AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE CONTEXT OF FARM STRUCTURE CHANGE IN ZAMBIA By Chewe Nkonde A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Community, Agriculture, Recreation and Resource Studies—Doctor of Philosophy 2017 ABSTRACT AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE CONTEXT OF FARM STRUCTURE CHANGE IN ZAMBIA By Chewe Nkonde The rise of domestic medium-scale investor farms (holdings between 5 and 100 hectares) is ushering in a change in farm structure that perhaps signals an alternative pathway to agricultural development in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). This dissertation examines this change and what it implies for agricultural development in the region through three standalone but closely linked essays using the case of Zambia. The first essay examines the causes and consequences of the rise of domestic mediumscale investor farms in Zambia using a mixed-methods approach. By locating the study within the broader political economy and new institutional economics literature, the study gleans some important findings. Results show that a positive change in society’s perception of farming, a change in enforcement of informal rules of land governance, and unintended consequences of public spending agricultural support programs have played a pivotal role in farm structure change. In addition, farm structure change has been associated with agricultural land concentration, a growing informal land rental and sales market and a skewed level of agricultural commercialization. The second essay re-examines the farm size – productivity relationship hypothesis in the context of farm structure change using a comprehensive set of productivity indicators and a wide range of farm sizes. Results show that the IR hypothesis is not consistently upheld across alternative indicators of productivity. While the study finds that small-scale farms are more productive when the outcome variable is either land productivity or cost of staple food production per metric ton produced, relatively larger farms have higher labor productivity. Relaxing the constant returns to scale assumption helps to isolate sources of productivity differences between less than five-hectare farms and those above five hectares. The third essay investigates recent trends in agricultural mechanization use, its effects on agricultural household production and the factors contributing to the rise of mechanization initiatives in Zambia. Results show that mechanization use for land preparation has remained low and stagnant. For users, its effects on cropland expansion have been positive but this has not translated into net gains in crop productivity. The study shows that actors on the supply side have become active in promoting agricultural mechanization. On the demand side, however, the level of mechanization use has remained low in part because the changes in the rental rates for mechanization relative to agricultural labor costs have probably not changed to a level that induces an unequivocal shift to labor saving technologies such as mechanization. Three main conclusions are drawn from this dissertation research. First, in order to achieve agricultural development that is broad-based and inclusive, policy strategies should address inequalities in land access, enhance a more inclusive formalization of land ownership and continue to support small-scale agriculture production. Second, findings on the relationship between productivity and operated farm size, while important, should not be the decisive factor in guiding agricultural development and land policies in SSA because there are many other important considerations. Third, this research demonstrates that if identified pitfalls of mechanization initiatives are not quickly addressed, sustainability of these initiatives may be compromised. Copyright by CHEWE NKONDE 2017 In loving memory of Ena Manda Nkonde. v ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS My doctoral studies journey would not have come to its successful completion without the unwavering support, encouragement and guidance of a number of people. First and foremost, I would like to recognize and appreciate each member of my PhD guidance committee—Dr. Robert Richardson, Dr. John Kerr, Dr. Maria Claudia Lopez and Dr. Thomas Jayne—who contributed immensely to my scholarly development while I was at Michigan State University (MSU). To Robby, thank you for your guidance and effective leadership throughout the last three years. Your critical review of my work has made me a better researcher and my sincere hope is that we will continue to collaborate beyond this dissertation research. To John, you played a pivotal role in strengthening my scholarship especially during the time I took your course: Foundations of Community Sustainability. I learned a lot from the way you quickly responded and gave insightful feedback to students’ work. Maria Claudia, thank you for accepting to be on my committee and for sharing literature and critical insights on institutions and the critical role they play in development. And Thom, I cannot thank you enough for the important role you have played in my career development. You faithfully supported my research assistantship position, which catered for my tuition, living and medical expenses for the entire duration of my stay in the U.S. It is, however, the research experience that I gained from being part of your team that I will forever cherish. Zikomo kwambiri!! I would also like to acknowledge the support of Dr. Scott Loveridge, Dr. Scott Swinton, Dr. Bob Myers, Dr. Nicole Mason and other members of faculty in the Departments of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics (AFRE) and Community Sustainability (CSUS). vi During my time at MSU, I was blessed to meet a number of very good people who I am now proud to call friends. Because I run the risk of forgetting somebody’s name, I will not list the names of fellow graduate students, members of staff and other friends in and around the Greater Lansing community. To all of you (you know yourselves), I say thank you guys. You made my time in East Lansing and Michigan much more enjoyable than I had initially envisaged. I am indebted to my employers, the University of Zambia, for granting me study leave for five (5) years to enable me pursue my PhD studies. Special thanks also go to Mr. Chance Kabaghe and his entire team of directors, researchers and support staff at the Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI) for allowing me to use their data and office space during my dissertation research. I would also like to thank the Borlaug LEAP fellowship, and in particular Ms. Susan Johnson, for funding my qualitative field research and providing me an opportunity to do my internship at the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) in Washington DC under the mentorship of Dr. Frank Place. Finally, I would like to thank my parents who continued to believe in me. Your first-born son is now a PhD, congratulations Mr. and Mrs. Nkonde! To my mother in law Ms. Sylvia Mudenda, aka MIL, thank you for your love and for taking care of our two oldest sons while both Ntombi and I were busy burning the midnight oil studying. I honestly cannot imagine how we would have done this without you. To my dear wife Ntombi, you still remain the epitome of beauty, elegance and intelligence. Thank you for your support, love and constant reminder that I could do this. To my sons—Penjani, Tabiso and Aiden—who have had to endure my absence, I hope to make it up to you moving forward. I love you boys. To crown it all, I would like to thank God for his presence throughout this journey even when I had a lot of doubts. vii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ......................................................................................................................... xi LIST OF FIGURES ..................................................................................................................... xiii KEY TO ABBREVIATIONS ...................................................................................................... xiv CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................... 1 REFERENCES ............................................................................................................................... 7 CHAPTER 2: THE RISE OF DOMESTIC MEDIUM-SCALE FARMS IN ZAMBIA: CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES ............................................................................................................. 10 2.1. Introduction ................................................................................................................... 10 2.2. Literature review ........................................................................................................... 13 2.2.1. Small-scale agriculture: opportunities and challenges .......................................... 13 2.2.2. Farm structure change in SSA: empirical insights and gaps ................................. 15 2.2.3. Agricultural transformation and political economy of institutions ....................... 16 2.2.4. Farm structure change in the context of land institutions in Zambia .................... 19 2.3. Data and methods .......................................................................................................... 23 2.3.1. Phase 1: quantitative data collection ..................................................................... 24 2.3.2. Phase 2: qualitative data collection ....................................................................... 27 2.3.2.1. Farmer in-depth interviews ............................................................................... 27 2.3.2.2. Community leader in-depth interviews ............................................................. 28 2.3.2.3. Interviews with national-level stakeholders...................................................... 28 2.3.3. Data analysis ......................................................................................................... 28 2.3.3.1. Quantitative data analysis ................................................................................. 28 2.3.3.2. Qualitative data analysis ................................................................................... 29 2.4. Results and discussion .................................................................................................. 30 2.4.1. Perceived causes of farm structure change ........................................................... 30 2.4.1.1. Change in society’s perception of agriculture .................................................. 30 2.4.1.2. Changes in enforcement of informal rules of land governance ........................ 32 2.4.1.3. Unintended consequences of agricultural subsidy programs ............................ 34 2.4.2. Characterizing farm structure change in Zambia .................................................. 36 2.4.2.1. Nature of change in farm structure ................................................................... 37 2.4.2.2. Characteristics of medium-scale farms ............................................................. 40 2.4.2.3. Agricultural land ownership by urban-based households ................................. 43 2.4.3. Agricultural land use in the context of farm structure change .............................. 45 2.4.4. Land titling and markets in the context of farm structure change ........................ 49 2.4.4.1 Extent of land titling ........................................................................................ 49 2.4.4.2. Extent of participation in land markets ............................................................ 53 2.4.5. Level of agricultural commercialization ............................................................... 58 2.5. Conclusions and policy implications ............................................................................ 62 APPENDIX ................................................................................................................................... 65 viii REFERENCES ............................................................................................................................. 79 CHAPTER 3: REVISITING THE INVERSE FARM SIZE-PRODUCTIVITY RELATIONSHIP: A CASE STUDY OF ZAMBIA ................................................................................................... 86 3.1. Introduction and background ........................................................................................ 86 3.2. Data and methods .......................................................................................................... 95 3.2.1. Computation of productivity indicators ................................................................ 98 3.2.2. Empirical framework and estimation strategy .................................................... 102 3.3. Results and discussion ............................................................................................... 107 3.3.1. Descriptive results ............................................................................................... 107 3.3.2. Testing the IR with alternative productivity measures over a wide range of farms . ........................................................................................................................... 118 3.3.3. Understanding productivity differences across farm sizes ................................. 135 3.4. Conclusions and implications for policy.................................................................... 142 APPENDIX ................................................................................................................................. 146 REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................... 149 CHAPTER 4: AGRICULTURAL MECHANIZATION IN ZAMBIA: TRENDS AND EFFECTS ON HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION........................................................................................... 154 4.1. Introduction ................................................................................................................ 154 4.2. Background ................................................................................................................ 157 4.2.1. Agricultural mechanization in SSA and Zambia: historical perspective ............ 157 4.2.2. Agricultural mechanization in SSA and Zambia: recent developments ............. 160 4.3. Data and methods ...................................................................................................... 162 4.3.1. Phase 1: quantitative data collection ................................................................... 163 4.3.2. Phase 2: qualitative data collection ..................................................................... 165 4.3.2.1. Farmer in-depth interviews ............................................................................. 166 4.3.2.2. Community leader in-depth interviews ........................................................... 166 4.3.2.3. Interviews with national-level stakeholders.................................................... 167 4.3.2.4. Interviews of mechanization service providers............................................... 167 4.3.3. Data analysis ...................................................................................................... 168 4.3.3.1. RQ1: Quantitative analysis of trends in mechanization use and tractor hiring services ......................................................................................................................... 168 4.3.3.2. RQ2: Quantitative analysis of effects of mechanization on household level production ....................................................................................................................... 168 4.3.3.3. RQ3: Quantitative analysis of the rise of agricultural mechanization services .... ......................................................................................................................... 172 4.3.3.4. Qualitative data analysis ................................................................................. 173 4.4. Results and discussion ............................................................................................... 174 4.4.1. Trends in agricultural mechanization use and tractor hiring services ................. 174 4.4.1.1. Mechanization use of small- and medium-scale farmers by province ............ 174 4.4.1.2. Mechanization use of medium-scale farmers by selected districts ................. 175 4.4.1.3. Tractor use per area cultivated in Zambia....................................................... 177 4.4.1.4. Demographic and production characteristics of users versus non-users of mechanization ................................................................................................................. 178 4.4.1.5. Access to and provision of tractor hiring services in selected districts .......... 180 ix 4.4.2. Effects of mechanization on area cultivated and net value of crop production .. 183 4.4.2.1. Effects of mechanization on area cultivated ................................................... 184 4.4.2.2. Effect of mechanization on net value of crop production per hectare ............ 189 4.4.3. Explaining the rise of agricultural mechanization services in Zambia ............... 192 4.4.3.1. Factor price ratios: are they changing enough to induce demand for mechanization? ............................................................................................................... 193 4.4.3.2. Insights from supply side actors and their role in the rise in mechanization .. 195 4.4.3.2.1. Drivers of current mechanization initiatives........................................... 195 4.4.3.2.2. Performance of these initiatives .............................................................. 196 4.4.3.2.3. Constraints .............................................................................................. 196 4.4.3.2.4. Summary .................................................................................................. 197 4.5. Conclusions and recommendations............................................................................. 198 REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................... 202 CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSIONS ................................................................................................. 206 x LIST OF TABLES Table 1: Changes in farm structure among small- and medium-scale farmers in Zambia (2001 – 2015) based on official national survey data ........................................................................ 39 Table 2: Demographic characteristics of medium–scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia by mode of land acquisition ....................................................................................................... 41 Table 3: Summary statistics of agricultural land ownership of urban based households in Zambia (2007 – 2013/14) ................................................................................................................... 44 Table 4: Comparison of cultivated and uncultivated agricultural land across landholding size categories in Zambia (2012 – 2015) ..................................................................................... 45 Table 5: Characteristics of uncultivated land by medium-scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia .................................................................................................................................. 46 Table 6: Extent of land titling by small- and medium-scale farmers in Zambia by landholding size categories ....................................................................................................................... 51 Table 7: Maize production in Zambia by landholding size categories ......................................... 60 Table 8: Marketed maize output in Zambia by landholding size categories ................................ 60 Table 9: Gross value of production (crops only) in Zambia by landholding size categories ....... 61 Table 10: Gross value of marketed crops in Zambia by landholding size categories................... 61 Table 11: Proportion of farms in Zambia by landholding size categories .................................... 62 Table 12: Productivity measures and farm sizes in selected past IR studies ................................ 90 Table 13: Variable explanation ................................................................................................... 103 Table 14: Demographic, land, and input use characteristics by landholding size categories ..... 108 Table 15: Crop production characteristics of main crop categories by landholding size categories ............................................................................................................................................. 112 Table 16: Crop production costs and productivity measures by landholding size categories .... 115 Table 17: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and net value of crop production per hectare .................................................................................. 120 xi Table 18: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and net value of crop production per family labor/total labor day .................................................. 124 Table 19: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and cost of maize production per metric ton ......................................................................................... 128 Table 20: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and total factor productivity............................................................................................................... 132 Table 21: Summary of key findings for the relationship between each measure of productivity and operated farm size ........................................................................................................ 135 Table 22: Production function estimates used for TFP estimation ............................................. 148 Table 23: Tractor use per thousand hectares cultivated in Zambia ............................................ 177 Table 24: Comparison of demographic and agricultural production characteristics of households using mechanization versus non-users over a three-year period ........................................ 179 Table 25: Access to and provision of tractor hiring services among medium-scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia ................................................................................................ 181 Table 26: Comparison of means between users and non-users of mechanization among mediumscale farmers in selected districts of Zambia ...................................................................... 184 Table 27: Full information maximum likelihood estimates of the endogenous switching regression for area cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users ........................ 186 Table 28: Expected log of hectares cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users ...... 187 Table 29: Full information maximum likelihood estimates of the endogenous switching regression for net value of crop production per hectare of users of mechanization versus non-users ............................................................................................................................. 190 Table 30: Expected log of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users ......................................................................................... 191 xii LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1: Proportion of rural households by landholding size categories stating that market based land transfers are possible in customary areas ...................................................................... 54 Figure 2: Map of Zambia showing location of ACS households.................................................. 66 Figure 3: Bivariate relationships between factor input ratios and landholding size ................... 116 Figure 4: Box plots of measures of productivity by landholding size categories ....................... 118 Figure 5: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of net value of crop production per hectare (with and without CRS assumption) ................................................................ 138 Figure 6: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of net value of crop production per family labor day (with and without CRS assumption) ................................................. 139 Figure 7: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of net value of crop production per labor day (with and without CRS assumption) ............................................................. 139 Figure 8: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of cost of maize production per metric ton produced (with and without CRS assumption) .................................................. 140 Figure 9: Operated farm size and alternative predicted values of total factor productivity (with and without CRS assumption) ............................................................................................ 141 Figure 10: Map of Zambia showing location of ACS and RALS households............................ 147 Figure 11: Proportion of small- and medium-scale farming households using mechanization for agricultural land preparation by province between 2012 and 2015 .................................... 175 Figure 12: Proportion of medium-scale farming households using mechanization for agricultural land preparation by selected districts .................................................................................. 176 Figure 13: Changes in factor price ratios for mechanization and agricultural labor (adjusted for inflation) by selected provinces in Zambia ......................................................................... 