)+023+() As we can see, both dY/dG and dV/dG are indeterminate and, even when 011 and 032 are determined, the multipliers will still remain undetermined. In the case of a pure bond- financed deficit, the impact on investment is not clear because the policy does not directly affect the equity 181 market. An increase in the supply of bonds increases the real wealth and the rate of interest on bonds at the same time. These two will have offsetting effects on the demand for equity and the net change in the equity values is not clear. The net change in the aggregate demand for output is also unclear because, at the same time that G rises, the bond rate also rises. The higher bond rate will reduce the demand for investment and private consumption. Comparing the results of a debt-financed and equity-financed deficit, we see that there is more certainty about the impact in the case of the equity-financed deficit. We at least know that the investment will decline. APPENDIX B (CHAPTER THREE) A Study of Pure Fiscal Policy and a Pure Increase in the Supply of Money The government’s budget constraint requires that any increase in a government deficit be accompanied by an equivalent increase in the supply of bonds or money. Similarly, an increase in the money supply is always accompanied by an equivalent increase in bonds or government deficit. While a pure increase in money supply or a pure increase in government deficit can never happen without something else also increasing, their study will help us improve our understanding of the feasible policies that were described in this chapter. B-l. E E E. J E 1. . E °I ‘E 1 E Working with the model of an equity-based economy that was developed in section 2, we modify the model to show that an increase in G, in this case, does not change the supplies of money or bonds and, therefore, has no wealth effect. The model becomes: 182 183 ? - + + + - C(Y,P,M,V)+I(V,P)+G:Y 15.A - ? + ? Vg/P+f1( ,Y,M,V) :V/P 15.B - ? + + f2(P,Y,M,V) :M/P 15.0 Totally differentiating the first two equations of the model W.R.T. Y,V,G, we get: C4+Il Cz-l dV -1 . = .dG f14-1/P f12 dY .0 dV f12 1-Cz -1 -f12 = 1/D*. : 1/D*. .dG dY 1/P-f14 C4+I1 0 f14-1/P We have already shown that for this model to be stable, f12 must be negative. f12 is a sufficient condition for D*<0. Therefore, we have: dY/dG=(-)/(-)>0 dV/dGz-fiz/(-) <> 0 If the system is stable, then f12<0 and dV/dG<0. B-Z. WW We repeat the same exercise with the model in section 3 for a regular economy. Since there is no wealth effect, G will no longer appear in the asset-demand functions. The modified model is: 184 +— _?++- C(P,Y,M,V,b)+1(V,P)+G=Y 16.A _?+?_ £1 (P, Y,M,V,b) :V/P 16.B —?++- f2 (P, Y,M,V,b) =M/P 16.C --++? f4(P, Y,M,V,b) =S/(bP) 16.D Totally differentiating the first three equations W.R.T. V,Y,b,G, we get: C4+Il Cz-l C5 dV +1 f24 £22 £25 . dY : - 0 .dG f14-1/P f12 f15 db 0 The multipliers will be: dV 011 - + -1 011 dY = 1/5 + - 022 0 = -1/5 + 3<0 db + 023 + 0 + dV/dG ()0 , dY/dG>0 and db/dG>0 Appendix C (CHAPTER THREE) The Stability of the Macro Models In this appendix, we will use Samuelson’s Correspondence theorem to investigate the stability of the macro models that were developed in this chapter. This investigation shows that, within acceptable range of the parameters, all three models are stable. C-l- We We define the time rate of changes in V and Y as increasing functions of