194 xiii KEY TO ABBREVIATIONS ACS Agricultural Commercialization Survey AFRE Agricultural Food and Resource Economics AMSECS Agricultural Mechanization Service Enterprise Centers AU African Union CAADP Comprehensive Africa Agricultural Development Program CFS Crop Forecast Surveys CFU Conservation Farming Unit CRS Constant returns to scale CSO Central Statistical Office CSUS Community Sustainability DHS Demographic and Health Surveys DRC Democratic Republic of Congo FAO Food and Agriculture Organization FIML Full Information Maximum Likelihood FISP Farmer Input Support Program FRA Food Reserve Agency GIS Geographical Information Systems GoG Government of Ghana GPS Geographical Positioning System GRZ Government of the Republic of Zambia IAPRI Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute xiv IFPRI International Food Policy Research Institute IR Inverse Relationship ISPs Input Subsidy Programs LGP Length of the Growing Period MAL Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock MoA Ministry of Agriculture MSU Michigan State University NIE New Institutional Economics OLS Ordinary Least Squares RALS Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Survey RD Research and Development RNFE Rural Non-Farm Economy RTS Returns to Scale SRTM Shuttle Radar Topography Mission SSA Sub-Saharan Africa TFP Total Factor Productivity TGCC Tenure and Global Climate Change TSPs Tractor Service Providers USAID United States Agency for International Development ZLA Zambia Land Alliance ZMW Zambian Kwacha ZNFU Zambia National Farmers’ Union xv CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION Agricultural development has continued to receive unprecedented attention in the developing world mainly because a significant proportion of its inhabitants depend on agriculture for livelihoods (Timmer, 1998; Barrett et al., 2010). Yet, agricultural development—defined in this dissertation as the process that creates the conditions for the fulfillment of agricultural potential (de Laiglesia, 2006)—in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) has not progressed at the same pace as other developing regions of the world. A critical examination of an important outcome of the agricultural development process such as increased agricultural productivity reveals that SSA has witnessed a modest upward trend in agricultural total factor productivity since the 1980s (Fugile & Rada, 2013). However, agricultural productivity in the region still significantly lags behind that of other developing regions—for example, Latin America or South East Asia—in part because of a number of constraints that have continued to stifle the pace of growth. The constraints include low technology use, market failures and inconsistent policies that continue to distort the allocation of resources to enhance the much needed agricultural development (Diao et al., 2007). As a consequence, food security concerns and high poverty levels have continued to persist leaving more than 20 percent of the population in the region undernourished (FAO, 2014). This dissertation explores an important issue that has re-emerged in the development discourse—farm structure change—and whether this change represents an opportunity for countries in SSA to address the myriad of challenges confronting agricultural development outlined above. In this dissertation, farm structure or the structure of agriculture refers to a number of attributes such as “the number and size of farms; ownership and control of resources; and managerial, technological, and capital organization of farming” (Knutson, Penn, and 1 Flinchbaugh, 1998, p296). By extension, change in farm structure describes how the aforementioned attributes of agriculture, in SSA for example, have evolved over time driven by factors that are either endogenous (internal) or exogenous (external) to the entire system. Research on the dynamics of farm structure is not new to development scholars. A review of the literature reveals that research on farm structure change and its implication for development has been of interest to development scholars for more than three decades (Berry & Cline, 1979; Kydd & Christiansen, 1982; Binswanger, Deininger, & Feder, 1993). While there is quite a diversity in the specific lines of inquiry pursued by a myriad of studies, the overarching themes that have been investigated in relation to farm structure change include: (1) migration of labor from the small to the large farm sector (e.g., Bryceson, 1996; Barrett et al., 2001; Bryceson, 2002); (2) large-scale land acquisitions (Kydd & Christiansen, 1982; Deininger & Byerlee, 2012; German et al., 2013; Nolte, 2014), and; (3) the expansion of domestic land investors (Jayne et al., 2014; Sitko & Jayne, 2014; Jayne et al., 2016). The general focus by scholars studying farm structure change in the current development discourse has largely been on the development implications of large-scale land acquisitions of foreign origin. Farm structure change associated with the rise of domestic medium-scale farmers has received less attention. While foreign driven large-scale land acquisitions have played a role in altering the agricultural landscape in SSA, the increase in pace at which land is being acquired by domestic land investors—for example in Ghana, Kenya, Tanzania and Zambia—has completely changed the farm structure outlook (Jayne et al., 2014; Jayne et al., 2016). In the four case study countries mentioned above, the total area under the control of domestic medium-scale investor farms now exceeds that of foreign and previously established domestic large-scale holdings combined. And in the case of Zambia, it has been estimated that medium-scale farms (5 2 to 100 hectares landholding size) control about 2.5 million hectares while small-scale farms (those with less than 5 hectares landholding size) control approximately 2.1 million hectares of land (ibid). The distinction between small- and medium-scale farms employed in this study is based the following. First, we rely on how African governments in general define these categories. They use 5 hectares as the distinction between small- and medium-scale holdings. Second, we want to be consistent with how the emerging scholarly work on the rise of mediumscale investor farms in SSA has defined this scale of farming; they refer to medium-scale farms as those between 5 and 100 hectares of land The domestic land investor dynamic has ignited interest in the development discourse to understand whether or not this new phenomenon signals an alternative pathway for achieving agricultural development in parts of SSA. Therefore, this dissertation examines farm structure change associated with domestic medium-scale investor farms and its implications for agricultural development in sub-Saharan Africa. The study has three specific objectives: (1) to investigate the causes and consequences of the rise of domestic medium-scale investor farms; (2) to re-examine the farm size – productivity relationship hypothesis in the context of farm structure change, and; (3) to explore recent trends in agricultural mechanization use, its effects on agricultural household production and the factors contributing to recent initiatives aimed at enhancing mechanization in Zambia. The study was conducted in Zambia because the country has been experiencing major changes in farm structure, the most salient of which is a major increase in cultivated area under the control of farms cultivating between 5 and 100 hectares. To this end, the dissertation consists of three essays summarized here in turn. The first essay, presented in Chapter 2, examines the underlying political economy and institutional factors driving the change in farm structure and explores the effects of this change 3 on indicators inextricably linked with a vibrant agricultural sector. It uses a mixed-methods approach that relies on quantitative—secondary and primary—and qualitative sources of data collected in Zambia. The secondary quantitative data includes various years of national level agricultural household data that demonstrate the changing dynamics of agricultural land ownership and use over the last 10 to 15 years. The primary quantitative data, collected in 2013, is a cross-sectional dataset that investigates the life history and pathways to agricultural commercialization of medium-scale farm households in six districts located in central and southern Zambia. The qualitative data are in-depth interview transcripts of purposively sampled respondents from the six aforementioned districts and Lusaka, the capital city of Zambia. In total, 48 in-depth interviews were conducted comprising 24 small- and medium-scale farmers, 12 community leaders and relevant district officials, and 12 national level representatives. Results indicate that farm structure change has been driven by factors such as a positive change in perception of farming by society that has ushered in new entrants with a desire to farm at a level above small-scale agriculture. Further, the change in enforcement of informal rules of land governance has enhanced the rate of land acquisitions by domestic medium-scale investor farms. Lastly, the unintended consequences of public spending agricultural support programs have been favorable to the rise of domestic medium-scale farms. The research also finds that the change has been associated with agricultural land concentration, perpetuation of a maize monoculture, accumulation of idle land among medium-scale investor farms and increasing land constraints among small-scale farmers. Further, the evidence points to low land titling especially among small-scale farms, a growing informal land rental and sales market and a skewed level of agricultural commercialization. The study concludes that in order to achieve broad-based development, policy strategies should address inequalities in land access, the process of 4 formalization of land ownership and low production and productivity among small-scale farm households. The second essay, presented in Chapter 3, revisits the inverse farm size-productivity hypothesis by extending the methodological approach in previous research and provides practical implications for policy. Past studies have remarkably been limited to data from farms of less than ten hectares, yet their findings have been extrapolated beyond this farm size range. Moreover, productivity has mainly been restricted to land productivity when exploring the hypothesis. Further, previous studies have consistently used the assumption of constant returns to scale when examining the farm size-productivity relationship, which may not be appropriate when including large farms. This paper accounts for these issues by relaxing the ceteris paribus assumption and finds that the inverse farm size-productivity relationship is not consistently observed across alternative indicators of productivity. While the study finds that small-scale farms are more productive when the outcome variable is either land productivity or cost of staple food production per metric ton produced, relatively larger farms have higher labor productivity. Relaxing the assumption of constant returns to scale strengthens the hypothesis of an inverse relationship, particularly when productivity is measured in terms of land productivity and total factor productivity. The paper concludes that findings on the relationship between productivity and operated farm size, while important, should not be the decisive factor in guiding agricultural development and land policies in sub-Saharan Africa because there are many other important considerations. The third essay (Chapter 4) examines the trends and effects on agricultural household production of agricultural mechanization and explores the factors contributing to recent developments aimed at enhancing mechanization in Zambia. The essay is motivated by the 5 observation that there is a dearth of research that examines the contribution of agricultural mechanization to agricultural development in SSA given the current environment in which policy makers, the private sector and farmer organizations have teamed up to promote tractor use for land preparation. The third essay has three key findings. First, the evidence across a three year period (2012 – 2015) shows that agricultural mechanization use by small- and medium-scale farming households has remained low and stagnant with only 1.5 percent of these households reporting that they used mechanization for land preparation. Second, the study finds that use of mechanization for land preparation increased farmers’ area cultivated by about 60 percent relative to those who did not use mechanization. However, the study finds that mechanization use did not necessarily translate into net gains in productivity for farmers. The study attributes this to low levels of intensification by farmers in Zambia of productivity enhancing inputs such as improved seed, fertilizer and others. Third, although results indicate that the price ratios for rental of mechanization relative to labor costs had changed over time in favor of a shift to labor saving technologies, demand for mechanization has not increased correspondingly. Therefore, the study established that mechanization initiatives in Zambia have mainly been driven by the supply side. The study concludes by recommending more involvement of government extension in training potential users of mechanization services, which could in turn stimulate demand for services. Further, some key areas for remodeling mechanization initiatives are proposed. The last essay of the dissertation, Chapter 5, summarizes the dissertation by synthesizing the key findings and policy options crucial to achieving agricultural development. 6 REFERENCES 7 REFERENCES Barrett, Christopher B., Michael R. Carter, and C. Peter Timmer. 2010. “A Century-Long Perspective on Agricultural Development.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 92 (2): 447–68. doi:10.1093/ajae/aaq005. Barrett, Christopher B., T. Reardon, and P Webb. 2001. “Nonfarm Income Diversification and Household Livelihood Strategies in Rural Africa: Concepts, Dynamics, and Policy Implications.” Food Policy 26: 315–31. Berry, Robert Albert, and William Richard Cline. 1979. Agrarian Structure and Productivity in Developing Countries: A Study Prepared for the International Labour Office Within the Framework of the World Employment Programme. John Hopkins University Press. Binswanger, Hans, Klaus Deininger, and Gershon Feder. 1993. “Power, Distortions, Revolt, and Reform in Agricultural Relations.” In Handbook of Development Economics, edited by Jere Behrman and T.N. Srinivasan. Vol. IIIB. Amsterdam: North-Holland. http://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/6645289.pdf. Bryceson, Deborah Fahy. 1996. “Deagrarianization and Rural Employment in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Sectoral Perspective.” World Development 24 (1): 97–111. ———. 2002. “The Scramble in Africa: Reorienting Rural Livelihoods.” World Development 30 (5): 725–739. de Laiglesia, Juan Ramón. 2006. “Institutional Bottlenecks for Agricultural Development.” http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/development/institutional-bottlenecks-for-agriculturaldevelopment_671788081061. Deininger, Klaus, and Derek Byerlee. 2012. “The Rise of Large Farms in Land Abundant Countries: Do They Have a Future?” World Development 40 (4): 701–14. Diao, Xinshen, Peter B. R. Hazell, Danielle Resnick, and James Thurlow. 2007. The Role of Agriculture in Development: Implications for Sub-Saharan Africa. Intl Food Policy Res Inst. FAO. 2014. “Food Security Data, FAOSTAT.” http://faostat3.fao.org/home/E. Feder, Gershon, Richard E. Just, and David Zilberman. 1985. “Adoption of Agricultural Innovations in Developing Countries: A Survey.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 33 (2): 255–98. doi:10.1086/451461. Fugile, Keith, and Nicholas Rada. 2013. “USDA Economic Research Service - Research Raises Agricultural Productivity in Sub-Saharan Africa.” USDA Economic Research Service. May 6. http://www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2013-may/research-raises-agriculturalproductivity-in-sub-saharan-africa.aspx#.UzRXIF660oY. 8 German, Laura, George Schoneveld, and Esther Mwangi. 2013. “Contemporary Processes of Large-Scale Land Acquisition in Sub-Saharan Africa: Legal Deficiency or Elite Capture of the Rule of Law?” World Development 48 (August): 1–18. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.03.006. Jayne, T. S., Chamberlin, J., Traub, L., Sitko, N., Muyanga, M., Yeboah, F. K., … Kachule, R. (2016). Africa’s changing farm size distribution patterns: the rise of medium-scale farms. Agricultural Economics, 47(S1), 197–214. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12308 Jayne, Thomas S., Antony Chapoto, Nicholas Sitko, Chewe Nkonde, Milu Muyanga, and Jordan Chamberlin. 2014. “Is the Scramble for Land in Africa Foreclosing a Smallholder Agricultural Expansion Strategy?” Journal of International Affairs 67 (2): 35–53. Johnston, Bruce F., and John W. Mellor. 1961. “The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development.” The American Economic Review 51 (4): 566–93. Knutson, Ronald D, J.B. Penn, and B.L. Flinchbaugh. 1998. Agricultural and Food Policy. 4th ed. Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Pearson/Prentice Hall. Kydd, Jonathan, and Robert Christiansen. 1982. “Structural Change in Malawi since Independence: Consequences of a Development Strategy Based on Large-Scale Agriculture” 10 (5): 355–75. Nolte, Kerstin. 2014. “Large-Scale Agricultural Investments under Poor Land Governance in Zambia.” Land Use Policy 38 (May): 698–706. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2014.01.014. Sitko, Nicholas J., and T. S. Jayne. 2014. “Structural Transformation or Elite Land Capture? The Growth of ‘emergent’ Farmers in Zambia.” Food Policy, Boserup and Beyond: Mounting Land Pressures and Development Strategies in Africa, 48 (October): 194–202. doi:10.1016/j.foodpol.2014.05.006. Timmer, C. Peter. 1998. “The Agricultural Transformation.” In International Agricultural Development, edited by Carl K. Eicher and John M. Staatz, 113–35. Johns Hopkins University Press. 9 CHAPTER 2: THE RISE OF DOMESTIC MEDIUM-SCALE FARMS IN ZAMBIA: CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES 2.1. Introduction Most rural households in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) directly or indirectly depend on agriculture for their livelihoods (Diao et al., 2010). With more than two-thirds of these households residing on small farms of less than two hectares (Hazell et al., 2010), development practitioners and policymakers in the region have in the last 50 years or so championed agricultural development strategies that support small-scale agriculture. Yet, agriculture in SSA has continued to underperform relative to other developing parts of the world. This is partly because of low technology use, market failures and inconsistent policies that distort allocation of resources in agriculture (Diao et al., 2007). As a result, food security concerns and high rural poverty levels persist in SSA—almost 23.8 percent of the population is undernourished—and the contribution of agriculture to overall economic development in the region has been dismal at best. In essence, prospects of achieving agricultural development and in the process structural transformation through a strategy that is focused on small-scale agriculture have continued to suffer major setbacks. However, recent evidence has shown that there is a rapid expansion in farmland acquisitions in parts of SSA by domestic land investors or medium-scale farms—farms with landholdings between 5 and 100 hectares (Jayne et al., 2014)—and foreign owned large-scale farms (Deininger & Byerlee, 2012; German et al., 2013; Nolte, 2014; Schoneveld, 2014; Land Matrix, 2015). This evidence suggests that farm structure in affected countries of SSA has been undergoing changes symbolized by the relative increase in the number of larger farms. Does this change signal an emerging alternative pathway to address the myriad of challenges confronting 10 agriculture in SSA? Is this change likely to help achieve the main goal of rural and overall economic development in SSA? In view of the aforementioned questions, the current study examines the change in farm structure characterized by the rapid expansion of medium-scale investor farms and addresses its implications for rural development in SSA using the case of Zambia. In Zambia, recent estimates have shown that medium-scale farms now account for more land than the holdings in the entire small-scale sector (Jayne et al., 2014). Understanding the causes and consequences of this farm structure change is vital as this seems to be a crucially important topic and one on which more applied research evidence is required. In this paper, we define medium-scale investor farms as farm holdings between 5 and 100 hectares. As observed by Jayne et al (2016), definition of what each scale of farming implies is rather arbitrary and could mean different things in different regions of the world. Therefore, our decision to use cutoff points of 5 and 100 ha has been informed by two things. First, the choice is based on how a number of African governments define medium-scale farm households. They use 5 hectares as the distinction between small- and medium-scale holdings (ibid). Second, we wanted to be consistent with how the emerging scholarly work on the rise of medium-scale investor farms in SSA has defined this scale of farming; they refer to medium-scale farms as those between 5 and 100 hectares of land (see for example, Jayne et al., 2014; Jayne et al., 2016). Farm structure or the structure of agriculture, in this essay, refers to a number of attributes such as “the number and size of farms; ownership and control of resources; and managerial, technological, and capital organization of farming” (Knutson, Penn, and Flinchbaugh 1998, p296). By extension, farm structure change implies the evolution of farm 11 structure over time driven by factors that are either endogenous (internal) or exogenous (external) to the entire system. While there are studies that have examined recent changes in farm structure (e.g., Jayne et al., 2014; Sitko & Jayne, 2014), some gaps in the literature still exist. First, past studies have not employed a rigorous analytical framework to comprehend the political economy and institutional dimensions contributing to changes in farm structure. Second, given the complexity of this topic, it is remarkable that past studies have largely employed quantitative methods of inquiry at the expense of using a mixed-methods approach that elicits deeper understanding of observed changes in farm structure. This study addresses these gaps by developing an analytical framework that combines quantitative and qualitative methods to understand the direct and indirect effects of farm structure change symbolized by rapid expansion of medium-scale investor farms. The current study addresses five research questions that extend beyond what has been examined previously: 1. What do farmers, community leaders and stakeholders involved in land governance issues perceive to be the key drivers of farm structure change in Zambia? 2. How has farm structure changed and what are the characteristics of domestic land investors that have emerged in the last decade or so in Zambia? 3. How has land use evolved in the context of farm structure change? 4. How have attributes such as agricultural land titling and participation in land markets evolved in the context of farm structure change? 5. What relationship exists between farm structure change and the level of agricultural commercialization in the rural economy of Zambia? 12 The rest of the paper is organized into four main sections. The next section presents a review of the literature by outlining the following: (1) a discussion of the opportunities and challenges affecting small-scale agriculture; (2) insights from empirical studies on farm structure change; (3) the conceptual foundations used to develop the analytical framework for this study, and; (4) a historical perspective of land institutions in Zambia. The “Data and Methods” section explains the primary and secondary sources of data and the qualitative and quantitative methods employed in the study. The results are presented and discussed in the penultimate section and the last section concludes and provides implications for policy. 2.2. Literature review 2.2.1. Small-scale agriculture: opportunities and challenges Before examining recent developments pertaining to farm structure change, it is first important to outline reasons why development practitioners and policymakers in SSA champion agricultural development strategies that support small-scale agriculture. A popular explanation relates to the often-observed inverse farm size-productivity relationship—a hypothesis that postulates that small farms are more productive per unit of land than large farms (Berry & Cline, 1979). Although the existence of an inverse farm size-productivity relationship is widely contested, one cannot ignore the preponderance of evidence from studies conducted in Asia that have empirically found this relationship (e.g., Sen, 1962; Ghose, 1979; Berry & Cline, 1979; Carter, 1984; Chen et al., 2011). Likewise, there has been an increase in the number of empirical studies in SSA that have also shown the existence of an inverse farm size-productivity relationship (e.g., Kimhi, 2006; Carletto et al., 2013; Ali & Deininger, 2015; Larson et al., 2014). 13 As a consequence, findings of an inverse relationship have been used as the basis for supporting agricultural strategies that promote small-scale agriculture. Another explanation relates to the argument that a smallholder-led or ‘unimodal’ farm structure (featuring relatively egalitarian land distribution) is more effectively advantageous for achieving poverty reduction and broader economic growth than a large-scale farm structure (Mellor & Johnston, 1984; Timmer, 1998; Barrett et al., 2010). Asia still provides a good example of a developing country region where a smallholder-led strategy has led to pro-poor growth. Hazell et al. (2010, p. 1351) have argued that, “Asia’s green revolution demonstrated how agricultural growth that reaches large numbers of small farms could transform rural economies and raise enormous numbers of people out of poverty.” In such an environment, universal intensification of a great number of small farms not only maximizes output and employment in agriculture, but also provides a strong impetus to the development of the Rural Non-Farm Economy (RNFE) culminating into long-run structural transformation (Hayami, 1977; Haggblade et al., 1989; Delgado, 1998; Lanjouw & Lanjouw, 2001). This is presumably because increased income is widely distributed and strengthens local demand for what the RNFE produces. Meanwhile, agricultural growth continues to elude most of SSA as evidenced by poor agricultural performance (Larsson et al., 2002). In Zambia, for instance, Hichaambwa & Jayne (2014) showed that there has been very little production growth among the bottom 60 percent of smallholders. They also showed that the top five percent of farmers with over 10 hectares are the category of farmers who have achieved almost all of the growth in agriculture over the past decade. In general, smallholder production has been hampered by many challenges that have undermined its potential (Jayne et al., 2010). 14 2.2.2. Farm structure change in SSA: empirical insights and gaps The literature is replete with empirical studies of agrarian transformation or farm structure change in Africa covering the colonial period through to the post-independence era. While the line of inquiry pursued regarding farm structure change is quite diverse, three main topical areas that have been investigated include studies that aim to understand how farm structure has been affected by: (1) migration of labor from the small to the large farm sector (e.g., Bryceson, 1996; Barrett et al., 2001; Bryceson, 2002); (2) large-scale land acquisitions (Kydd & Christiansen, 1982; Deininger & Byerlee, 2012; German et al., 2013; Nolte, 2014), and; (3) the expansion of domestic land investors (Jayne et al., 2014; Sitko & Jayne, 2014). Since this paper is focused on the direct and indirect effects of domestic land investors, the rest of this subsection is only dedicated to the discussion of empirical studies that have investigated the expansion of domestic land investors. The general focus by scholars studying farm structure change in the current development discourse has largely been on the development implications of large-scale land acquisitions of foreign origin. While the increase in foreign-driven-large-scale land acquisitions cannot be overemphasized, the increase in pace at which land is being acquired by land investors from within the boundaries of SSA countries (e.g. Ghana, Kenya and Zambia) has completely changed the farm structure outlook (Jayne et al., 2014). In the three aforementioned countries, the area under these domestic land investors (mainly medium-scale farms) now exceeds that of foreign and previously established domestic large-scale holdings combined. And in the case of Zambia, it has been estimated that medium-scale farms (5 to 100 hectares landholding size) control about 2.5 million hectares while small-scale farms (less than 5 hectares landholding size) control approximately 2.1 million hectares of land (ibid). As a result, the domestic land investor dynamic 15 has ignited interest in the development discourse to understand whether or not this new phenomenon signals an alternative pathway for achieving agricultural development in parts of SSA. Studies examining the rise of domestic land investors have investigated how the rate of land acquisitions by these new investors relates to the amount of economically attractive arable land and changing conditions of land access, inequality, and alienation of small-scale farmers (Jayne et al., 2014; Sitko & Chamberlin, 2015). The other issues explored include pathways by which the emergent farming sector has grown (Sitko & Jayne, 2014) and the causes and likely effects of this structural change (Jayne et al., forthcoming). Based on the aforementioned issues, these studies have provided important insights that demonstrate that the rise of domestic investors: (1) threatens to exacerbate localized land scarcity; (2) may be largely comprised of urban based or elite farmers and very few farmers who have organically developed through farming, and; (3) is probably not addressing national goals of poverty reduction and agricultural development. The current study builds on this emerging literature by focusing on existing gaps; the need to employ a rigorous analytical framework and mixed-methods of inquiry to understand the direct and indirect effects of farm structure change symbolized by rapid expansion of domestic land investors. 2.2.3. Agricultural transformation and political economy of institutions This study is situated within the broader context of two main strands of literature that discuss: (1) the agricultural transformation process (e.g. Johnston & Mellor, 1961; Timmer, 1998), and; (2) the political economy of institutions in agricultural development (extensively reviewed by Hoeffler (2011)). The agricultural transformation process can be described as one by which individual farms shift from highly diversified, subsistence-oriented production towards 16 more specialized production oriented towards the market or other systems of exchange (Staatz, 1998). When examining the political economy of institutions, the focus is on the analysis of formal and informal rules underlying political powers, bureaucratic agencies or social and private organizations in the agricultural development process (The World Bank, 2008). Each of these conceptual foundations is outlined in turn. Timmer (1998) demonstrates that overall economic development of most nations is preceded by rapid growth in the agricultural sector. In the process, however, the importance of agriculture begins to diminish as other sectors of the economy take center stage. The reason for this apparent paradox is that when agriculture undergoes this transformation process, there is a greater reliance on input and output delivery systems and increased integration of agriculture with other sectors of the domestic and international economies (Staatz, 1998). This leads to overall economic structural transformation whereby agriculture plays a lesser role in economic output and employment generation. The literature further shows that the evolutionary process of agricultural transformation goes through four distinct phases (Timmer, 1998). First, there is a noticeable increase in the returns to agricultural labor, which helps to enhance agricultural surplus production. Second, the increase in surplus production invariably leads to the development of the nonagricultural sector of both the rural and urban economies. Third, there is a progressive integration of the agricultural sector into the macro economy through improved infrastructure and market equilibrium linkages. And as already explained above, the role of agriculture gradually becomes less noticeable due to the economy-wide structural transformation. Given that developing countries have largely remained committed to the desire to stimulate the much-needed economic growth, is the current change in farm structure (explained 17 above) likely to engender the theoretical predictions embodied in the agricultural transformation process? Interestingly, proponents of a broad based agricultural development process question whether this apparent concentration of land ownership and subsequent concentration of upstream agricultural production is the ideal path for SSA agriculture. Therefore, locating this paper within the context of the agricultural transformation literature is important for understanding of the effects of farm structure change on rural development in SSA and Zambia in particular. The agricultural transformation process happens within the context of political decisionmaking and institutions that exist in a given society. Hoeffler (2011, p. 31) explains that, “the agricultural sector shows so many specific historic, agro-ecological, economic, social and political features that a careful analysis of the agents, institutions, markets and networks involved as well as their respective interests and powers within the sector is mandatory for agricultural policy analysis and reform implementation.” Therefore, it is vital that a study that seeks to understand the causes and consequences of farm structure change should clearly understand existing institutions. This essay mainly draws from the New Institutional Economics (NIE) framework to develop an analytical framework for unpacking the study’s overarching research questions. The NIE framework is a useful tool for assessing institutions and how institutions interact with organizational arrangements (Ménard & Shirley, 2008). The range of applications where the framework has been extensively applied include studies exploring transaction costs economics (North, 1990, 2008; Williamson, 1985) and property rights (Ostrom, 1990; Schlager & Ostrom, 1992; Kim & Mahoney, 2005; Libecap, 2008). Scholars, for example North (1994), have also generally been interested in understanding institutional change and have therefore developed and implemented an analytical approach with 18 attributes that help the researcher to: (1) identify individuals—actors—who are at the center of institutional change; (2) comprehend the sources of institutional change, whether external or internal to the actor’s environment; (3) understand whether institutional change takes the form of changes to formal rules (legislative, judicial, regulatory or constitutional changes) or changes in informal constraints that constitute norms, conventions, or personal standards of honesty or both; (4) understand the role of path dependence—the idea that history matters, and; (5) determine whether any revolutionary change has occurred that has led to institutional change. This study adapted this analytical framework to get insights on farm structure change in Zambia and the implications this has for overall rural and economic development. 2.2.4. Farm structure change in the context of land institutions in Zambia The institutional environment for land administration in Zambia has undergone changes over time alongside the country’s evolution of political governance chronologically categorized as follows: (1) the pre-colonial period (before 1924); (2) the period of colonial rule (1924-1964); (3) the first post-independence era (1964-1972); (4) the second post-independence era (19731991), and; (5) the third post-independence era (beyond 1991). The pre-colonial period land institutions mainly operated within the context of customary law. In this context, people were linked to land through ethnic ties to a particular region of the territory where the present Zambia exists (van Loenen, 1999). Although the laws differed from one ethnic group to the other, there were a number of similarities that cut across most ethnic groups. Land was never viewed as a saleable commodity, landownership was communal and systems of regulating communal rights existed (Chinene et al., 1998). The coming in of colonial rule probably represents the first wave of noticeable changes in farm structure in Zambia. The British Colonial Authority took over land administration in 1924 19 and initially created a dual land tenure system: Crown land for the minority European settlers and Native Reserves for Africans (natives). The location of Crown land was mainly in parts of the country considered to have the best potential for agriculture and along the line of rail constructed in the early parts of the 20th Century (Adams, 2003). Three aspects or developments emerged during the colonial land tenure system. First, European settlers occupying Crown land were granted freeholds or leaseholds in this land with title while natives occupying Native Reserves were not allowed to obtain title (van Loenen, 1999). Second, European settlers or non-natives were also allowed to obtain land in Native Reserves but for only five years or less (ibid). However, Africans did not have access to land in Crown territory Third, colonialists introduced a new law that allowed reclassification of suitable land not previously alienated, which therefore introduced a third category of land called Trust land. This new law was only introduced a couple of decades after colonialists assumed land administration. The introduction of Trust land came about because of the pressure colonialists received from both natives and European settlers. Natives had perpetually resisted the concept of Native Reserves as reserves were associated with overcrowding and impoverishment while European settlers had also continued to demand for larger tracts of land (Chinene et al., 1998). Therefore, Trust land was accessible to both the natives and the non-natives. Unfortunately, the introduction of Trust land did little to circumvent the non-egalitarian land distribution of the colonial era. This is because the good fertile land was still reserved for European settlers. When Zambia gained independence in 1964, the new political leadership led by Kenneth Kaunda largely maintained the land tenure system left by colonialists (Chileshe, 2005). Although a large proportion of European settlers left when Zambia became a sovereign state in 1964, most 20 of the best farm land remained in the hands of the remaining settlers (van Loenen, 1999). During the first post-independence era, the few changes made were that Crown land was renamed State land and was now vested in the President rather than the British colonial government and that the new Zambian government was allowed by law to acquire undeveloped and unutilized lands particularly those lands held by absentee landowners (Brown, 2005). The second post-independence era when multiparty politics were abolished probably represents the period when the Kaunda-led administration made significant changes to land policies inherited from colonialists. Although socialism and nationalism were economic models that the country embraced at independence, the second republic was the period when these ideals became truly entrenched and thus had a significant impact on a number of policies including those related to land. Through an act of parliament, the Land (Conversion of Titles) Act of 1975, freehold tenure was abolished and converted to statutory leasehold while the market for land was suppressed and the state directly administered all land transfers (van Loenen, 1999; Brown, 2005). Further, when selling or buying land, no intrinsic value was attached to such property unless the property in question had improvements such as buildings and other infrastructure. To curtail foreigners from owning large tracts of land, parliament passed legislation in 1985 that restricted the alienation of land to foreigners (transferring of land acquired from customary landowners by government to foreigners), with the exception of presidentially certified investors and charitable organizations (ibid). Therefore, farm structure during the second post-independence era was characterized by highly subsidized state farms, a few largescale commercial farms owned by European settlers and small-scale farmers who remained in the majority and still occupied Reserve and Trust lands. 21 The land policy environment in the third post-independence era represents the current system, which began when the country reverted to multiparty politics in 1991. The new government led by Fredrick Chiluba was committed to making substantive land reforms and by 1995, they had managed to enact the 1995 Lands Act (Government of the Republic of Zambia (GRZ), 1995) which paved way for investment in land including by foreigners who were restricted by the previous regime (Nolte, 2014). According to Brown (2005), the new land law came with four fundamental changes. First, the law significantly strengthened the property rights of titleholders on State land, which made it possible for owners of land to sell land even without any improvements to it. A second aspect of the Act was that it eased restrictions on land ownership by foreigners. Third, the Lands Act created a Lands Tribunal to protect leaseholders and customary rights holders from abuse and to ease congestion within the High Court. Fourth, the Act made both cosmetic and substantive changes to the administration of customary land tenure. The cosmetic change made was the amalgamation of Reserve and Trust lands into a new category called customary lands. The substantive change made it easier for both outside investors (foreign or domestic living outside customary lands) and indigenous Zambians living on customary lands to acquire private title to customary land. Despite the good intentions of the Lands Act, its implementation has probably led to adverse effects on the allocation of unutilized land in customary land areas. First, while the law intends to benefit all potential land owners with respect to acquisition of private title to customary land, the clear beneficiaries have not been the majority of small-scale farmers but elites both at the local level and those coming from urban areas (Sitko & Jayne, 2012; Malambo, 2014). Second, although the original intent of allowing purchases of land by foreigners was to 22 encourage investments important for national development, the nature of land transactions that have been processed with foreign companies have been questionable at best and have largely excluded local land users from the process (Economist, 2011; McMichael, 2012; Nolte, 2014). Therefore, the third post-independence era has been characterized by land acquisition by individuals and firms who have the social and financial capital to benefit from a market-based environment at the expense of poor small-scale farmers. It is for this reason that civil society efforts spearheaded by the Zambia Land Alliance (ZLA) have been aimed at lobbying and advocating for a just land policy and law that takes into account the interests of the poor. 2.3. Data and methods In this section, the data and methods used are discussed in detail. An explanatory sequential mixed-methods approach was used to address the main research questions. First, what are the perceived causes of farm structure change? Second, what are the characteristics of farm structure change? Third, how is land use evolving in the context of farm structure change? Fourth, what is the extent and pattern of titling of agricultural land and farmer participation in agricultural land markets? Fifth, what is the relationship between agricultural commercialization and farm structure change? The sequential mixed-methods approach involved the following steps. The first step involved collecting and analyzing secondary and primary quantitative household survey data. The surveys provided data and analytical results related to a number of themes such as proportional changes in the number of small- versus medium-scale farms, demographic attributes of medium-scale investor farmers, extent of participation in land markets and other measurable attributes. The second step involved qualitative research methods. The qualitative methods helped with exploring the views of farmers, community leaders and land governance actors with 23 knowledge about farm structure change and agricultural development. The mixed-methods approach helped the researcher to triangulate findings generated from the two unique methods, an approach that enhanced the validity and generalizability of the study. 2.3.1. Phase 1: quantitative data collection The quantitative data were collected using secondary and primary data sources (survey instruments are available upon request). The secondary data sources were drawn from three nationally representative surveys conducted in Zambia in the last decade or so. The first nationally representative source of secondary data that the study relied on was various years of the Crop Forecast Surveys (CFS) of small-, medium- and large-scale farms in Zambia beginning from 2001.1 The Central Statistical Office (CSO) of Zambia conducts the CFSs on an annual basis in collaboration with the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL). The CFSs are designed to collect data from an average of 12,000 households on key agricultural production parameters during each agricultural season that runs from October 1 to September 30 the following year. Because it is not practical to collect all policy relevant information in this annual survey, this study relied on another secondary source of nationally representative data—the Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Survey (RALS) of small and medium-scale farming households in Zambia collected in 2012 and 2015. The RALS is a longitudinal survey conducted by the Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI) in conjunction with the two aforementioned public offices. The RALS used the new sampling frame derived from the 2010 census. A total of 8,839 and 7,934 households were interviewed during the 2012 and 2015 surveys respectively. The survey collected data on a 1 Similar to (Jayne et al., 2016), the three farm size categories in this study are defined based on landholdings as follows: small-scale (0-5 hectares); medium-scale (5-100 hectares); large-scale (more than 100 hectares). 24 number questions related to the following main themes: demographic characteristics of household members; farmland and use; crop sales from own production; input and credit acquisition; livestock ownership and marketing; off-farm income sources; food security indicators, and; other themes such as kinship ties of the household head. In addition, soil samples were collected from largest maize fields of sub-sampled households during the 2012 survey. The third source of secondary data was the Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS) collected in Zambia in 2007 and 2014. These datasets were used primarily because they capture information about land acquisitions of not only rural households but urban-based households as well. To get a better understanding of the changes in farm structure observed in Zambia especially with respect to medium-scale farms, the study also used primary data collected through the Agricultural Commercialization Survey (ACS). The ACS was conducted because both the CFS and RALS had two main limitations. First, it was established that the sampling frame for both surveys did not adequately capture medium-scale farms especially those between 20 and 100 hectares of land owned. Second, both the CFS and the RALS were not designed to capture information about the timing of land acquisitions, sources of income for these acquisitions and the employment history of the rising group of relatively large domestic landowners. The ACS was therefore designed to fill this gap but for only selected regions of Zambia. The ACS of 2013 was a follow-up to a survey of medium-scale farms conducted in Zambia in 2011 by Sitko & Jayne (2012) with assistance from the author of this paper. The main objective of the ACS was to understand the history, characteristics, land use decisions and patterns, and level of commercialization of medium-scale farmers observed to be a growing class 25 of farmers in Zambia. Similar to the first survey, the 2013 ACS survey purposively selected research sites (administrative districts) based on the concentration and number of medium-scale farms as reported in the 2010/2011 CFS. Two main criteria were used to select the districts included in the survey. First, at least 3 percent of farming households had to be classified as medium-scale farms in order to ensure a reasonable population from which to sample. Second, the research sites were selected along a continuum of concentrations to ensure geographical diversity. But as noted by Sitko & Chamberlin (2015), because medium-scale farms are concentrated along what is referred to as the ‘line of rail’ in Zambia, the selected districts were in close proximity to this region. The line of rail is a region of Zambia that is served by the railway linking the Copperbelt province with Lusaka, and with the border town Livingstone in the south of the country. Therefore, the six selected districts were Chibombo, Choma, Chongwe, Kalomo, Mpongwe and Mumbwa (see Figure 2 in Appendices for the map). A total of 482 households were randomly selected from a list of medium-scale farms generated in consultation with the Zambia National Farmers’ Union (ZNFU) and the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) district offices. The Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) block areas were identified as the sampling units with help from local district offices. Whereas the sampling procedure was supposed to ensure reasonable representativeness of farmers in the 5-100 hectare category within the selected districts, the sample may have not been statistically representative of all mediumscale farmers in Zambia. This is because medium-scale farmers were not sampled from the other 65 districts. But we can say that the chosen districts are understood to contain the highest proportions of farms in this size class. 26 2.3.2. Phase 2: qualitative data collection Qualitative data were collected through in-depth interviews of 48 purposively sampled respondents. For each interview, detailed notes were taken; and where the interviewee consented, an audio recorder was used to record the full interview. At the end of each day, the field notes and audio recordings were fully transcribed in readiness for analysis. The respondents included: (1) farmers (small- and medium-scale farmers); (2) community leaders and relevant district officials, and; (3) national level stakeholders. We describe each of these sources of qualitative data in turn. 2.3.2.1. Farmer in-depth interviews The in-depth interviews with farmers allowed the researcher to get further insights on issues not adequately addressed during the survey such as the following: (1) why they became farmers and what motivated them to acquire land; (2) agricultural land use and farmers’ perception of critical drivers; (3) agricultural technology choices, and; (4) relationship between farm structure change and prevailing institutions and policies. A total of 24 farmer in-depth interviews were conducted, with12 small-scale farmers and 12 medium-scale farmers. The in-depth interviews were conducted in the six districts were household survey data was collected using the ACS. The study first identified two medium-scale farmer in-depth interview participants per district using the ACS list. Selection of the participants was based on the trajectory the household followed to achieve medium-scale farmer status: organic growth through small-scale farming or lateral entry through non-farm income. Using snowball sampling, the study then selected small-scale farmers who were neighbors to the medium-scale farmers who participated in the in-depth interviews. 27 2.3.2.2. Community leader in-depth interviews Community leaders were included in this study because they have vast knowledge pertaining to land issues and the observed phenomenon of the change in farm structure in their respective areas. The community leader interviews targeted two community leaders in each of the six districts. In each district, the study undertook interviews with one village headman from the agricultural blocks visited during the survey and one high level official working for one of the key government ministries at district level with knowledge about the evolution of farm ownership in the district. In total, the study interviewed 12 community leaders. 