excess money supply and excess demand for output, respectively. dV/dt= 0(M-Md) dY/dt = I’(I-s.Y) 0’ >0 F’>O After replacing Mk, 5 and I from 3.1 and 3.2, we apply a Taylor expansion to these equations and write them in the matrix form: 185 186 [dV/dt [o’(K.f34 + f24)(-1) o’(K.f31 + f12)(-1) {V—Vo dY/dt F’(11-s4.Y) F’(-s1.Y-s) ' Y-Yo C.1 The characteristic equation of this system is: ~o’A12-n -o’A22 =0 0.2 -F’A11 -F’.A12-u We have: A11 = s4.Y- I1 A21 = K.f34 + £24 A12 = 51.Y + S A22 = K.f31 + £21 - + A11 A12 + + is the Jacobian of system 4.1 and u’s are A21 A22 the eigenvalues of equation 0.2. Expanding equation C.2, we get: 112 - u(-a’A11 - I"A12) + F’o’(A21.A12 - A11.A22) =0 0.3 For the system to be stable, the roots of this equation must have negative real parts. The necessary and sufficient conditions for having negative real parts are: (-a’A21 - F’A12) <0 C.4 (A21.A12 - A11.A22)>0 C.5 Since A21 and A12 are both positive, the first inequality is satisfied. The second inequality implies that the determinant of A must be negative. Furthermore, we can give a different interpretation for inequality, C.5. The slopes of IS and LM equations (3.1 and 3.2) are: nylrm -1:1_._LL1+ =-A1_z. dY 15 dIS/dV s4.Y-Ii A11 dil|=-dLM2dI -1.K.121_m_1+ =-122 dY LM dLM/dV K.f34+f24 A21 187 Manipulating inequality C.5, we have: A21.A12 > A11.A22 :: -A12/A11>-A22/A21 In other words, for stability, the IS curve must be steeper than the LM curve. C-Z, =.'_' ._ ,- on: O, 1, o ’ -:a ‘q - .,o For the model that was developed in section two, we define the time rates of change of the endogenous variables, V and Y, as increasing functions of excess demands for equities and commodities, respectively. dV/dt o(Vd-V) o’>0 0(0) 0 dY/dt F(C+I+G-Y) F’>0 I(O) 0 Applying Taylor expansion to these differential equations around the equilibrium values, we get: dV/dt o’(f14 - l/P) o’fiz V—Vo [dY/dt} - [r’(04+11) r'(02-1)] Y-Yo] The characteristic equation is dV/dt c’(f14 - 1/P)-u a’fiz V-Vo [dY/dt] _ [F’(C4+Il) F’(Cz-1)-u] Y-Yo] - 0 or uz-(a’(f14-1/P)+F’(Ca-1)).u + a’(f14-1/P).F’(Cz-1) - a’F’(C4+Ii).f12=0 The roots of this equation must have negative real parts in order for the system to be stable. The necessary and sufficient conditions for having negative real roots are: 188 1) o’(f14-1/P)+F’(Cz-1)0 We have already shown in section 2 that (f14-1/P)<0 and (Cz-l)<0, so the first equation is satisfied. f12<0 is a sufficient condition for the second inequality to hold. In general, we can write the second condition as: '(C2-1)/(C4+Il) > -f12/(f14-1/P) From equations 7.1 and 7.2, we can drive the lepes of the IS and LM equations: fig, : - d|§£dx : - - >0 dY IS dIS/dV C4+Il 01 =-0mmx =-_f1_2_ <>0 dY LM dLM/dV f14'l/P Therefore, a necessary condition for stability is for the IS curve to be steeper than the LM curve in a (Y,V) graph. Finally, it must be noted that an equivalent condition for stability is that the determinant must be negative. C-3. WW For the regular model in section 3, we investigate stability by defining the following three ‘differential equations. dV/dt = d(Vn-V) o'>0 6(0) = 0 dY/dt = T(C+I+G-Y) T’>0 I(O) = 0 db/dt = t(-M/P + f2) t’>0 t(0) = 0 Applying Taylor expansion, we get: 189 dV/dt f14-1/P f12 f15' V-Vo V-Vo dY/dt = C4+I1 C2-1 Cs Y-Yo = A* Y-Yo C.4 db/dt £24 £22 f25 M-Mo M-Mo The characteristic equation of C.4 is: 0’(f14-1/P)-n o’fzz o’.f25 (A*-nII = T’(C4+Ii) T’(Cz-1)-n T’.Cs = 0 t’.