2.3.2.3. Interviews with national-level stakeholders The national level stakeholder perspectives helped to broaden the study’s understanding of the causes and the consequences of the rise of medium-scale farms in Zambia. A total of twelve national level stakeholder interviews were conducted with senior officials from relevant government ministries, civil society organizations dealing with land issues in Zambia such as the Zambia Land Alliance (ZLA), farmer organizations such as the Zambia National Farmers’ Union (ZNFU), private sector firms and experts on land issues in Zambia. 2.3.3. Data analysis 2.3.3.1. Quantitative data analysis In order to quantitatively address research questions two to five, the study conducted descriptive analysis of secondary and primary sources of survey data assembled using Stata 14 software. Analysis of all secondary sources of data (CFS, RALS and DHS) involved comparison of means across small- and medium-scale farming households disaggregated by landholding size categories. Further, analysis of the secondary data accounted for the survey design by using the svy command available in Stata. For the primary source of data (ACS), the study compared 28 sample means among the survey respondents disaggregated by their mode of entry to this level of operation through: (1) farming from family acquired farm; (2) farming from non-family acquired farm, and; (3) through non-farm income sources. The first mode of entry described medium-scale farmers that began farming by acquiring a small piece of land (less than five hectares) from another family member and expanded their farms with revenue generated from small-scale farming. The second group described mediumscale farmers that began by acquiring a small piece of land (less than five hectares) from someone other than a family member, and expanded their farms with revenue generated primarily from small-scale farming. The third mode of entry described medium-scale farmers that were primarily involved in non-farm employment or business to begin with but afterwards acquired land (more than five hectares) using their non-farm income sources. Based on the dichotomy developed by Sitko & Jayne (2014), the first and second mode of entry captured medium-scale farmers that followed an agricultural-led growth strategy while the third group captured farmers that followed a lateral entry into medium-scale farming. 2.3.3.2. Qualitative data analysis The data collected using key informant interviews were used to gain insights for research questions one to four. Transcripts were developed for each of the 48 key informant interviews captured through audio recordings and hand written notes taken during the interviews. Based on grounded theory approach (Strauss & Corbin, 1994), the study used an iterative process to develop a coding scheme in NVivo 10 software. The coding scheme specified the concepts and themes, their definition and the rules for applying the codes. The codes developed enabled the researcher to easily retrieve similar information across individual transcripts. Summary 29 statements were written to represent the diversity of responses and where possible, quotes from the respondents were used to clearly represent their perspectives. 2.4. Results and discussion This section presents and discusses the key findings in line with the study’s main research questions. To remain consistent with the explanatory mixed-methods research design employed, the quantitative results are first discussed followed by the qualitative results except in the case of research question 1 that exclusively relied on qualitative data and analysis. 2.4.1. Perceived causes of farm structure change Jayne et al. (2016) conjecture several key drivers of the rise of medium-scale investor farms in SSA. These include the spike in food prices experienced in the latter parts of the last decade, improved access to inputs and technology, relative profitability of larger-scale farming, and vociferous farmer lobby groups whose agenda is pro large farms. Using a framework based on New Institutional Economics, the current study elicited views from key informants about what they perceived to be the main causes of farm structure change unique to the Zambian case. We found that change in society’s perception of agriculture, change in informal rules and customary land governance, change in the land policy environment and unintended consequences of public spending in agriculture have played a key role in changing the farm structure. 2.4.1.1. Change in society’s perception of agriculture All categories of key informants who participated in the in-depth interviews alluded to the fact that the change in society’s perception of agriculture has attracted new entrants. Some respondents stated that prior to the liberalization of the Zambian economy in the early 1990s, agriculture was viewed as a domain for either resource constrained small-scale farmers or highly 30 capitalized large-scale farms owned by European settlers or government state farms. While relatively medium-scale farms that were better capitalized than small-scale farms existed, they were few and far between. The general perception that prevailed at the time was that you had to be poor to be a farmer by default or extremely rich to reap the benefits of farming. Because of this perception, the majority of Zambians with levels of education high enough to escape the trap of farming by default, looked to work in industries other than primary agriculture. But with time, there has been a general realization that agriculture can also be a profitable venture and society’s perception of primary agriculture in the last two decades has changed. The change in society’s perception of agriculture has influenced ongoing farm structure changes in two ways. First, individuals not primarily involved in agriculture but have salaried jobs or sources of income in other sectors, now view agriculture as a sustainable option for securing their current and future livelihoods. One respondent put it this way: “People have realized that there is money in agriculture now. Previously, people wanted to work in mining or other sectors. But now, they have realized that actually they can make money out of agriculture. So, everyone wants to have land.” One of the national-level key informants also explained it as follows: “In the past we [Zambians] were working as workers with no interest in farming. We now have realized it’s important to have land. The villagers have sold the land along the road. They’ve just moved further and a lot of people are buying, not just the Chinese, but also Zambians because they want to be growing things. I have colleagues at the University [of Zambia] who have small-holdings.” Second, the change in society’s perception of agriculture has also influenced land acquisition decisions of people involved in primary agriculture for most of their lives. One farmer explained it this way: “I think people have woken up. They are learning from people 31 coming from urban areas. A lot of people from the urban areas are coming to get land, so people have realized that land is finishing and are being compelled to acquire agricultural land to increase production.” 2.4.1.2. Changes in enforcement of informal rules of land governance The current study also focused on understanding the role that recent developments in formal and informal land governance rules have had on farm structure. Of particular interest to this study were changes in policy provided for in the 1995 Lands Act and changes in customary land governance. All categories of respondents were asked whether they knew anything about changes in land policy in Zambia before eliciting their views on the link between land policy and farm structure change. The majority of farmers, mostly small-scale farmers, indicated that they had not been exposed to any information related to changes in land policy. Knowledge of changes to land policies for other categories of respondents—community leaders and national-level stakeholders—varied among the respondents with some showing limited knowledge while others were extensively familiar with relevant land policies obtaining in Zambia. However, the majority of these respondents did not attribute the changes in farm structure to changes in land policy or enactment of the 1995 Lands Act. They argued that the Act is not very clear and that there is no proper mechanism for implementation of existing provisions. Therefore, they contended that the changes in land policy have not directly induced the rapid expansion of domestic medium-scale investor farms. The following statements highlight this view: “I don’t think policy has played any role. It is only because people have realized that they need to go back to the land” (community leader, August 2014). “The problem is that the current land policy or Lands Act is not very clear and therefore difficult to implement. It is just that people in this era are waking up to the idea that they 32 need some land; they need some land to do some farming” (land policy consultant, August 2014). Nonetheless, the general consensus among the respondents was that changes in enforcement of customary rules of land governance have played a key role in changing the farm structure landscape. Through in-depth interviews, the study asked the respondents to highlight some of the key features of customary land governance, whether these features have changed over the last two decades and the effects of these changes, if any, on farm structure in Zambia. Despite a few variations in customary norms and values in the different sites visited for this study, the following features of customary land governance cut across all the communities visited: (1) headmen administer land at village level on behalf of a chief; (2) land is freely allocated if available; and (3) community members are not allowed to rent out or sell land. Across all categories of respondents, there was widespread consensus that these salient features of customary land administration have not, in principle, changed. However, a number of them indicated that with increased demand for land, land allocation has not been free in reality and a land rental and sales market has emerged in some communities; the changes in enforcement of informal rules of land governance have been the genesis of this. The result of this emerging land rental and sales market is that land acquisition has disproportionately been by those who can afford to pay for it. As one community leader stated, “The rules have not changed, but if one has money, they are likely to get land than someone without money.” One mediumscale farmer interviewee also described the prevailing situation in this manner: “I do not think the rules have changed, but these days you have to buy to acquire land [in customary areas].” The majority of the in-depth interview respondents perceived that the subtle changes in the governance of customary land have had an effect on farm structure in Zambia. They said that 33 the development of the informal market for land has significantly contributed to the acquisition of individual land parcels especially between 10 and 50 hectares of land in rural areas closer to urban centers of Zambia. This has effectively ushered in new participants in agricultural production who are perceived to be relatively more passionate about farming than an average small-scale farmer. 2.4.1.3. Unintended consequences of agricultural subsidy programs The Zambian government signed onto the Comprehensive Africa Agricultural Development Program (CAADP) during the African Union (AU) Heads of State summit held in 2003 in Maputo, Mozambique. The objective of CAADP is to “help African countries reach a higher path of economic growth through agriculture-led development, which eliminates hunger, reduces poverty and food insecurity, and enables expansion of exports” (African Union, n.d.). A key commitment made by each member state at this summit was to allocate at least 10 percent of their national budgets to agriculture. Since the establishment of CAADP, Zambia has steadily increased its public spending and has in some years (since 2007) surpassed the program’s spending objectives (Kuteya & Kabwe, 2015). When critically analyzed, however, there are two related issues of concern about this increase in spending which threaten attainment of the program objective in Zambia. First, the increase in spending has been primarily achieved because of increased spending in two subsidy programs that account for more than 50 percent of the agriculture budget—Farmer Input Support Program (FISP) and Food Reserve Agency (FRA) (Sitko & Chamberlin, 2015). Second, the subsidy programs disproportionately favor relatively larger farms that have the capacity to cover the cost-sharing requirements of the FISP and to produce surplus maize to sell to the FRA at prices above equilibrium market prices (ibid). 34 The in-depth interviews inquired further on the latter concern. Although all the interviewees indicated that the two subsidy programs were targeted towards both small- and medium-scale farms, they shared a number of implementation challenges that have implicitly distorted the intended benefit structure. With respect to the FISP, the respondents shared three main implementation challenges. First, the respondents overwhelmingly indicated lack of transparency in the way some cooperatives—farmer organizations through which farmers access FISP inputs at local level—operate and that such have only benefited a few. They further indicated that those with financial capacity are the ones who have greater control of existing cooperatives. The following statements summarize the respondents’ concerns: “There are loopholes you know. FISP is politics. What usually happens is that even political cadres who are not engaged in farming form cooperatives and access program inputs. So you find that a local political cadre, his spouse, nephews and people that are dead become members of that cooperative.” “When you join the cooperative you just continue benefiting even if the rules say one is supposed to graduate after a few years. You find that it is the same people who are members of the cooperative for years.” “It’s not the small farmers [who are benefitting] from FISP. Cooperatives, through which FISP inputs are sold, need financial resources and logistics to be able to travel between the community and districts to try and lobby for input packs. The people that have these financial resources and connections tend to be those who are on a higher scale—a very small-scale famer will be part of the [cooperative] executive but not necessarily at the forefront of making decisions to access this fertilizer.” Second, some respondents complained about the late delivery of FISP inputs as a major implementation challenge. As a result, farmers, especially small-scale farmers who rely on subsidized inputs, plant late, have poor harvest and therefore little to no surplus production for the market. Third, most of the farmer respondents mentioned that the input packs delivered to some cooperatives are fewer than the expected allocation. Therefore, members of a cooperative 35 are either compelled to share or some are completely left out from accessing the few available input packs. The respondents highlighted two main implementation challenges of the maize output market provided by the FRA. The first challenge mentioned was that the FRA rarely pays the farmers on time after they have delivered their maize. This delay has a negative impact on the farmers’ ability to meet contemporaneous household needs and future plans for the next agricultural season. The second challenge indicated was that some of the procedures put in place by FRA of repackaging grain at their buying depots have effectively removed some resourceconstrained farmers from extracting the benefits of selling their maize at prices above market equilibrium. As one respondent put it: “the problem is that you have to repackage the maize again when you had already done that at home. So that process is costly because you pay for labor when doing that at the depot again.” Put together, the unintended consequence brought about by the implementation challenges of the two subsidy programs is that the incentive structure has been distorted. The distorted incentive structure has worked in favor of relatively resource-rich farmers who are more likely to be medium-scale farmers. 2.4.2. Characterizing farm structure change in Zambia In order to have a clear characterization of farm structure change in Zambia, the current study conducted the following series of analyses using both quantitative and qualitative data. First, the study assessed the change in the number of farms and total landholdings of households, disaggregated by classifications based on landholding size. Second, we examined the demographic characteristics of domestic investor farms and, third, we explored available data 36 sources to understand the extent to which urban households are entering into agriculture. We discuss each of these in turn. 2.4.2.1. Nature of change in farm structure This study sought to explain the nature of change in farm structure in Zambia using two Crop Forecast Survey (CFS) datasets separated by a period of 15 years. Table 1 summarizes a number of important statistics that demonstrate the nature of these changes between 2001 and 2015. The table uses landholding size to characterize farm structure in Zambia classified as follows: (1) 0-2 hectares; (2) 2-5 hectares; (3) 5-10 hectares; (4) 10-20 hectares, and; (5) 20-100 hectares. Three important changes can be identified from this table. First, although the number of farms for all categories has increased during the reference period, the change in the absolute number of farms with five hectares and above has been more rapid. When analyzed at national level, the change in the number of farms in the 0-2 hectares and 2-5 hectares categories is less than 40 percent while farms above 5 hectares have increased by more than 60 percent. When we isolate six districts that were the site for further investigation of medium-scale farm growth, the increase in the number of farms above 5 hectares is over 100 percent. Second, the results show that the proportion of small- and medium-scale farmland owned by farmers with five hectares and above has increased by 11 percent from 58 percent in 2001 to 69 percent in 2015 when analyzed at national level. If the focus is on the six districts, we find a similar positive trend (15 percent increase) in the proportion of total small- and medium-scale farmland owned by farms with five hectares and above during the two time periods. Third, the results indicate that average landholding has decreased the most for the smallest category of farms with less than 2 hectares at both national level and the six selected 37 districts. On the other hand, the largest category (20-100 hectares) of medium-scale farmers has seen an increase in average landholding of about 11 and 34 percent at national level and the six districts respectively. Findings from the qualitative analysis also reveal the general perception that there has been an expansion of medium-scale farms in Zambia in recent years. As one medium-scale farmer observed: “[the] number [of medium-scale farmers] is increasing. It is like a veil has just been removed from people, everyone has arisen and looking for land.” Other key informants, especially national level stakeholders, gave more insights on how the expansion of medium-scale farms is happening across the whole country including regions that previously had minimal agricultural activity. One national-level stakeholder explained it this way: “I have had an opportunity to travel around the country and in my tour of duty I think that [medium-scale farm expansion] is happening countrywide. People have just realized that land has value and as such they are strategically positioning themselves to use it [land] now to earn a living or leave it for future investment or to use it as an inheritance for their children.” The insights from both the quantitative and qualitative analysis suggest that the changes in farm structure have been characterized by expansion of medium-scale farms. The quantitative analysis, however, demonstrates that these changes have further led to land concentration in fewer households both nationally and in the six districts analyzed. 38 Table 1: Changes in farm structure among small- and medium-scale farmers in Zambia (2001 – 2015) based on official national survey data Landholding Number of farms Change in % of total small- and Total landholdings (ha) % change in size categories number of medium-scale farms total farms (%) landholdings 2001 2015 2001-2015 2001 2015 2001 2015 2001-2015 National level 0-2 ha 597,310 704,776 17 15 8 1.1 1.0 -9 2-5 ha 343,372 466,051 36 27 23 3.2 3.3 3 5-10 ha 122,318 204,793 67 24 28 6.8 6.8 0 10-20 ha 35,535 73,154 106 16 22 13.4 13.2 -1 20-100 ha 12,897 22,226 72 18 19 36.8 41.0 11 Total 1,111,019 1,469,136 32 100 100 3.1 3.7 19 Six selected districts* 0-2 ha 63,811 81,050 27 11 5 2-5 ha 44,037 58,992 34 26 17 5-10 ha 16,339 39,953 145 28 34 10-20 ha 5,444 12,067 122 21 25 20-100 ha 1,174 2,920 149 14 20 Total 130,805 194,982 49 100 100 Source: CSO/MAL Crop Forecast Surveys (CFS) various years Notes * Six selected districts = Chibombo, Choma, Chongwe, Kalomo, Mpongwe and Mumbwa. ha = hectares 39 1.1 3.2 6.9 13.3 33.9 3.3 1.0 3.4 7.0 13.5 45.5 4.4 -9 6 1 2 34 33 2.4.2.2. Characteristics of medium-scale farms The ACS of medium-scale farms conducted in 2013 captured valuable information on the demographic characteristics of domestic land investors, as this is an important step to knowing who these farmers really are. Table 2 presents summary statistics on demographic characteristics of medium-scale farmers by comparing them based on three modes of entry to this scale of operation. About 41 percent of the respondents indicated that they achieved medium-scale farming status through farming from a family acquired farm while those who achieved this scale of operation either through non-family acquired farm or non-farm income accounted for 43 and 16 percent of the respondents respectively. A number of key lessons emerge from the comparison presented in Table 2. First, medium-scale farm owners who enter through non-farm income sources are on average older (53 years) than those entering through farming from family acquired farms (49 years) or those entering through farming from non-family acquired farms (50 years). Second, medium-scale farm owners in the non-farm income source category are more likely to have held a salaried job other than farming than those entering through alternative means. Third, more than two thirds of respondents who achieved medium-scale farming either through non-family acquired farms or non-farm income sources are more likely to have been born outside the areas where they own agricultural land. On the other hand, less than 45 percent of medium-scale farm owners who entered farming through family acquired farms were born outside the areas where they own agricultural land. Fourth, while we are cognizant of the fact that Zambia has undergone shifts in the generational composition of its population, the results still suggest that more than 75 percent of land acquisitions by domestic land investors for all three modes of land acquisition have happened during the last two periods (1990 – 99 and 2000 – later). 40 Table 2: Demographic characteristics of medium–scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia by mode of land acquisition Mode of land acquisition 1 2 3 Full sample % Cases 41 43 16 100 % Men 90 91 89 90 Respondent’s marital status Single (%) 2 2 0 2 Monogamous marriage (%) 59 64 81 65 Polygamous marriage (%) 27 27 8 24 Divorced (%) 4 2 3 3 Widowed (%) 7 5 8 6 Age (years) 49 50 53 50 Years of education of head 9 9 10 9 Have held a salaried job other than farming (%) 31 44 66 42 Parents to the head owns/owned land (%) 89 90 80 88 Where was the head born? Born in the area (%) 56 34 31 42 Not born in the area but settled and live in the 42 57 58 51 area (%) Not born in the area, acquired farm in the area 2 9 11 7 but spend most of time elsewhere (%) When did HH head acquire land? 1969 or earlier (%) 2 2 0 2 1970 – 79 (%) 5 3 7 5 1980 – 89 (%) 15 15 12 14 1990 – 99 (%) 33 31 33 32 2000 or later (%) 45 49 48 47 Notes Source: Agricultural Commercialization Survey of medium-scale farms in Zambia (2013) Mode of entry: (1) Achieved through farming from family acquired farm; (2) achieved through farming from non-family acquired farm; (3) achieved through non-farm income The qualitative part of this study investigated the origins of medium-scale farm owners. Although the general consensus by all 48 key informants interviewed was that a sizeable proportion of medium-scale farmers are individuals who are considered local, they acknowledged that there has also been an increase in the number of medium-scale farmers 41 coming from other parts of Zambia.2 From the in-depth interviews, three main categories of “non-local” medium-scale farmers were identified. The first group consists of medium-scale farm owners who have retired from salaried jobs based either in the nearest or outside district town. These farmers have been able to acquire land through established social networks. The second group of medium-scale farm owners consists of those migrating from areas with a number of limitations such as land availability constraints, land degradation and climate change, and lack of important infrastructure to support agricultural expansion. The third group of medium-scale farms is individuals working in urban areas that have acquired land and started farming. One of the national level stakeholder respondents ably described the third group in this manner: “It is not only indigenous people coming from a given community that own medium-scale farms; it is also people like us [professionals/working class]. When one goes for work [field visits in some of these communities], community members usually make offers to sell land.” In sum, findings from both the quantitative and qualitative analysis suggest that the expansion of medium-scale farms in Zambia is not only characterized by farm owners who are local to the community but individuals migrating from other parts of the country. Moreover, individuals who have had or still have access to wage income have also driven the expansion in medium-scale farms and that this surge in land acquisitions has gathered momentum in the last 20-25 years. 2 A farmer is considered local if he or she has family ties in an area and is most likely to have ethnic ties to people in that settlement. A household head is local if he/she is CONSIDERED local. In many cases people will consider themselves as non-local if they are denied certain benefits as a result of having migrated into the area. In other cases migrants will still consider themselves as local if they feel that they have been accepted into the community and have the same basic rights as other residents (CSO, MAL, and IAPRI 2012, p.77). 42 2.4.2.3. Agricultural land ownership by urban-based households Anecdotal evidence in Zambia suggests that urban-based households have also been a major factor in farm structure changes unfolding in the country. With limited data, however, studies looking at farm structure in Zambia have generally just hypothesized that the rapid expansion in domestic land investors and hence farm structure change could also be associated with urban based households. Only recently did Jayne et al. (forthcoming) empirically assess the extent to which urban-based households control agricultural land in six sub-Saharan countries including Zambia using the Demographic Health Surveys. Using the Zambian DHS data collected in 2007 and 2013/14, the current study adapts the analysis conducted in the aforementioned study but further extends it to show the following: (1) changes in the proportion of agricultural landholdings held by urban households by landholding size categories; (2) changes in average landholding, in hectares, held by urban based households, and; (3) how these changes link to the rapid expansion of domestic land investors. Results presented in Table 3 suggest that although the number of households who stated that they own agricultural land between 2007 and 2013/14 seemed to have reduced, the proportion of agricultural land that is controlled by urban households has increased during the same period. When disaggregated by landholding size categories, the results show that the change in the proportion of agricultural land controlled by urban-based households has decreased for farms below ten hectares, marginally increased for farms between 10 and 20 hectares but significantly increased for farms above 20 hectares. In terms of average landholding by urban households analyzed by landholding size categories, the results indicate a marginal reduction, marginal increase, modest increase and significant increase for farms in the 0-2 hectares, 2-10 hectares, 10-20 hectares and 20-100 hectares range respectively. The findings in Table 3 lends 43 credence to the view that urban-based households have been playing a key role in the control of agricultural farmland in Zambia. It is, however, interesting that the level of control in terms of landholding size is more likely to lead to an increase in medium-scale farms and a probable reduction in small-scale farms primarily owned by rural based households. Table 3: Summary statistics of agricultural land ownership of urban based households in Zambia (2007 – 2013/14) 2007 2013/14 Change (A) (B) (B – A) Number of households interviewed 7,164 15,920 % of urban households owning agricultural land 27.4 24.8 -2.6 % of rural households owning agricultural land 88.3 88.1 -0.2 % of all households owning agricultural land 67.2 61.7 -5.5 % of total agricultural landholdings held by 19.5 26.6 7.1 urban households % of total agricultural landholdings held by urban households by landholding categories 0-2 ha 2.9 0 -2.9 2-5 ha 2.2 0.7 -1.5 5-10 ha 2.5 1.7 -0.8 10-20 ha 2.6 2.8 0.2 20-100 ha 9.4 21.3 11.9 Average agricultural landholding size (ha) held by urban households by landholding categories 0-2 ha 0.2 0 -0.2 2-5 ha 3.9 4.0 0.1 5-10 ha 8.6 8.9 0.3 10-20 ha 15.4 16.9 1.5 20-100 ha 52.7 63.5 10.8 Source: Demographic Health Surveys (2007, 2013/14). Notes: Households with landholding above 95 hectares were reclassified as owning 95 hectares because the DHS did not collect actual landholding data from such households. ha = hectares 44 2.4.3. Agricultural land use in the context of farm structure change To understand how land use has evolved in the context of farm structure change, the current study examined available quantitative data by generating the following statistics: (1) average size of area cultivated by landholding size; (2) average proportion of uncultivated area by landholding size, and; (3) average proportion of uncultivated land used for grazing by mode of entry into medium-scale farming. Results for (1) and (2) are reported in Table 4 and those for (3) are reported in Table 5. Table 4: Comparison of cultivated and uncultivated agricultural land across landholding size categories in Zambia (2012 – 2015) Landholding size categories Year 0-2 ha 2-5 ha 5-10 ha 10-20 ha 20-100 Full ha sample Number of respondents 2012 4020 3002 1244 440 133 8839 2015 3388 2589 1242 492 223 7934 Landholding (ha) 2012 0.9 3.1 6.9 13.4 42.6 3.8 2015 1.0 3.2 7.0 13.5 44.6 4.7 Area cultivated (ha) 2012 1.1 2.4 4.5 6.3 6.5 2.3 2015 1.1 2.4 4.0 5.6 6.3 2.4 Area uncultivated (ha) 2012 0.1 0.7 2.3 7.1 36.0 1.5 2015 0.2 1.0 3.2 8.1 37.3 2.4 Maize area planted (%) 2012 64 55 57 58 59 59 2015 63 58 58 59 59 60 % Uncultivated land 2012 13 22 34 53 85 40 2015 16 30 45 60 84 52 Source: Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Surveys (2012, 2015) Note: ha = hectares 45 Table 5: Characteristics of uncultivated land by medium-scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia Full Mode of entry into medium-scale sample farming 1 2 3 % Cases 100 41 43 16 Uncultivated land: Fallow (%) 38 44 32 38 Forested (%) 42 32 54 35 Rented out (%) 6 1 4 20 Grazing/pastures (%) 14 23 10 7 Source: Agricultural Commercialization Survey of Medium-Scale farms in Zambia (2013) Mode of entry: (1) Achieved through farming from family acquired farm; (2) achieved through farming from non-family acquired farm; (3) achieved through non-farm income Results show that the average number of hectares cultivated increases with landholding size and this is true across the two rounds of RALS data. The cropping system is dominated by maize with an average of 60 percent of area cultivated planted to maize. This dominance of maize production is strikingly similar across all landholding size categories and has also remained consistent over the two survey years. The proportion of area that is uncultivated is increasing with landholding size and this is evident across both survey years. In 2012, for example, households in the 0-2 hectare category only had an average of 13 percent uncultivated land while about 85 percent of total landholding for households in the 20-100 hectare category was uncultivated. This similar pattern emerged in 2015 where households in the 0-2 hectare category had 16 percent uncultivated land but those in the 20-100 hectare category had 84 percent uncultivated land. The fact that farmers with relatively large landholdings cultivate less than 20 percent of the land they own suggests that a lot of land is being left idle by this category of farmers. However, one has to be cautious with interpreting these results since there is a possibility that some of the uncultivated land particularly by medium-scale farms is dedicated to animal grazing and not necessarily left idle. 46 To establish whether farmers apportion most of their uncultivated land for animal grazing purposes, the current study further analyzed the medium-scale farmer survey conducted in selected districts of Zambia. The survey asked the respondents to give estimates of how they apportion uncultivated land based on the following categories: (1) fallow land; (2) forested land; (3) land rented out, and; (4) grazing/pasture land. Results reported in Table 5 show that more than 70 percent of uncultivated land is either fallow or is forested across the three modes of entry into medium-scale farming. The proportion of uncultivated land that is dedicated to grazing animals is only about 23 percent, 10 percent and 7 percent for farms categorized based on the three respective modes of entry (farming from family acquired farm, farming from non-family acquired farm, and non-farm income sources). These results affirm the conclusion that most medium-scale farms leave idle a greater proportion of their land. The study also explored stakeholder perceptions of changes in land use in the context of farm structure change. The line of inquiry specifically focused on getting the views of all key informants in relation to changes in crop and livestock production in the last five to ten years. The majority of all respondent groups agreed that crop production patterns had changed over the last decade. The consensus by most respondents, who perceived that crop production patterns had changed, indicated that crop production had now become maize centric. As one respondent put it, “… in the 80’s and early 90’s, farmers were growing a diversity of crops. People grew different types of crops including those mainly grown for the fertility of the soil but now it is just maize. I have seen the mono-cropping culture resurfacing.” Some respondents, however, highlighted changes in cropping patterns, which have witnessed a growth particularly in oilseeds (e.g. soya beans) as a consequence of crop diversification efforts promoted by either the government or the private sector. 47 The qualitative research revealed a number of reasons for the changes in cropping patterns, but the following were mentioned the most by the interview participants. First, the respondents argued that favorable market conditions for maize supported by government policies have been key to the resurfacing of the maize monoculture. One of the favorable market conditions cited included near proximity of maize buying points (Food Reserve Agency (FRA) or private traders) to maize producing households. In addition, a number of respondents stated that the low gross margins in some of the traditional cash crops such as cotton has played a role in farmers moving back to maize production. Second, the respondents also mentioned labor constraint as a factor that has contributed to producers moving away from more labor-intensive crops (e.g. cotton) to less labor-intensive crops. Third, some respondents attributed the shift to other crops such as oilseeds to changes in the environment and climate. Respondent views about livestock production also suggested that production patterns have evolved in the last decade. Four notable developments pertaining to livestock production emerged during the key informant interviews. First, while cattle production is still common particularly in regions where it has been part and parcel of tradition, several communities have embraced small ruminant production such as goats. One respondent gave an interesting illustration of how things have changed in his community in terms of goat production. He said it as follows: “when I was growing up, when you introduced a goat in the area, dogs would think it’s a wild animal and they would even catch it. But now, almost everyone has a goat.” Second, a number of communities have become more proactive in terms of disease control compared to two decades or so ago when they were more reactive, waiting for government to do something about animal diseases. Third, livestock production in some communities has also seen a shift to more intensive methods of livestock production such as use 48 of feedlots. Fourth, the growing urban population and change in consumption patterns have also led to the growth of poultry production in Zambia. 2.4.4. Land titling and markets in the context of farm structure change To gain further insights into the effects of changes in farm structure in rural Zambia, the current study used the various survey data and stakeholder perceptions to analyze the extent and pattern of titling of agricultural land and farmer participation in land markets. We discuss the quantitative and qualitative findings for each of these attributes in turn. 2.4.4.1 Extent of land titling To assess the extent and pattern of land titling in the context of farm structure changes, the current study examined both the survey and qualitative data assembled. Using the 2015 round of the Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Survey (RALS), Table 6 reports information on tenure status disaggregated by landholding size. Seven tenure status categories were reported in the 2015 RALS: (1) state land with title; (2) state land with title in the process; (3) state land with no title; (4) former customary land with title; (5) former customary land with title in the process; (6) customary land with no title, and; (7) customary land with chief certificate. The first three categories refer to land not under the jurisdiction of traditional leaders differing only on account of the land owner having either processed title deeds or has commenced the process of obtaining title deeds or has no title deeds at all. The fourth, fifth and sixth categories refer to land under the jurisdiction of traditional leaders differing only on account of the stage of processing title deeds similar to the case of state land. For the chief's certificate (category seven), it refers to land under the jurisdiction of traditional leaders except in this case; a particular chief gives a certificate of occupancy to any individual requesting for it to 49 abate conflicts in future. While this is a practice that existed prior to the 1995 Lands Act, it has increased of late. The following can be summarized from Table 6 about the extent and pattern of land titling. First, the proportion of either state land or former customary land that is with title or is in the process of being titled is clearly an increasing function of landholding size. For instance, only four percent of land (both state and customary land) controlled by households in the 0-2 hectares category is either under title or is in the process of being titled. On the other hand, more than 20 percent of land (both state and customary land) controlled by households in the 20-100 hectares category is either titled or undergoing the process of titling. Second, households with large landholding sizes are more likely to process the traditional landholding certificate granted by a chief than households with small landholdings. About eight percent of households in the 0-2 hectares category have acquired traditional landholding certificates while 17 percent of households in the 20-100 hectares category have managed to process these certificates. The traditional landholding certificate initiative has been popularized by civil society organizations like the Zambia Land Alliance (ZLA) in collaboration with bilateral partners like the USAID’s Tenure and Global Climate Change (TGCC) project. The aim of this initiative has been to provide landowners on customary land acquire formal documentation in order to minimize land disputes. The current study suggests that households with larger landholdings are the ones taking advantage of this initiative aimed at helping vulnerable households who are most likely land constrained. 50 Table 6: Extent of land titling by small- and medium-scale farmers in Zambia by landholding size categories Landholding size categories 0-2 2-5 5-10 10-20 20 -100 Full ha ha ha ha ha sample Number of respondents 3388 2589 1242 492 223 7934 % Land owned by tenure status State land with title 2 State land with title in the process 1 State land with no title 12 Former customary land with title 1 Customary land with title in the 0 process Customary land with no title 76 Chief certificate 8 Source: Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Surveys (2015) Note: ha = hectares 3 1 7 1 1 2 1 8 2 2 4 2 11 3 1 10 3 19 6 3 5 2 12 3 1 82 5 79 6 69 10 42 17 67 10 The qualitative research phase of the study elicited respondents’ views about reasons why the extent of land titling has remained low especially among smallholder farmers. Three main explanations emerged. First, the farmer in-depth interviews generally revealed a ubiquitous lack of awareness of existing provisions that allow individuals such as smallholders living in customary land areas, to process title for agricultural land under their control. Interestingly, the interviews also revealed that smallholder farmers who are aware about these provisions have not proceeded with getting title because such farmers have not understood the process involved. Second, respondents from all categories of key informants suggested that traditional leaders have continued to express reservations about approving conversion of customary land to titled land—a key policy introduced in the 1995 Lands Act. According to the respondents, traditional leaders have continued to contend that the aforementioned provision threatens to shift the balance of power away from chiefs/headmen and render them redundant; customary land administration by and large embodies authority of traditional leaders. The following statements 51 summarize the views of key respondents interviewed about whether traditional leaders allow community members to freely apply for title deeds: “We discourage them [community members] because when you get title for the land the headman loses authority over the land. We don’t like the issue of the title deeds” (headman, August 2014). “I have not [applied for title deeds]. I found it difficult because headmen fear to give title deeds because they know they won’t have power [since] everyone will be a headman on his own” (medium-scale farmer, August 2014). “No [we have not applied for title deeds]. This is because we are afraid that the village headman may feel as though his powers are being threatened” (small-scale farmer, August 2014). The third explanation that was also widely mentioned by key informants as the reason for the low extent of land titling among smallholders had to do with the lengthy and bureaucratic process of obtaining title. Other than technical delays such as getting survey diagrams of land in question promptly processed, there are other administrative hurdles that exacerbate bureaucracy. This is because a number of aspects pertaining to processing of titles are not decentralized and require approval by government officials based at the Ministry of Lands headquarters in Lusaka. Unfortunately, this issue of the Government of the Republic of Zambia perpetuating a highly centralized system of carrying out functions pertaining to land has been an issue of concern for decades (Bruce et al., 1995). The undesirable outcome of this lengthy and bureaucratic process is that documents sometimes go missing somewhere between local government authorities at district level and the Ministry of Lands. In such cases, applicants have been forced to restart the process of applying for title. Ultimately, the lengthy process has proven to be quite expensive and has effectively eliminated a number of smallholder farmers from applying for title deeds. 52 2.4.4.2. Extent of participation in land markets The study also examined (both quantitatively and qualitatively) the extent of participation in land markets particularly in customary land areas. Using data from the two waves of RALS, the study quantitatively estimated the proportion of rural households that thought that market based land transfers were possible in customary land areas. The qualitative data analysis, on the other hand, explored in detail the evolution of land markets in the context of farm structure change. The current laws of Zambia allow for conversion of land under customary land tenure to leasehold tenure (Government of the Republic of Zambia (GRZ), 1995). This law in turn allows owners of “former customary land with title” to participate in market-based land transfers. This study assessed whether or not it is possible to buy or sell “customary land with no title” as this has implications for changes in farm structure. Figure 1 presents results of the proportions of rural households that stated that market based land transfers were possible for parcels of land categorized as “customary land with no title”. A Chi-square test was used to see the relationship between the aforementioned proportions and our five-landholding size categories. The test results are reported at the bottom of Figure 1 for each year of the RALS survey data. 53 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 31% 28% 26% 22% 22% 21% 25% 25% 5 - 10 ha 10 - 20 ha 29% 22% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 0 - 2 ha 2 - 5 ha 2012 > 20 ha 2015 Figure 1: Proportion of rural households by landholding size categories stating that market based land transfers are possible in customary areas Source: Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Surveys (2012, 2015) Note: ha = hectares Pearson Chi-square test within years: 2012—Pearson chi-square, F-stat = 22.3, p-value = 0.000 2015—Pearson chi-square, F-stat = 14.9, p-value = 0.005 The following findings emerged. First, more than 20 percent of households across different landholding size categories thought that it was possible to buy or sell land in customary land areas. Second, landowners with large landholding sizes were more likely to state that land under customary tenure could be transferred using markets. In 2012, for instance, more than 30 percent of landowners with landholding size greater than 20 hectares stated that it was possible to buy or sell land in customary land areas in comparison to 25 percent of landowners in the 0-2 hectare category. Based on the chi-square test results, these proportions are statistically different in both 2012 and 2015. Third, the proportion of households thinking that it was possible to buy or sell land in customary land areas was similar across the two survey years indicating that respondents’ views remained consistent between the two time periods. Put together, these three findings suggest that market based land transfers in customary land areas are happening despite 54 legal requirements that do not allow such transfers to take place. The outcome of these ‘vernacular’ land markets—a term borrowed from Chimhowu & Woodhouse (2006) of the categorization of land markets in customary land areas—is that they are likely to contribute to the increase in pace of land consolidation by elite domestic land investors. The information gathered through key informant interviews on land markets in customary land areas could be described as follows. First, the interviews provided more insights on whether land markets in customary land areas in Zambia exist and why. Second, the interviews asked respondents to explain their local understanding of the mode of land acquisition described as ‘allocated/given’ in most survey data collected from rural households. A follow up hypothetical question was asked to most of the respondents to consolidate the understanding of the aforementioned mode of land acquisition. The question was phrased as follows: “When an individual negotiates with the headman to have him/her allocate 50 hectares to that individual, and some money changes hands informally, would you still describe this mode of land acquisition as ‘allocated/given’?” The second set of questions was included to find out whether the mode of land acquisition categorized as ‘allocated/given’ inadvertently masks the full extent of informal land markets. The general view of the key informants interviewed for the study was that informal markets exist and are widespread in customary land areas in Zambia. Almost all of the informants interviewed seemed to suggest that renting of land has been the common feature of these emerging markets while selling or buying of land has been done in a subtler manner. The respondents gave the following reasons when asked to share their views of why land markets have emerged in customary land areas. On the supply side (renting out or selling land), most respondents indicated that some households living in customary land areas are too poor to 55 afford inputs to sustain agricultural production. Therefore, renting or selling part of their land allows them to meet input requirements as well as immediate consumption needs. On the demand side (renting in or buying land), some respondents argued that the improved economic fortunes associated with farming have attracted individuals from outside affected communities including urban-based households and hence the emergence of land markets. One respondent explained it this way: “people right now want to go into farming so we see a lot of people come to the village asking a person with a big piece of land to rent them land.” Farmer and community leader key informants were asked to explain their local understanding of the mode of land acquisition categorized as ‘allocated/given’ that is mainly associated with customary land. The consensus among the respondents was that when land is allocated or given, it implies that the recipient of the land does not pay a market value price. However, the tradition has been that after a person has been shown and given the land, they are expected to give a token of appreciation to the headman who showed them the location of the land in question. The respondents’ views to the follow up hypothetical question—whether the mode of land acquisition with an informal payment for a relatively large piece of land after negotiations with a headman, can still be considered as ‘allocated/given’—were evenly split. On the one hand, some respondents (both farmers and community leaders) still maintained that they would consider this mode of land acquisition as ‘allocated/given’ and that whatever amount of money is paid, is just a token of appreciation. The following statements summarize the views of the key respondents who had this view: “When someone comes to ask for land from the [village] headman and land is found to be available, the [village] headman shows the person the land who will then give a token of appreciation. So, the land is still given to him. The only thing he has done is to say thank you.” 56 “That is just to appreciate what the parent [headman] has done for you; the land is still given to you.” “Yes, I would still say it’s given. This is because it’s not selling as such. This is just part of the procedure that one has to follow; it’s just a token of appreciation.” The second group of respondents (also composed of both farmers and community leaders) used the following explanations to argue against the fact that the aforementioned mode of land acquisition could be considered as ‘allocated/given’. First, the key informants with this counterview explained that village headmen have devised a system of asking potential land seekers to pay for a unit of land similar to a market based system. Usually, when someone gives the headman a token of appreciation, the payment is in kind and not cash. Alternatively, if the token of appreciation is in cash form, it is generally small, not based on a pricing system similar to market based transactions and is determined by the person looking for land. However, if a headman uses a payment system reminiscent of a market-based system, the mode of land acquisition cannot be categorized as ‘allocated/given’ but ‘purchased’. One of the community leader informants described it this way: “there are those [headmen] who literally sell their land. They even have rates on a per hectare basis. For example, they would put the rate at ZMW5,000 [Zambian Kwacha] per hectare. That is selling and not “allocated/given.” Second, some key informants argued that because land has increasingly become scarce in a number of communities, the mode of land acquisition where land is allocated or given freely no longer exists. To a great extent, whether or not land is given freely is likely to vary by scarcity of land of a given location or region of the country. Key informants explained that cases where people were allocated land freely happened years back but this has not been the case in the last one to two decades. In this light, if an individual negotiates with a headman for a piece of land as large as 50 hectares, the exchange of land with money is part of the negotiation process. The 57 individual looking for land knows that they need to pay something close to market value to expedite the land allocation process. The key informant interviews further revealed that an individual seeking a relatively large piece of land diminished their chances of getting it if no payment was made to the headman. In sum, the qualitative research component of this study found that the extent of land markets in customary land areas has been expanding over the years and has been partly a consequence of those with money. One of the small-scale farmer respondents put it this way: “These days they just go through the village and approach people and ask if they can buy some land from them. And you know these days, if you have money it is easy to buy land.” 2.4.5. Level of agricultural commercialization The final set of analysis conducted in this study focused on understanding how farm structure in Zambia (using quantitative data) is associated with the level of agricultural commercialization especially in agricultural output markets as this has implications for rural development and economic growth. The analysis assessed production and sales data of farming households in Zambia using Crop Forecast Survey (CFS) data of small and medium-scale farming households for 2009, 2012 and 2014. To capture production and sales across the whole farm size continuum in Zambia, the analysis also included data from Large-Scale CFS data: an additional survey that is conducted by the CSO of farming households cultivating more than 20 hectares. Disaggregating the data by two landholding size categories— 5 hectares or less (smallscale farming households) and > 5 hectares (medium- and large-scale farming households)—the study specifically conducted the following analyses in line with the fifth study objective (to examine the relationship between farm structure change and level of agricultural commercialization). 