£24 t’.f22 t’.f25-n According to Samuelson’s correspondence theorem, the model will be stable if the principle minors of matrix A* alternate in sign as follows. £14-1/P f12 (f14-1/P|<0 , >0 C4+I1 Cz-l f14-1/P f12 f15 C4+I1 C2-1 Cs <0 £24 £22 £25 The last determinant is the same as D*; therefore, D*<0 is a necessary condition for stability of the model. BIBLIOGRAPHY [‘0 10. BIBLIOGRAPHY Abu Saud, Mahmud. "Interest-Free Banking", Mimio 164p. paper presented at the First International Conference on Islamic Economics, Mecca (Saudi Arabia) (1976). "The Economic Order Within the General Conception of the Islamic Way of Life", Islamic Review, London, Vol. 55, No. 2 and 3, 24-26 and 11-24. ‘ Ahmad, Sheik Mahmud. "Interest and Unemployment", Islamic Studies, Islamabad (Pakistan), Vol.8, No.1, 9- 46. Ecanamics of'lslam: A comparative Study. Lahore (Pakistan), Mahmud Ashraf, XV (1972), Al-Araby, M. A. "Contemporary Bank Transactions and Islamic Views Thereon", Islamic Thought (Aligarh) ll(3,4) (July, 1967), 10-43. Al-Jarhi, M. A. "A Monetary and Financial Structure for an Interest-Free Economy: Institutions, Mechanism and Pol icy" , Money and Banking in Islam Ed. by Ahmed, Z. ; Iqbal, M.; Khan, M. F.; Published by the Institute for Policy Studies in Islamabad (Pakistan) (1983) 69-87. "The Relative Efficiency of an Interest- Free Economy: The Fiat Money Case", Studies in Islamic Economics, Edited by Khurshid Ahmed. Published by the Islamic Foundation, Liecester, The U.K., (1980) 85-118. Al-Sadr, Baqir. Al—Bank Al—la Rabavi fi’l-Islam (Interest-free Bank in Islam), in Arabic. Urdu translation by Ali Javadi, Islamic Bank. Bombay, Jamali Publications, (1974). Iqtisaduna (Our Economy), Beirut, Daral- Fikr (1968), 2V, 694p. Alchian, A. A. "The Rate of Interest, Fisher’s Rate of Return, and Keyenes’ Internal Rate of Return", mmyiamw Economic Review, Vol. 45, 938—943. 190 ll. 12. 13. 14. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 191 Allen, D. "Finance: A Theoretical Introduction", St. Martin’s Press, New York (1983). Arrow, K. J. "Some Aspects of the Theory of Riskbearing", Helsinki (1956). Awsaf, Ali. "The Political Economy of Islamic State", Ph.D. Thesis, University of Southern California (1970) 280p. Baily, M. "Formal Criteria for Investment Decisions", Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXVII (Oct. , 1959) 476-488. Benavie, A. "Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Two-Sector Keynesian Model", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, (1976) 63-84 (8). Boskin, M. J. "Taxation, Saving and the Rate of Interest", Journal of Political Economy, 86, 83-827 (April, 1978). Brainard, W. and Tobin, J. "Financial Intermediaries and the Effectiveness of Monetary Control", .mmwdcan Economic Review (May, 1963) 383—400. Chapra, M. "Monetary Policy in Islamic Economy", Mbnev and Banking in Islam, edited by Ahmed, Z. ; Iqbal, M. ; Khan, M. F., published by the Institute of Policy Studies, (1983), 27-46. Famma, E. F. and Miller, M. H. "The Theory of Finance", Holt-Rinehart-Winston, Inc. (1972). Farid, "Is Interest Obsolete?", Voice of Islam, Karachi (Pakistan), Vol.13, No.10, (July, 1964), 495-502. Fisher, I. "The Theory of Interest", MacMillan, New York (1930). Green, T. L. "Corporation Finance", Putnam, New York (1897). Hamidullah, M. "Chiers do 1’I.S.E.A.", Suppl. No. 120 (Series V, No.3) (Dec., 1961) 35. Hassan, Imam. "The Welfare Cost of Interest Rate Ceilings in Developing Countries: A General Equilibrium A p p r o a c h " , New Bevel opmen ts in Applied General Equilibrium Analysis. Edited by John Piggot and John Whalley, Cambridge University Press, (1985). to 01 to O“) 28. 