58 First, given the important role of maize in Zambia’s agricultural sector, the study estimated maize production (Table 7) and marketed output (Table 8) separately across landholding sizes. Second, the study also estimated the gross value of production (Table 9) and marketed output (Table 10) of non-maize crops across landholding size categories. It was inevitable to use the gross value of production and marketed output because the study was aggregating production volumes of more than one non-maize crop. Third, the proportions of farms across landholding sizes categories (Table 11) were also estimated. According to results reported in Table 7 and 8 for maize production and marketed output, the following can be summarized. First, maize production in Zambia has increased across the years for both landholding size categories. Small-scale farming households produce more than 50 percent of total maize production. However, the proportion of total maize produced of farming households with five hectares and above has steadily increased during the five year period considered. For example, the proportion of national maize production (Table 7) of the aforementioned households was about 41 percent in 2009. In 2014, households in this category produced about 46 percent of total national maize production. Second, marketed maize output (Table 8) has also increased across the years for both landholding size categories. But, the proportion of national marketed output is greater for medium- and large-scale farms than that of small-scale farms. 59 Table 7: Maize production in Zambia by landholding size categories Year 0 – 5 ha > 5 ha Maize production (Thousand metric tons) 2009 1132 772 2012 1619 1334 2014 1809 1541 % of national maize production 2009 59.47 40.53 2012 54.84 45.16 2014 54 46 Source: CFS data (2009, 2012, 2014) Note: ha = hectares Table 8: Marketed maize output in Zambia by landholding size categories Year 0 – 5 ha > 5 ha Marketed maize output (Thousand metric tons) 2009 345 491 2012 785 850 2014 824 1088 % of total marketed maize output 2009 41.23 58.77 2012 48.01 51.99 2014 43.09 56.91 Source: CFS data (2009, 2012, 2014) Note: ha = hectares Table 9 and 10 report the gross value—in Zambia’s currency, Kwacha (ZMW)—of production and marketed output of non-maize crops produced by both landholding size categories. The results demonstrate that production and marketed output have both increased over the five-year period. While small-scale farms had a higher level of production relative to medium- and large-scale farms of non-maize crops in 2009, the gross value of production of the latter group exceeded that of former group in 2012 and 2014. This finding illustrates the increase in the role that relatively large farms in Zambia play in the production of crops outside the politically influenced maize production. Similar to maize marketing results reported above, gross value of marketed outputs of non-maize crops is higher for medium- and large-scale farms than that of small-scale farms. 60 In sum, although agriculture is still dominated by small-scale farms in Zambia (more than 80 percent as reported in Table 11), medium- and large-scale farms have steadily increased their share of national crop production especially non-maize crop production. In terms of crop marketing (maize and non-maize crop sales), small-scale farms continue to contribute to national marketed output. However, the level of participation in marketing of all crop types by mediumand large-scale farming households suggests that relatively large farms have an important role in Zambia’s agricultural growth and development. Table 9: Gross value of production (crops only) in Zambia by landholding size categories Year 0 – 5 ha > 5 ha Gross value of crop production (million ZMW) 2009 2810 2560 2012 3750 3920 2014 3880 4260 % of total gross value of crop production 2009 52.33 47.67 2012 48.89 51.11 2014 47.67 52.33 Source: CFS data (2009, 2012, 2014) Note: ha = hectares Table 10: Gross value of marketed crops in Zambia by landholding size categories Year 0 – 5 ha > 5 ha Gross value of marketed crops (million ZMW) 2009 1050 2200 2012 1880 3310 2014 1730 3120 % of total gross value of marketed crops 2009 32.11 67.89 2012 36.22 63.78 2014 35.67 64.33 Source: CFS data (2009, 2012, 2014) Note: ha = hectares 61 Table 11: Proportion of farms in Zambia by landholding size categories Year 0 – 5 ha (%) > 5 ha (%) 2009 89 11 2012 84 16 2014 82 18 Source: CFS data (2009, 2012, 2014) Note: ha = hectares 2.5. Conclusions and policy implications Although the rise in foreign owned large-scale farms has somewhat altered the agricultural landscape in SSA, recent evidence has also shown that the rise in farmland acquisitions by domestic medium-scale investor farms—between 5 and 100 hectares—represents a more significant change in farm structure. In Zambia, recent estimates have shown that medium-scale farms now account for more land than the holdings in the entire small-scale sector. In view of the relative underperformance of small-scale agriculture in SSA that has been documented by a number of scholars, one important question that has emerged is this: is the change in farm structure characterized by the rapid expansion of medium-scale investor farms, signaling an alternative pathway for agricultural and rural development? This study investigated the causes and consequences of the rise of domestic mediumscale investor farms in Zambia using a mixed-methods approach. By locating the study within the broader political economy and new institutional economics literature, the study gleaned some important findings. Three main causes of farm structure change associated with domestic medium-scale investor farms emerged from the key informant interviews. First, society’s perception of agriculture has changed from being viewed as a domain for those who are poor to a domain that is seen as a profitable sector. Second, the governance of customary land has undergone some changes that have led to the development of informal land markets contrary to established norms. 62 Third, public spending in agriculture has had the unintended consequence of shifting support to relatively better capitalized medium-scale investor farms at the expense of small-scale farm households. Put together, all the three drivers identified by this study had contributed to the rise of domestic medium-scale investor farms and change in farm structure in Zambia. The consequences of the change in farm structure are closely associated with agricultural land concentration, perpetuation of a maize monoculture, accumulation of idle land among medium-scale investor farms and increasing land constraints among small-scale farmers. Further, the evidence pointed to low land titling especially among small-scale farms, a growing informal land rental and sales market and a skewed level of agricultural commercialization. These findings point to three main conclusions. First, while there are some positives that can be drawn from the identified causes of farm structure change, growth in Zambian agriculture is not being driven by organic growth of existing small-scale farmers. Rather, a considerable number of entrants in the medium-scale farming sector are either local elites with connections to traditional leaders responsible for land administration in customary land or urban-based Zambians with the financial capacity to acquire land. If small-scale farmers are not growing organically, stated public policy goals of addressing household food security and reducing rural poverty (currently standing at 78 percent headcount) will be difficult to achieve. As a result, this threatens prospects of achieving overall economic development through agricultural development. Second, the system of land acquisition is unintentionally being rigged in favor of the wealthy even though the provisions of the 1995 Lands Act, which allow for conversion of customary land to titled land, are not designed to distort things. The prevailing system has implications for prospects of small-scale agricultural expansion especially when recent evidence 63 clearly shows that small-scale farmers face serious land constraints (Chisanga & Chapoto, 2015). Third, the limited participation of small-scale farmers in agricultural output markets presents another set of challenges. Our analysis demonstrates that although more than 80 percent of farmers in Zambia fall within the small-scale farming category, approximately two-thirds of gross value of marketed agricultural crops is by medium- and large-scale farms. This suggests that small-scale farmers remain predominantly subsistent farmers. While this is not a problem in terms of addressing food security concerns if the level of subsistence enhances self-sufficiency, limited participation of the majority of farmers in output markets may weaken prospects of a vibrant commercialized agricultural sector, exacerbate high levels of poverty and rural unemployment and further frustrate rural development efforts. Policy strategies should therefore address not only the inequalities that exist in terms of land access and ownership but also address the bottlenecks associated with obtaining title or indeed traditional landholding certificates. Although there is considerable debate on the link between agricultural productivity and tenure status (Place, 2009), we demonstrate that the process of obtaining title is mainly being exploited by farmers who are categorized as mediumscale farmers. If small-scale farmers are not part of this process, there is a danger that, with time, some households may become landless. To enhance small-scale farmers’ role in agricultural markets, policy should also endeavor to promote research and development initiatives that would uplift their production levels and generate surplus for markets. Obviously, this strategy should not be maize centric but should extend to other crops or livestock suitable for small-scale agriculture. 64 APPENDIX 65 Figure 2: Map of Zambia showing location of ACS households 66 Appendix A1: Key informant interview guides Participant’s Code #_________________________________________ Place: ____________________________________________ Date: ________________________ Time______________________ Hello [Participants name] My name is Chewe Nkonde currently pursuing my doctoral studies at Michigan State University (MSU) in the United States of America (USA). Thank you for taking time to meet with me and participate in this interview. This interview is part of a study that seeks to understand stakeholder views on the constraints affecting and opportunities influencing agricultural development in the context of rising large landholders (emergent farmers) in Zambia. You have been identified as a key informant among different stakeholders, which includes farmers, traditional authorities, district officials, and stakeholders and thought leaders at national level. In sum, I anticipate to interview about 48 key informants. This component of the broad study is designed to address the following main objectives: 1. Assess the direct and indirect impacts of emergent farms on income growth and distribution 2. Examine how land accumulation in agriculture is changing over time and the implications for small-scale agriculture 3. Characterize land use of small-scale and emergent farmers and explore the factors that influence land utilization 4. Explore the institutional changes (formal or informal) that are contributing to the rise of emergent farmers The key informant interviews are designed to supplement the data collected from a survey that I coordinated called the Agricultural Commercialization Survey (ACS). The ACS for emergent farming households in Zambia was conducted in 2011 and 2013 in six districts namely Chibombo, Choma, Chongwe, Kalomo, Mpongwe and Mumbwa. A total of 482 households participated in the survey. Overall, this study is part of the requirement for my doctoral program. Ultimately, I expect to present the results from this study in Zambia and East and Southern Africa to promote discussions among African policy makers and local analysts regarding how land policy in Africa can be harmonized more compatibly with other national policy objectives. Therefore, your voluntary participation in this interview will be very much appreciated. Today’s interview should take about one hour to complete. All questions have been designed to help me draw on your knowledge to help enrich the quality of my research. A follow up interview may be requested if more information is desired. It is important to know that there are no right or wrong answers. I just want to know what your views about the topic are with respect to your farm, community or the whole country. Your participation is voluntary and you may choose not to participate at all, refuse to answer certain questions, or stop your participation at 67 any time without any consequences. If you are interested, you will be provided with a final document of the whole research at the end of the study. To ensure that I do not miss anything we talk about, I would like to audio-record our conversation. All your responses will be kept confidential and your privacy will be protected to the maximum extent allowable by law. All reports and publications resulting from this interview will be written and shared using pseudonyms and code numbers. If you have any questions or concerns regarding your participation in this study, you may contact my dissertation advisors: 1. (Major advisor) Robert B. Richardson, PhD, Associate Professor, Department of Community Sustainability, Michigan State University, 480 Wilson Road, Rm 305, East Lansing, MI 48824-1222, Tel: +1(517)-355-9533, e-mail: rbr@msu.edu 2. (Advisor) Thomas S. Jayne, PhD, Professor, Department of Agricultural, Food and Resource and Economics, Michigan State University, 446 W. Circle Dr., Rm 317c, Justin S. Morrill Hall of Agriculture East Lansing, mi 48824-1039 Tel: +1(517)-604-1572 Fax: +1(517)-432-1800 email: jayne@anr.msu.edu At this point, do you have any questions? Yes No [if yes, answer questions and proceed] Is it okay for you if I audiotape our interview? May I begin? Yes Yes No No [If no, thank and end] Interview guide 1: Questions for medium-scale farmers (Emergent farmers) Theme 1: Farmer categorization, land access and distribution 1. In the survey we conducted in 2013, we classified you as an emergent farmer based on the size of land you owned at the time of the survey (we defined emergent farmers as those owning between 5 and 100 hectares of land). Do you agree with our assessment of your status? Please elaborate on why you agree or disagree. 2. Why did you become a farmer? 3. Based on our definition of an emergent farmer, what is your assessment of the number of emergent farmers in your community? Has the number increased or reduced in the last 20 years? 10 years? What do you think has led to this increase (decrease) in the number of emergent farmers in your community? 4. If someone wants land in this area, is there land available? 5. About 62% of emergent farming households interviewed in 2013 indicated “allocated/given” as the mode of land acquisition for the land they owned. Could you please clarify to me what “allocated/given” really means? Is the land given freely without any cash or in-kind transaction? 6. When an individual negotiates with the headman to have him/her allocate 50 hectares to him/her, and some money changes hands informally. Would you still describe this mode of land acquisition as “allocated/given”? 68 7. In the 2013 survey, the largest proportion (49%) of emergent farmers, by our definition, said that they achieved that status through farming from non-family acquired farm and using nonfarm income sources. Is it difficult to achieve emergent farmer status by farming from a family acquired farm (growing from small-scale to emergent farmer status)? Please share your thoughts with us on this. 8. What are the primary barriers, from your experience, for achieving a larger scale of operation? 9. Are there any other reasons that hinder some farmers from graduating to emergent farmer status? Theme 2: Land use and drivers of utilization 1. How many crops do you cultivate in a serious way? (Ignore small garden plots, etc.) 2. Please describe at most three main crops that you have consistently planted in the last 3-4 farming seasons. 3. Has the choice of three main crops that you have planted in the last 3-4 seasons changed from what you planted in the first 3-4 seasons when you began farming? If there has been a change, please explain what has led to this change. 4. Do you anticipate changing your current three main crop portfolio in the near future? 5. What crops or alternative land use do you envisage to change to? Please explain why. 6. What are some of the main factors that determine how you utilize the land that you own? Explain how each factor influences land utilization. 7. Results from the 2013 Survey indicated that only 6.2% of emergent farming households cultivated the entire land owned. Are you in the category of farmers who usually do not cultivate the entire land they own? 8. In what state is the land that you leave uncultivated? Is it cleared? Forested? Fallow rotation? Theme 3: Direct and indirect effects of emergent farms on household income growth and distribution 1. What is your current main source of income? 2. Has this been your main source of income since you became an adult? 3. If farming is your current main source of income, what is your assessment of your annual gross farm income from the time you started farming? Has your income been increasing or decreasing from one year to the next since you started farming? Please explain. 4. What are some of the favorable factors that have contributed to your ability to sustain an increase in annual gross farm income? 5. Do you hire labor from surrounding small farms to work on your farm? 6. Is this primarily piece work/ganyu, salaried-casual or salaried-formal? 7. How do you hire and how often? 8. Why do you hire labor? 9. Why don’t you hire people permanently? 10. What do you think of the quality of hired labor? 11. Are people readily available from small farms to work on your farm? 12. Please explain whether your level of agricultural production (crop and livestock) has increased, decreased or remained unchanged in the last 5-10 years? Explain why it has increased, decreased or remained unchanged. 69 13. How do you interact with small-scale farmers in your vicinity? Do you provide some form of training or knowledge transfer to them? Explain how and the type of training. 14. Do you buy agricultural output from small-scale farmers in your locality? Please explain how and specify the types of output. 15. Do you sell agricultural inputs and services to small-scale farmers surrounding you? Please explain the terms of such transactions. Theme 4: Technology choices 1. More than 96% of emergent farming households stated that they used either animal or mechanized draft power for land preparation during the 2012/2013 farming season in the communities we visited including yours. Which of the two methods do you prefer using and why? 2. Are there hiring services for animal draft power in your community? 3. Do you provide these [animal draft power] services? 4. Do you hire out when you have completed all your tasks on your farm or do you do it whenever somebody asks for your services? 5. Why do you hire out your oxen draft power? 6. In general, do you think that the use of animal draft power for land preparation has increased in your community in the last 5-10 farming seasons? 7. Are there tractor-hiring services for land preparation and other farming activities in your community? 8. Do you provide these [tractor hiring] services? 9. Do you use these [tractor hiring] services? 10. Why do you use the tractor hiring service? 11. In general, do you think that the use of mechanized draft power (tractors) for land preparation has increased in your community in the last 5-10 farming seasons? And among what type of farmers? 12. Can farmers access tractor-hiring services on credit? 13. Are you aware of any initiatives (government, farmer organizations, donors, NGO’s, private sector) that have been recently promoted in your community to enhance tractor use as a source of power for land preparation? 14. If you are aware of such initiatives, what categories of farmers do they target? Please explain why they target those categories. 15. Have you been consistent with using improved seed varieties, inorganic fertilizers and other agricultural intensification technologies over the last 5-10 farming seasons? Could you say your use of such inputs has increased or reduced over the stated period? Theme 5: Institutions and policies 1. Are you aware of any government policies designed to empower landowners with respect to tenure security? Have you heard of the lands act? 2. Have formal land rental and sales markets become common in your community? 3. Have informal land rental and sales markets become common in your community? 4. Are you aware of any government policies designed to empower farmers with respect to enhancing farm productivity, food security and marketing of surplus production? 5. What are these policies and could you describe some of their key provisions? 70 6. Have you been a consistent beneficiary of these policies designed to improve farm productivity, food security and marketing of surplus production? 7. Does the presence of emergent farms (including yours) influence the types of services that are available locally (e.g. vets, mechanics, transportation services, extension, input suppliers)? Please distinguish this effect in the village versus impacts on services available at the nearest district. 8. Do larger farms (including yours) attract better/different types of buyers of agricultural output? If so, why? If not, why 9. Do you belong to a farmer group (association/cooperative)? 10. If yes, how long have you been a member? 11. Is the membership restricted to farmers at your scale of operation and larger? Or, do you have small-scale farmers who are members? 12. What are some of the benefits that you get from being a member? 13. What are the rules and norms governing land administration (allocation and provision of tenure security) in your community? 14. If you were involved in off-farm employment prior to settling in this area, to what extent did the economic changes in the 1990’s when the Zambian economy was liberalized compel you to acquire land and become a farmer? Please explain. Interview guide 2: Questions for small-scale farmers Theme 1: Farmer categorization, land access and distribution 1. In your community, has the number of farmers owning between 5 and 100 hectares of land (aka emergent farmers by our definition) increased or reduced in the last 10 years? 2. What do you think has led to this increase (decrease) in the number of emergent farmers? 3. Why did you become a farmer? 4. Why did you acquire land? 5. About 73% of small-scale farming households interviewed in 2012 indicated “allocated/given” as the mode of land acquisition for the land they owned. Could you please clarify to me what “allocated/given” really means? Is the land given freely without any cash or in-kind transaction? 6. What are your plans with respect to growing from small-scale farming to emergent farming? 7. Is it difficult to achieve emergent farmer status by growing from small-scale farming? Please share your thoughts with us on this. 8. Does the presence/growth of large farmers in this area make it harder for small farmers to access/acquire additional land here? (In other words, is the growth of larger holdings contributing to scarcity?) 9. Do large farmers bring benefits to small farmers in this area? If so, what are these benefits? (Could be: new farming technologies/knowledge, wage-income opportunities, traction services, transport services, aggregation/bulking opportunities, lower cost of inputs, etc….) Theme 2: Land use and drivers of utilization 1. How many crops do you cultivate in a serious way? (Ignore small garden plots, etc.) 2. Please describe at most three main crops that you have consistently planted in the last 3-4 farming seasons. 