29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. 37. 38. 39. 192 Hershliefer, J. "On the Theory of the Optimal Investment Decision" , Journal of Political Economy, Vol. LXVI, (August, 1958) 329-352. . "Investment, Interest and Capital", Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J. (1970), Chapters 2—4. Hunt, P. and Williams, C. M. "Case Problems in Finance", Irwin, Chicago (1949). Imadi, Tamanna, "Riba va Bai" (Interest and Trade), Fikro-Nazar Islamabad (Pakistan), Vol.2, No.7, 429-434. Irshad, S. A. "Bila Sud Bankari" (Interest-Free Banking), Karachi, Pakistan, Published by Maktaka Tehrik-i-Musawat (1965). Jorgenson, D.W. "Capital Theory and Investment Behavior" , American Economic Review, (May, 1963) 247- 257. Kahf, Monzar. "A Contribution to the Study of the Economics of Islam", University of Utah, S.L.C, July 1973. 110p. Mimeo. Khan, M. A. "Theory of Employment in Islam", Islamic Literature. Lahore (Pakistan), Vol. XIV, No.4, (April, 1968), 5-16. "International Monetary Crisis: Causes and Cure", The criterion, Karachi (Pakistan), Vol. 6, No.2, 5-19. "Islamic Ma,eeshat men bankour Bachten", (Savings and Banks in Islamic Economy). Cheragh-e-Rah, Karachi, Vol. 19, No.5-6, (May-June, 1965) 63-83. . "Issues in Islamic Economics", Islamic Publications LTD, Lahore (Pakistan) (1983). Khan, Mohsin. "Islamic Interest-Free Banking", IJmii StaffPapers, (June, 1986) 1-27. Khan, Rafi. "A Profit- and Loss-Sharing Banking System", Ph.D. Thesis, University of Michigan (1982). Kaufman, G. "The U.S. Financial System: Money, Markets and Institutions. The Second Edition", Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, N.J. (1983). Knight, F. H. "Risk, Uncertainty and Profits", Houghton Mifflin, Boston and New York, (1921). 40. 41. 42. 43. 44. 45. 46. 47. 48. 49. 50. 51. 52. 53. 193 Kotlikoff and Summers. "The Role of Intergenerational Transfers in Aggregate Capital accumulations", .Rnuwal of Political Economy, 89, (1981) 706-732. Mannan, M. A. "Islamic Economics", Lahore (Pakistan), Sh. M. Ashraf (1970). Markovitz, H. M. "Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments", Wiley, New York (1951). "Portfolio Selection", Journal of Finance, 7(1), (March, 1952) 77-91. Maududi, A. A. "Sud", (Interest), Lahore (Pakistan), Islamic Publications (1961) . . "Mu’ashiyate-Islam", (Islamic Economics), Islamic Publications, Ed: K. Ahmed, Lahores (1969). Mazhar, Farida and Thorn, Philip. "Banking Structure and Sources of Finance in the Middle East", London, Bankers Research Unit, (1975). Mettwally, M. M. "Macroeconomic Models of Islamic Doctrine", J.K. Publishers, London, (1981). Modigliani, F. and Brumberg, R. "Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross- Section Data", Post—Keynesian Economics, K. Kurihita, Ed., New Brunswick, (1954). Najjar, Ahmed. "Banks Without Interest as a Strategy for Economic and Social Development of Muslim Countries", Jeddah (Saudi Arabia), Jami’at a1 malik Abd al-Aziz, (1972). Paidar, Habibollah. "Bardashti dar bareye Malekiyat, Kar va Sarmayeh az didgahe Islam (Some Insights on Ownership, Work and Capital from the Islamic Point of View)", Published by Daftar-e-Nashr-e Farhang Islami (in Farsi), Tehran, Iran (1977). Pervez, G. A. "Quranic Economicsz, Lahore (Pakistan), Quranic Research Center, n.d., 24p. Phalwarawi, M. J. "Sud Khari Ki Qismen (Types of Interest)", Thaqafat, Lahore (Pakistan) Vol. 4, No. 3, 29-37. Pratt, J. W. "Risk Aversion in Small and Large", Econometrica 32, (January-April, 1964) 122-136. 54. 55. 56. 57. 58. 59. 60. 61. 62. 63. 64. 65. 66. 194 Qureshi, A. 1. "Islam and the Theory of Interest with an Introduction by Syed Sulaiman Nadvi", Lahore (Pakistan), Mohammad Ashraf XXIV. Rahman, Fazalur. "Riba and Interest", Islamic Studies, Karachi (Pakistan), Vol. 3, No. 1, 1—43. "Commercial Interest ki fighi Haithiyyat ka Tangidi Ja’iza" (A Critical Appraisal of the Jurisdictal Position of Commercial Interest)", Burhan, Delhi (India), Vol.48. Rudinson, Maxime. "Islam and Capitalism (English Trans. by Brian Pierce)", Penguin Books Ltd., London (1974). Samuelson, P.A. "Foundations of Economic Analysis", Harvard University Press, Cambridge, (1963). Shafi, Mufti Muhammad. "Mas’ala Sud (The Question of Interest)", Karachi (Pakistan), Idaratul Ma’arif, (1390 A.H.). Shah, Syed Yaqub. "Chand Mu’ashi Masa’il aur Islam (Islam and Some Economic Problems)", Lahore (Pakistan), Idara Thaqafat-e-Islamia, (1967). Sharpe, W. F. "Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium Under Conditions of Risk", Journal of Finance, 29(3), (September, 1964) 425-442. Sheikh, N. A. "Islami dastur and Islami Iqtisadiyat ke chand pahlu (Some Aspects of Islamic Costitution and Islamic Economics)", Karachi, Pakistan, (1959) 96-ff. "Some Aspects of the Constitution and Economics of Islam"; Woking, England. "The Woking Mission and Literary Trust", (1967) 139-225. Siddiqui, Mazharudin. "Sud ka mas’ala (The Question of Interest)", Thaqafat, Lahore (Pakistan), Vol. 4, No. 5, 52-62. Siddiqui, M. N. "Ghair Sud Bankari (InteresteFree Banking) " , Lahore (Pakistan), Islamic Publications, 2 Volumes, (1968). Siddiqui, Na’im. "Islamic usul par banking (Banking According to Islamic Principals)", Chiragh-e-Rah, Karachi (Pakistan), 1(11), (November) 48:60-64:1(12), (December) 48:24-28. (In Urdu) 67. 68. 69. 70. 71. 72. 73. 74. 195 AlflTahawi, Ibrahim. "Al-iqtisad al-Islami Madhhaban va Nizaman Va dirasah muqaranah (Islamic Economics - A School of Thought and a System: A Comparative Study)", Cairo (Egypt), Majma’al- Buhuth al-Islamiyah, (1974), 2 Vols., 616,400p. (In Arabic) Taleghani, Seyed Mahmood. "Society and Economics in Islam", Mizan Press, Berkeley, (1982). Tobin, James. "A General Equilibrium Approach to M o n e t a r y t h e o r y " , Journal of Money (.‘redi t and Ban/ring, (Feb., 1969), 15-29. Ulgener, Sabir.F. "Monetary Conditions of Economic Growth and the Islamic Concept of Interest", [shade fibvhmg London, Vol. 55, No. 2, (Feb., 1967) 11-14. Uzair, M. "Some Conceptual and Practical Aspects of Interest-Free Banking", Studies in Islamic Economics, Ed. K. Ahmed. Published by The Islamic Foundation, Leicester, U.K., (1980). Viner, J. "Religious Thought and Economic Society", Edited by Melitz, J. and Winch, D., Duke University Press, Durham, North Carolina, (1978). Wilson, Rodney. "Banking and Finance in the Arab Middle East", St. Martin,s Press, New York, (1983). Wohlers-Scharf, Traute. "Arab and Islamic Banks: New Business Partners for Developing Countries", OECD Publications Center, (1983). "I11111111111111s