71 3. Has the choice of three main crops that you have planted in the last 3-4 seasons changed from what you planted in the first 3-4 seasons when you began farming? If there has been a change, please explain what has led to this change. 4. What are some of the main factors that determine how you utilize the land that you own? Explain how each factor influences land utilization. 5. Do you anticipate changing your current three main crop portfolio in the near future? 6. What crops or alternative land use do you envisage to change to? Please explain why. Theme 3: Direct and indirect effects of emergent farms on income growth and distribution 1. What is your current main source of income? 2. Has this been your main source of income since you became an adult? 3. If farming is your current main source of income, what is your assessment of your annual gross farm income from the time you started farming? 4. Has your income been increasing or decreasing from one year to the next since you started farming? Please explain. 5. What are some of the favorable factors that have contributed to your ability to sustain an increase in annual gross farm income? 6. Are there wage-earning opportunities on emergent farms in this area? 7. Do you or any of your family members earn income from this source? 8. Do they pay well/fairly? 9. Is this primarily piece work/ganyu, salaried-casual or salaried-formal? 10. Please explain whether your level of agricultural production (crop and livestock) has increased, decreased or remained unchanged in the last 5-10 years? Explain why it has increased, decreased or remained unchanged. 11. Have you gained any knowledge about farming and other related activities from them? Explain how? 12. Do you sell any of your agricultural output to them? Please explain how and specify the types of output. 13. Do emergent farmers sell agricultural inputs and services to you? Please explain the terms of such transactions. Theme 4: Technology choices 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. What is your preferred source of draft power for land preparation? Explain why. Are there hiring services for animal draft power in your community? Do you use these services? Who provides these services? (i.e. are they primarily provided by emergent farmers?) In general, do you think that the use of animal draft power for land preparation has increased in your community in the last 5-10 farming seasons? 6. In general, do you think that the use of mechanized draft power for land preparation has increased in your community in the last 5-10 farming seasons? 7. Are you aware of any initiatives (government, farmer organizations, donors, NGO’s, private sector) that have been recently promoted in your community to enhance tractor use as a source of power for land preparation? 8. If you are aware of such initiatives, what categories of farmers do they target? Please explain why you think they target those categories. 72 9. Have you been consistent with using improved seed varieties, inorganic fertilizers and other agricultural intensification technologies over the last 5-10 farming seasons? 10. Could you say your use of such inputs has increased or reduced over the stated period? Theme 5: Institutions and policies 1. Are you aware of any government policies designed to empower landowners with respect to tenure security? 2. Have you acted upon the provisions of the policies to improve your land tenure and security? 3. Have informal land rental and sales markets become common in your community? 4. Have you ever used these informal land markets either as a renter (landlord) or buyer (seller)? 5. Are you aware of any government policies designed to empower farmers with respect to enhancing farm productivity, food security and marketing of surplus production? 6. When did you learn about these policies? 7. Do you sell your produce to FRA? 8. Do you belong to a farmer group (association/cooperative)? 9. For how long have you been a member? 10. If you are a member of a farmer group, what are some of the benefits that you get from being a member? 11. Are these benefits available to all farmers in your community or specific category of farmers? Please explain in detail. 12. What are the rules and norms governing land administration (allocation and provision of tenure security) in your community? a. Is there any communal land were farmers can have there cattle to graze from? b. Is it allowed for my cattle to graze from my friend’s farm? 13. Have these rules and norms been the same since you started farming in this community? Explain if there are any changes that have occurred. 14. If the rules and norms have changed in your community, has the change improved the way land is administered? Please explain. Interview guide 3: Local community leaders (includes traditional authorities and district officials) Theme 1: Role in community/district 1. How long have you lived in this community/district? 2. How long have you been operating in your capacity as a traditional authority/district official in this community/district? 3. Please explain the role that your position plays in the administration of agricultural land in this community/district. 4. What kind of plans are you dealing with especially with agriculture land? Are these farmers who have title to land or do you also provide services to farmers living in customary land? 5. How do you interact with farmers in this community/district in relation to land issues? 6. What challenges do farmers in this community/district share with you about land related issues? 73 7. What challenges do you see with respect to land related issues in your community/district? 8. What do you think should be done to address both land related challenges discussed above? Theme 2: Emergent farmers, land access and distribution 1. Results from national surveys of small- and medium- scale farming households in Zambia reveal that the area controlled by medium-scale holdings in the 5 to 100 hectare category now exceeds that of small-scale farms of less than 5 hectares in Zambia. Is this large land acquisition by so-called emergent farmers something that you have observed in your community? Please explain. 2. How long has this phenomenon of large land acquisition been going on in this community? 3. Our retrospective survey for emergent farming households in selected districts of Zambia showed that about 42% of the household heads were born in the communities visited while the other 58% came from neighboring districts or other provinces of Zambia. From your assessment, are farmers acquiring large tracts of land community members from within, Zambians based in urban areas or foreign investors? Explain. 4. What do you think has led to the increase in large land acquisitions in your community, if at all it is happening? 5. A high proportion of small-scale and emergent farming households that we have interviewed have indicated “allocated/given” as the mode of land acquisition for the land they own. Could you please clarify what “allocated/given” really means? Is the land given freely without any cash or in-kind transaction? 6. When an individual negotiates with the headman to have him/her allocate 50 hectares to him/her, and some money changes hands informally. Would you still describe this mode of land acquisition as “allocated/given”? 7. From survey results, less than 45% of farmers perceive that traditional authorities still have unallocated arable land to give in the area they live. To what extent would you attribute land availability constraints in customary land areas to the increase in large land acquisitions? 8. Does the presence/growth of large farmers in this area make it harder for small farmers to access/acquire additional land here? (In other words, is the growth of larger holdings contributing to scarcity?) Theme 3: Land use and drivers of utilization in community/district 1. Please explain whether land use in terms of crops grown and livestock raised has evolved in the last 10-20 years by farmers in your community/district. 2. Has the change in land use happened across all categories of farmers in your community/district? Explain. 3. What factors have contributed to the change in land use by farmers in your community/district? 4. Has the use of improved seed varieties, inorganic fertilizers and other agricultural intensification technologies in your community/district increased or reduced over the last 510 farming seasons? What are the main factors that have contributed to the increase (decrease) of use of such inputs? 5. What are some of the main factors that determine how farmers (small-scale and emergent farmers) utilize the land that they own? Explain how each factor influences land utilization. 74 Theme 4: Direct and indirect effects of emergent farms 1. Please explain whether the level of agricultural production (crop and livestock) has increased, decreased or remained unchanged in the last 5-10 years in your community/district? Explain why it has increased, decreased or remained unchanged. 2. What effect has the presence of emergent farms had on income growth for small-scale and emergent farmers in your community/district? 3. Has use of animal draft power (ADP) been on the rise? 4. Has use of mechanical power (tractors) been on the rise? 5. What could you say about hiring services for both ADP and tractors in your community? 6. Are there wage-earning opportunities on emergent farms in this area? 7. Is this primarily piece work/ganyu, salaried-casual or salaried-formal? 8. Does the presence of emergent farms influence the types of services that are available locally (e.g. vets, mechanics, transportation services, extension, input suppliers)? Please distinguish this effect in the village versus impacts on services available at the nearest district. 9. Do larger farms attract better/different types of buyers of agricultural output? If so, why? If not, why? 10. Do emergent farmers provide some form of training or knowledge transfer to small-scale farmers? Explain how and the type of training. 11. Do emergent farmers offer training to small-scale farmers? 12. Do emergent farmers buy agricultural output from small-scale farmers? Please explain how and specify the types of output. 13. Do emergent farmers sell agricultural inputs and services to small-scale farmers? Please explain the terms of such transactions. Theme 5: Institutions and policies 1. Have formal land rental and sales markets become common in your community? 2. What role has the development of formal land markets contributed to the increase in number of emergent farmers in your community? 3. Have informal land rental and sales markets become common in your community? 4. What role has the development of informal land markets contributed to the increase in number of emergent farmers in your community? 5. Which type of farmers in your community/district benefit from government policies designed to empower farmers with respect to enhanced farm productivity, food security and marketing of surplus production? 6. Are there farmer groups (associations/cooperatives) offering member services to farmers in your community? 7. What are some of the benefits that one gets from being a member of the groups that you have given as examples? 8. Are these benefits available to all farmers in your community or specific category of farmers? Please explain in detail. 9. What are the rules and norms governing land administration (allocation and provision of tenure security) in your community/district? 10. Have these rules and norms been the same since you started living in this community? Explain if there are any changes that have occurred. 75 11. If the rules and norms have changed in your community, has the change improved the way land is administered? Please explain. 12. To what extent did the economic changes in the 1990’s when the Zambian economy was liberalized, compel those laid off from wage earning jobs to acquire large tracts of land and become farmers? Please explain. 13. Should government policy be focused on supporting emergent farmers more than small-scale farmers? Interview guide 4: National level stakeholders (government officials, land experts and thought leaders) Theme 1: Roles and land related challenges 1. What roles do you or does your organization play in land administration (especially agricultural land) in Zambia? 2. What land related challenges have farmers shared with you during your interaction? 3. How do you think you are going to address the problem of customary land when most farmers are still living in the customary lands? Theme 2: Emergent farmers, land access and distribution 1. Results from national surveys of small- and medium- scale farming households in Zambia reveal that the area controlled by medium-scale holdings in the 5 to 100 hectare category now exceeds that of small-scale farms of less than 5 hectares in Zambia. Is this large land acquisition by so-called emergent farmers something that you have observed countrywide or is it something that is localized? Please explain. 2. Our retrospective survey for emergent farming households in selected districts of Zambia showed that about 42% of the household heads were born in the communities visited while the other 58% came from neighboring districts or other provinces of Zambia. From your assessment, are farmers acquiring large tracts of land community members from within, Zambians based in urban areas or foreign investors? Explain. 3. What do you think is leading to the increase in large land acquisitions in parts of Zambia, if it all it is happening? 4. From survey results, less than 45% of farmers perceive that traditional authorities still have unallocated arable land to give in the area they live. To what extent would you attribute land availability constraints in customary land areas to the increase in large land acquisitions? 5. Does the presence/growth of large farmers in parts of Zambia make it harder for small-scale farmers to access/acquire additional land? (In other words, is the growth of larger holdings contributing to scarcity?) Theme 3: Land use and drivers of utilization in Zambia 1. Please explain whether land use by farmers in terms of crops grown and livestock raised has changed in the last 10-20 years in Zambia. 2. If there has been a change, has the change in land use happened across all categories of farmers in Zambia? Explain. 76 3. Has the use of improved seed varieties, inorganic fertilizers and other agricultural intensification technologies in Zambia increased or reduced over the last 5-10 farming seasons? 4. What are some of the main factors that determine how farmers (small-scale and emergent farmers) utilize the land that they own? Explain how each factor influences land utilization. Theme 4: Direct and indirect effects of emergent farms 1. What effect has the presence of emergent farms had on income growth for small-scale and emergent farmers in Zambia? 2. Results from nationally representative surveys have shown that approximately 35% of smalland medium-scale farmers used animal draft power as their source of power for land preparation during the 2010/2011 farming season. The ACS survey for emergent farmers’ results indicated that 90% of these farmers used ADP as their main source of power for land preparation during the 2012/13 farming season. Would you consider these percentages as an increase in ADP use in comparison to a decade ago? 3. If the use of ADP has increased in the last ten years, why do you think this has occurred? If not, why? 4. Results from the nationally representative data have shown that only 1% of smallholders used tractors as their source of power for land preparation during the 2010/2011 farming season. The ACS survey for emergent farmers’ results indicated that 10% of medium-scale farmers used tractors as their main source of power for land preparation during the 2012/13 farming season. Would you consider these percentages as an increase in tractor use in comparison to a decade ago? 5. If the use of tractors has increased in the last ten years, why do you think this has occurred? If not, why not? 6. Are there wage-earning opportunities on emergent farms in some parts of Zambia? 7. Is this ganyu/piecework of salaried employment? 8. Does the presence of emergent farms influence the types of services that are available locally (e.g. vets, mechanics, transportation services, extension, input suppliers)? Please distinguish this effect in the village versus impacts on services available at the nearest district. 9. Do larger farms attract better/different types of buyers of agricultural output? If so, why? If not, why? 10. Do emergent farmers provide some form of training or knowledge transfer to small-scale farmers? Explain how and the type of training. 11. Do emergent farmers buy agricultural output from small-scale farmers? Please explain how and specify the types of output. 12. Do emergent farmers sell agricultural inputs and services to small-scale farmers? Please explain the terms of such transactions. Theme 5: Institutions and policies 1. What changes in national government policies are contributing to the increase in large land acquisitions? The 1995 Lands Act? 2. Have formal land rental and sales markets become common in some communities in Zambia? If so, since when? 77 3. What role has the development of formal land markets contributed to the increase in number of emergent farmers in Zambia? 4. Have informal land rental and sales markets become common in some communities in Zambia? 5. Which type of farmers in Zambia benefit from government policies designed to empower farmers with respect to enhanced farm productivity, food security and marketing of surplus production? Please explain. 6. What actions have you taken in the last decade to ensure/support/advocate a more inclusive pattern of agricultural development? Conclusion Is there anything else that you think I have not asked about that might be relevant to the study I am undertaking? Thank you very much. All the information you provided is very helpful. In the event that I have a few further questions or need you to clarify something we discussed today, can I please contact you again? [If yes, confirm contacts and asked for preferred contact mode] Thank you. 78 REFERENCES 79 REFERENCES Adams, M. (2003). Land tenure policy and practice in Zambia: issues relating to the development of the agricultural sector. Draft Document for DFID. Lusaka, Zambia. Retrieved from http://www.mokoro.co.uk/files/13/file/lria/land_tenure_policy_and_practice_zambia.pdf African Union. (n.d.). About CAADP | African Union. Retrieved April 23, 2016, from http://pages.au.int/caadp/about Ali, D. A., & Deininger, K. (2015). Is There a Farm Size–Productivity Relationship in African Agriculture? Evidence from Rwanda. Land Economics, 91(2), 317–343. Barrett, C. B., Carter, M. R., & Timmer, C. P. (2010). A Century-Long Perspective on Agricultural Development. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 92(2), 447– 468. http://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aaq005 Barrett, C. B., Reardon, T., & Webb, P. (2001). Nonfarm income diversification and household livelihood strategies in rural Africa: concepts, dynamics, and policy implications. Food Policy, 26, 315–331. Berry, R. A., & Cline, W. R. (1979). Agrarian Structure and Productivity in Developing Countries: A Study Prepared for the International Labour Office Within the Framework of the World Employment Programme. John Hopkins University Press. Brown, T. (2005). Contestation, confusion and corruption: Market-based land reform in Zambia. In S. Evers, M. Spierenbug, & H. Weis (Eds.), Competing Jurisdiction: Settling Land Claims in Africa (Vol. 6, pp. 79–102). Leiden: Brill. Bruce, J., Kachamba, F., & Hansungule, M. (1995). Land administration: Processes and constraints. Land Tenure, Land Markets and Institutional Transformation in Zambia, Research Paper, Land Tenure Centre, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 47–77. Bryceson, D. F. (1996). Deagrarianization and rural employment in sub-Saharan Africa: A sectoral perspective. World Development, 24(1), 97–111. Bryceson, D. F. (2002). The scramble in Africa: reorienting rural livelihoods. World Development, 30(5), 725–739. Carletto, C., Savastano, S., & Zezza, A. (2013). Fact or artifact: The impact of measurement errors on the farm size–productivity relationship. Journal of Development Economics, 103, 254–261. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.03.004 Carter, M. R. (1984). Identification of the Inverse Relationship between Farm Size and Productivity: An Empirical Analysis of Peasant Agricultural Production. Oxford Economic Papers, 36(1), 131–145. 80 Chen, Z., Huffman, W. E., & Rozelle, S. (2011). Inverse Relationship Between Productivity and Farm Size: The Case of China. Contemporary Economic Policy, 29(4), 580–592. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7287.2010.00236.x Chileshe, R. A. (2005). Land tenure and rural livelihoods in Zambia: case studies of Kamena and St. Joseph. University of the Western Cape. Retrieved from http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Roy_Chileshe/publication/30758061_Land_tenure_a nd_rural_livelihoods_in_Zambia_case_studies_of_Kamena_and_St._Joseph/links/02e7e5 27e118c67533000000.pdf Chimhowu, A., & Woodhouse, P. (2006). Customary vs Private Property Rights? Dynamics and Trajectories of Vernacular Land Markets in Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of Agrarian Change, 6(3), 346–371. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1471-0366.2006.00125.x Chinene, V. R. N., Maimbo, F., Banda, D. J., & Msune, S. C. (1998). A Comparison of Customary and Leasehold Tenure: Agriculture and Development in Zambia. In P. Groppo (Ed.), Land Reform (Vol. 2). Rome, Italy: Food and Agricultural Organization. Retrieved from http://www.fao.org/docrep/x1372t/x1372t07.htm Chisanga, B., & Chapoto, A. (2015). Under-appreciated Facts about Zambia’s Agriculture. In Agriculture in Zambia: Past, Present and Future (pp. 25–36). Lusaka, Zambia: Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI). CSO, MAL, & IAPRI. (2012). The 2012 Rural and Agricultural Livelihoods Survey for small and medium-scale holdings: Interviewer’s Instruction Manual. Deininger, K., & Byerlee, D. (2012). The Rise of Large Farms in Land Abundant Countries: Do They Have a Future? World Development, 40(4), 701–714. Delgado, C. L. (1998). Agricultural Growth Linkages in Sub-Saharan Africa. Intl Food Policy Res Inst. Diao, X., Hazell, P. B. R., Resnick, D., & Thurlow, J. (2007). The Role of Agriculture in Development: Implications for Sub-Saharan Africa. Intl Food Policy Res Inst. Diao, X., Hazell, P., & Thurlow, J. (2010). The Role of Agriculture in African Development. World Development, 38(10), 1375–1383. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.06.011 Economist. (2011, May 5). The surge in land deals: When others are grabbing their land. The Economist. Retrieved from http://www.economist.com/node/18648855 German, L., Schoneveld, G., & Mwangi, E. (2013). Contemporary Processes of Large-Scale Land Acquisition in Sub-Saharan Africa: Legal Deficiency or Elite Capture of the Rule of Law? World Development, 48, 1–18. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.03.006 Ghose, A. K. (1979). Farm Size and Land Productivity in Indian Agriculture: A Reappraisal. Journal of Development Studies, 16(1), 27. 81 Government of the Republic of Zambia (GRZ). The Lands Act, Pub. L. No. Chapter 184 of the Laws of Zambia (1995). Haggblade, S., Hazell, P., & Brown, J. (1989). Farm-nonfarm linkages in rural sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 17(8), 1173–1201. http://doi.org/10.1016/0305750X(89)90232-5 Hayami, Y. (1977). Review of Agriculture and Structural Transformation: Economic Strategies in Late-Developing Countries by Bruce F. Johnston; Peter Kilby. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 26(1), 176–181. Hazell, P., Poulton, C., Wiggins, S., & Dorward, A. (2010). The Future of Small Farms: Trajectories and Policy Priorities. World Development, 38(10), 1349–1361. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.06.012 Hichaambwa, M., & Jayne, T. S. (2014). Poverty Reduction Potential of Increasing Smallholder Access to Land. Michigan State University, Department of Agricultural, Food, and Resource Economics. Retrieved from http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Munguzwe_Hichaambwa/publication/254388054_S mallholder_Commercialization_Trends_as_Affected_by_Land_Constraints_in_Zambia_ What_are_the_Policy_Implications/links/541829cf0cf2218008bf2a5f.pdf Hoeffler, H. (2011). The Political Economy of Agricultural Policies in Africa: History, Analytical Concepts and Implications for Development Cooperation. Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture, 50(1), 29–53. Jayne, T. S., Chamberlin, J., Traub, L., Sitko, N., Muyanga, M., Yeboah, F. K., … Kachule, R. (2016). Africa’s changing farm size distribution patterns: the rise of medium-scale farms. Agricultural Economics, 47(S1), 197–214. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12308 Jayne, T. S., Chapoto, A., Sitko, N., Nkonde, C., Muyanga, M., & Chamberlin, J. (2014). Is the Scramble for Land in Africa Foreclosing a Smallholder Agricultural Expansion Strategy? Journal of International Affairs, 67(2), 35–53. Jayne, T. S., Mather, D., & Mghenyi, E. (2010). Principal Challenges Confronting Smallholder Agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 38(10), 1384–1398. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.06.002 Johnston, B. F., & Mellor, J. W. (1961). The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development. The American Economic Review, 51(4), 566–593. Kim, J., & Mahoney, J. T. (2005). Property Rights Theory, Transaction Costs Theory, and Agency Theory: An Organizational Economics Approach to Strategic Management. Managerial and Decision Economics, 26(4), 223–242. Kimhi, A. (2006). Plot size and maize productivity in Zambia: is there an inverse relationship? Agricultural Economics, 35(1), 1–9. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2006.00133.x 82 Kuteya, A., & Kabwe, S. (2015). Zambia Agricultural Sector Performance, 2000 - 2015. In A. Chapoto & N. J. Sitko (Eds.), Agriculture in Zambia: Past, Present, and Future (pp. 37– 54). Lusaka, Zambia: Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI). Kydd, J., & Christiansen, R. (1982). Structural change in Malawi since Independence: Consequences of a development strategy based on large-scale agriculture, 10(5), 355– 375. Land Matrix. (2015). Zambia - LAND MATRIX. Retrieved June 19, 2015, from http://www.landmatrix.org/en/get-the-detail/by-targetcountry/zambia/?order_by=&starts_with=Z Lanjouw, J. O., & Lanjouw, P. (2001). The rural non-farm sector: issues and evidence from developing countries. Agricultural Economics, 26(1), 1–23. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2001.tb00051.x Larson, D. F., Otsuka, K., Matsumoto, T., & Kilic, T. (2014). Should African rural development strategies depend on smallholder farms? An exploration of the inverse-productivity hypothesis. Agricultural Economics, 45(3), 355–367. http://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12070 Larsson, R., Holmén, H., & Hammarskjöld, M. (2002). Agricultural Development in SubSaharan Africa. Lund: Lund University. Retrieved from http://lup.lub.lu.se/record/761418 Libecap, G. D. (2008). State Regulation of Open-Access, Common-Pool Resources. In C. Ménard & M. M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics (pp. 545– 572). Springer Berlin Heidelberg. Retrieved from http://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-3-540-69305-5_22 Malambo, A. H. (2014). Land Administration in Zambia After 1991: History, Opportunities and Challenges From the 1995 Lands Act. Journal of Geography and Geology, 6(1). http://doi.org/10.5539/jgg.v6n1p139 McMichael, P. (2012). The land grab and corporate food regime restructuring. Journal of Peasant Studies, 39(3–4), 681–701. http://doi.org/10.1080/03066150.2012.661369 Mellor, J. W., & Johnston, B. F. (1984). The World Food Equation: Interrelations Among Development, Employment, and Food Consumption. Journal of Economic Literature, 22(2), 531. Ménard, C., & Shirley, M. M. (2008). Handbook of new institutional economics. Berlin: Springer. Retrieved from http://public.eblib.com/EBLPublic/PublicView.do?ptiID=367382 Nolte, K. (2014). Large-scale agricultural investments under poor land governance in Zambia. Land Use Policy, 38, 698–706. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2014.01.014 83 North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press. North, D. C. (1994). Institutional Change: A Framework Of Analysis (Economic History No. 9412001). EconWPA. Retrieved from http://ideas.repec.org/p/wpa/wuwpeh/9412001.html North, D. C. (2008). Institutions and the Performance of Economies over Time. In C. Ménard & M. M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of new institutional economics (pp. 21–30). Berlin: Springer. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press. Place, F. (2009). Land Tenure and Agricultural Productivity in Africa: A Comparative Analysis of the Economics Literature and Recent Policy Strategies and Reforms. World Development, 37(8), 1326–1336. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.08.020 Schlager, E., & Ostrom, E. (1992). Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual Analysis. Land Economics, 68(3), 249. http://doi.org/10.2307/3146375 Schoneveld, G. C. (2014). The geographic and sectoral patterns of large-scale farmland investments in sub-Saharan Africa. Food Policy, 48, 34–50. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2014.03.007 Sen, A. (1962). An Aspect of Indian Agriculture. Economic Weekly, Annual Number 14. Sitko, N., & Chamberlin, J. (2015). The Anatomy of Medium-Scale Farm Growth in Zambia: What Are the Implications for the Future of Smallholder Agriculture? Land, 4(3), 869– 887. http://doi.org/10.3390/land4030869 Sitko, N. J., & Jayne, T. S. (2012). The Rising Class of Emergent Farmers: An Effective Model for Achieving Agricultural Growth and Poverty Reduction in Africa? (Working Paper No. 69). Lusaka, Zambia: Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI). Retrieved from http://www.aec.msu.edu/fs2/zambia/wp69.pdf Sitko, N. J., & Jayne, T. S. (2014). Structural transformation or elite land capture? The growth of “emergent” farmers in Zambia. Food Policy, 48, 194–202. http://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2014.05.006 Staatz, J. M. (1998). Agricultural Transformation Definition. Retrieved March 26, 2016, from http://fsg.afre.msu.edu/ag_transformation/Def_Trans.htm Stanton, B. F. (1991). Farm Structure: Concept and Definition. Department of Agricultural Economics, Cornell University Agricultural Experiment Station, New York State College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, Cornell University. Retrieved from http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/121378/2/Cornell%20SP%2091-06.pdf 84 Strauss, A., & Corbin, J. (1994). Grounded Theory Methodology: An Overview. In N. K. Denzin & Y. S. Lincoln (Eds.), Handbook of Qualitative Research (pp. 273–285). SAGE Publications. The World Bank. (2008). The Political Economy of Policy Reform: Issues and Implications for Policy Dialogue and Development Operations (No. 44288–GLB). Washington, D.C: Social Development Department, The World Bank. Timmer, C. P. (1998). The Agricultural Transformation. In C. K. Eicher & J. M. Staatz (Eds.), International Agricultural Development (pp. 113–135). Johns Hopkins University Press. van Loenen, B. (1999). Land tenure in Zambia. University of Maine. Retrieved from https://www.researchgate.net/profile/B_Loenen/publication/242672704_LAND_TENUR E_in_ZAMBIA/links/546e04f90cf29806ec2e6c15.pdf Williamson, O. E. (1985). Transaction Cost Economics. In The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (pp. 15–42). New York: The Free Press. 85 CHAPTER 3: REVISITING THE INVERSE FARM SIZE-PRODUCTIVITY RELATIONSHIP: A CASE STUDY OF ZAMBIA 3.1. Introduction and background Agriculture in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) has been experiencing gains in productivity since the early 1980s (Block, 2010). However, there remain lingering doubts whether an African “green revolution” can be achieved given the patchy progress in African smallholder agriculture (Mosley, 2002). The pessimism about African smallholder agriculture could be attributed to a number of challenges such as: (1) slow productivity growth and uptake of modern inputs (Diao et al., 2007); (2) shrinking size of most smallholder farms due to rural population growth and rising land scarcity (Hazell 2005; Jayne et al., 2012), and; (3) widespread land degradation (Lal, 1995). In addition, recent evidence showing a rapid expansion in farmland acquisitions by domestic land investors (Jayne et al., 2014) and foreign owned large-scale farms (Deininger & Byerlee, 2012; Land Matrix, 2015) in SSA is depleting available arable land, casting doubts on the viability of a smallholder-led agricultural growth. This article revisits the farm size-productivity relationship hypothesized to have an inverse relationship (IR) in development economics literature. The IR hypothesis postulates that small farms are more productive per unit of land than large farms (Berry & Cline, 1979). While a few studies that have found no evidence of a farm size-productivity inverse relationship (Kevane, 1996; Dorward, 1999), a large number of studies have found evidence upholding the relationship (Sen, 1962; Carter, 1984; Barrett, 1996; Barrett, Bellemare, & Hou, 2010; Chen, Huffman, & Rozelle, 2011; Carletto, Savastano, & Zezza, 2013; Larson, Otsuka, Matsumoto, & Kilic, 2014; Ali & Deininger, 2015). Binswanger, Deininger, & Feder (1995) demonstrated that without distortions that seem to favor large farms, small farms can be as efficient if not more efficient 86 than large farms. As a consequence, findings affirming the existence of the IR have been used as the basis for supporting agricultural strategies that promote small-scale agriculture especially in land-scarce countries. In SSA, smallholder agriculture has remained an integral part of the region’s agricultural development strategies and as such, development scholars have also taken an interest to examine the farm size-productivity relationship in this context. Research examining the inverse farm-size productivity hypothesis has explored the following questions. Is the observed relationship fundamentally because small farms are in and of themselves more productive than large farms? Or, are there other factors that explain the evidence that farm size and productivity are inversely related? A number of studies have empirically examined three contested explanations for why an inverse relationship is predominantly observed in developing countries. We discuss these in turn. The first explanation relates to market imperfections in factor markets such as labor, insurance and credit. Most studies on the IR have mainly focused on imperfections in labor markets. In an imperfect labor market, the cost of searching and supervising hired labor (transactions costs) is relatively high. Therefore, this creates an advantage for small farms who mainly rely on family labor for most farming activities. Large farms, on the other hand, depend substantially on hired labor to help with farming operations. According to Eswaran & Kotwal (1986), hired labor have a propensity to “shirk” if not supervised, and therefore, the labor that can be hired on the market is an imperfect substitute for one’s own time. Using Pakistan data, Heltberg (1998) found an inverse relationship between farm size and productivity explained by the presence of a supervision constraint with regard to labor, where outside workers were imperfect substitutes for family labor. Toufique (2005) compared two regions in Bangladesh with differences in transactions costs in rural labor markets. The study 87 found that in a region with higher transaction costs, output per acre on smaller farms was found to be higher than on larger farms. The opposite was true for the region with lower transactions costs. However, other studies have questioned imperfection in labor markets as the rationale for the existence of an IR. Assunção & Braido (2007) argued that the imperfect factor markets explanation does not explain the inverse farm size-productivity relationship based on evidence from India. To control for imperfect factor markets, their study analyzed household data with multiple plots in each season. They found that the inverse relationship remained virtually unchanged implying that the IR could not be explained by imperfection in labor markets. An empirical study of rice producers in Madagascar also concluded that only a small portion of the inverse farm size-productivity relationship could be explained by market imperfections (Barrett et al., 2010). The second explanation for the often-observed inverse relationship is the omission of important variables such as land quality in estimation equations. Since the estimation of the relationship between farm size and productivity is operationalized using econometric procedures, omission of relevant variables might lead to a biased coefficient on the variable of interest. If small farms have better (poorer) quality land, omitting important control variables for land quality might amplify (diminish) the inverse relationship between farm size and productivity. Bhalla & Roy (1988) found that when exogenous land quality variables are accounted for, the inverse relationship observed weakens, and in many cases, disappears. In other cases, failure to account for unobserved plot level characteristics such as soil and land quality overstated the inverse relationship (Lamb, 2003; Assunção & Braido, 2007). Conversely, Barrett et al. (2010) 88 found that none of the inverse relationship could be explained by the omission of soil quality measurements. The third explanation examined in the literature relates to the role of measurement error (Lamb, 2003; Holden & Fisher, 2013; Carletto et al., 2013). Measurement error, in this case, is considered as the inaccuracy in the variable measuring farm size (Lamb, 2003). Using econometric techniques that control for measurement error inherent in farmer self-reporting of their farm size, it has been observed that a statistically significant IR, reported prior to estimation adjustments, completely disappears (ibid). Recent studies (e.g., Carletto et al., 2013; Holden & Fisher, 2013) have addressed the issue of measurement error by using rich data that include selfreported land size information complemented by plot measurements collected using Global Position System (GPS) devices. They have found that using an improved measure of land size (GPS measure) strengthens the evidence in support of the existence of the inverse relationship. Despite these contestations, however, there are some methodological issues that have not been adequately addressed in previous empirical studies, especially those conducted in SSA. First, most research has been limited to data from farms of less than 10 hectares, yet their findings have been extrapolated beyond this farm size range. Moreover, productivity has mainly been restricted to one indicator of productivity—land productivity—when exploring this highly contested hypothesis. Table 12 (column 2) shows that most IR studies have predominantly used land productivity as the measure of productivity and that there are few cases when more than one measure of productivity has been used in a single study. 89 Table 12: Productivity measures and farm sizes in selected past IR studies Author Study Measure of How did they compute the measure location productivity of productivity? Carter (1984) India Land productivity Log of total annual farm output per hectare Heltberg (1998) Pakistan Land productivity Net value of total farm output per operated holding size Dorward (1999)af Malawi Land productivity Net value of output per area planted Lamb (2003) India Assunção & Braido (2007) India Land productivity Labor productivity Land productivity Log of household profits Log total hours by gender Log output per acre Kimhi (2006)af Zambia Land productivity Yield of maize Barrett et al. (2010)af Madagascar Land productivity Yield of rice Carletto et al. (2013)af Uganda Land productivity Net agricultural revenues per area operated Larson et al. (2014)af Kenya Land productivity Yield of maize (Kenya) 90 Salient farm size characteristics of sampled households ~90% of sampled households have farm sizes of 12 ha or below Bottom quartile of sampled households own 2.5% of all land, while the top quartile hold 71.5% ~90% of sampled households have farm sizes of 2 ha or below ND 95% of sampled households have farm sizes of 16.8 ha or below 87% of sampled households have farm sizes of 5 ha or below 95% of sampled households have farm sizes of 1 ha or below 90% of sampled households have farm sizes of 4 ha or below 75% of sampled households have farm sizes of 1.67 ha or below Table 12 (Cont’d) Author Study location Measure of productivity How did they compute the measure of productivity? Malawi Yield of maize (Malawi) Tanzania Yield of maize (Tanzania) Uganda Yield of maize (Uganda) Holden & Fisher (2013)af Malawi Land productivity Net agricultural return per unit area Verschelde et al. (2013)af Burundi Land productivity Net value of agricultural output per unit of land Li et al. (2013) China Land productivity Value per unit area Labor productivity Value/working days of the labor or value/number of farm’s labor force Ratio of total output to total input af Ali & Deininger (2015) Rwanda Total factor productivity Technical efficiency Land productivity Stochastic frontier analysis Logarithm of the value of crop output per hectare Source: Authors’ own compilation from previous IR studies Notes: af = Studies conducted in an African country ND = distribution of farm sizes not provided 91 Salient farm size characteristics of sampled households 75% of sampled households have farm sizes of 0.74 ha or below 75% of sampled households have farm sizes of 2.10 ha or below 75% of sampled households have farm sizes of 1.88 ha or below 90% of sampled households have farm sizes of 2.23 ha or below 95% of sampled households have farm sizes of 4.5 ha or below 95% of sampled households have farm sizes of 1.4 ha or below 98% of sampled households have farms of 1 ha or below In our review of the literature, we are only aware of one study (in China, by Li et al., 2013) that has used a comprehensive set of productivity measures to reexamine the IR hypothesis such as land productivity, labor productivity, profit ratio, total factor productivity (TFP), and technical efficiency. Nonetheless, the aforementioned study also has another issue; the data used covers a narrow range of farm sizes—zero to seven hectares—when exploring the farm sizeproductivity relationship. The use of a comprehensive set of productivity indicators provides a number of insights, which cannot otherwise be gleaned from one indicator. For example, land productivity, the most commonly used indicator, is important if one needs to assess food security especially when land is a highly binding constraint. Labor productivity is an important measure for capturing farm profitability while total factor productivity comprehensively captures farm production by accounting for labor, land and capital inputs simultaneously. Second, a number of studies conclude that small farms are more productive than large farms but by extrapolating their findings outside the range of the data available. The last column in Table 12 presents the operated farm size ranges reported in selected IR studies. While some studies do not report detailed descriptive statistics, the studies where such statistics are available reveal that very few include farms outside the 0-10 hectare range. Interestingly, these studies have mostly been done in countries where land is scarce and population is very dense, which probably justifies why farm size ranges analyzed have been within the 0-10 hectare range. What about countries like Zambia that is relatively less dense? Can findings from past IR studies be generalized? In the Zambian context, tests of the IR hypothesis covering a wide range of farm scales, take on even greater policy importance in light of recent papers questioning the viability and even the objectives of promoting small-scale agriculture in Africa (Collier & Dercon, 2014). 92 Third, previous studies have been consistently based on the assumption of constant returns-to-scale when examining the ceteris paribus farm size-productivity relationship. While the assumption may have been appropriate for studying the IR across small farms, it is less relevant when extending beyond this range to include medium- and large-scale farms. This study argues that findings from such studies cannot address the salient policy questions related to desired land allocation patterns given the rapid rise of farms between 5 and 100 hectares observed in some SSA countries such as Ghana, Kenya and Zambia (Jayne et al., 2014). Against this background, this essay extends the methodological approach used in the literature to examine the IR hypothesis in the context of farm structure change. The article has four specific objectives. First, it investigates the IR hypothesis over a much wider range of farm sizes using a statistically representative sample of small- and medium-scale farming households (both types of households mainly grow basic grains) with agricultural landholdings between 0 and 100 hectares from central and southern Zambia. Including this wide range of farms in our analysis can help clarify the IR hypothesis beyond the 0-10 hectare range and inform current policy discussions about how governments should allocate unutilized/underutilized land in order to achieve national equity and productivity goals. In this study, small-scale farmers are defined as agricultural households owning land less than or equal to five hectares and medium-scale farmers are defined as those whose landholding size ranges between 5 and 100 hectares.3 These definitions are based on how a number of African governments distinguish small- from medium-scale farm households. They use 5 hectares as the distinction between small- and medium-scale holdings (Jayne et al., 2016). Also, 3 In Zambia, medium-scale farmers are alternatively referred to as emergent farmers. This term became popularized in the 1970s when it was used to describe farmers that leave subsistence farming sufficiently far behind to sell at least half their produce to the market in an average year (Lombard, 1972). 93 we want to be consistent with how the emerging scholarly work on the rise of medium-scale investor farms in SSA has defined this scale of farming; they refer to medium-scale farms as those between 5 and 100 hectares of land (see for example, Jayne et al., 2014; Jayne et al., 2016). Second, the paper examines the relationship between farm size and productivity using five alternative measures of productivity: net value of crop production per hectare planted; net value of crop production per family labor day; net value of crop production per farm labor day; cost of maize production per metric ton produced, and; total factor productivity. A more detailed explanation of each productivity measure is provided in the “Data and Methods” section of this paper. A number of past studies have exclusively used yield or value of output per unit area— both measures of land productivity—to investigate the farm size–productivity relationship. While land productivity is an important measure that can be used to assess differences in farm productivity, we argue that a more comprehensive look at agricultural productivity is vital, more so because findings from such studies are used to draw implications for land policies and agricultural development strategies. For each measure of productivity, all production costs are accounted for including less commonly considered costs such as family labor and additional costs associated with fixed assets. Third, the paper explores reasons for potential differences in productivity within and between farm size categories. The study further reassesses the validity of the standard practice in the extant literature of holding everything else constant to examine the relationship between farm size and productivity. Since important sources of productivity differences could be input or management decision variables that tend to vary with farm size, we predict the relationship between farm size and productivity by relaxing the Constant Returns to Scale (CRS) assumption 94 and assess the extent to which this approach affects our interpretation. Fourth, the paper assesses whether findings of the relationship between productivity and operated farm size should be a decisive factor in guiding agricultural development and land policies under different situations characterized by differences in relative factor abundance. Zambia is an interesting case for the present paper because the country has been experiencing major changes in farm structure, the most salient of which is a major increase in cultivated area under the control of farms cultivating between 5 and 100 hectares (Sitko, Jayne, & Hichaambwa, 2013; Jayne et al., 2014). Kimhi (2006) is the only notable IR study we are aware of on Zambia. There are two things that are important to note about the aforementioned study. First, it uses data from the crop year of 1993-1994. Second, the study addresses the IR issue using data with 86 percent of the sampled households having farm sizes under 3 hectares. The changes in farm structure since that study was conducted have warranted an empirical review of the IR hypothesis that covers the relevant range of farm sizes with the goal of informing policy makers on how land policies can be harmonized more compatibly with other national policy objectives. The rest of the article is organized as follows. The following section presents the data and the estimation strategy used in this study. The study findings are outlined and discussed in the third section while the final section offers conclusions and draws out policy implications. 3.2. Data and methods The study uses two main sources of household survey data collected in Zambia. The first source of data is the Agricultural Commercialization Survey (ACS) of emergent farming households in Zambia conducted in 2013 by the Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI) of Zambia. The survey was conducted in six administrative districts of Zambia out of 72 95 districts: Chibombo, Choma, Chongwe, Kalomo, Mpongwe and Mumbwa (see Figure 2 in Appendices B1 for the map). The aforementioned districts were purposively selected based on the concentration and number of farmers owning over five hectares of land. Using the nationally representative Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Survey (RALS) of 2012, districts with at least three percent of all farmers owning over five hectares, were purposively selected. Medium-scale farming households in this study were defined as farmers with landholding between 5 and 100 hectares. The proportion of medium-scale farming households was 27 percent, 22 percent, 20 percent, 17 percent, 12 percent and 5 percent for Mumbwa, Kalomo, Choma, Chibombo, Mpongwe, and, Chongwe respectively. The main objective of the ACS was to understand the characteristics, behavior, land use patterns and agricultural output production of medium-scale farms. A total of 482 households were randomly selected from a list of emergent farming households compiled in consultation with the Zambia National Farmers’ Union (ZNFU) and the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) district offices. The Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) block areas were identified as the sampling units with help from local district offices. Whereas the sampling procedure was supposed to ensure reasonable representativeness of farmers in the 5-100 hectare category within the selected districts, the sample may have not been statistically representative of all medium-scale farmers in Zambia. This is because medium-scale farmers were not sampled from the other 65 districts. But we can say that the chosen districts are understood to contain the highest proportions of farms in this size class. We augment the ACS data with a second source of data called the Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Survey (RALS) of small- and medium-scale farming households in Zambia conducted in 2012. The RALS was implemented by IAPRI in collaboration with the Central 96 Statistical Office (CSO) of Zambia and the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL). The purpose of this survey was to provide policy relevant information that is not practical to collect annually from the government agricultural surveys. While the RALS is a nationwide survey, we restrict our analysis in this paper to the six districts where the ACS was conducted (see Figure 10 in Appendices for the location of households interviewed during the two surveys). Therefore, the number of households in the sub-sample from the RALS is 1000 households bringing the total number of households in our pooled sample to 1482. For the analysis in this study, we focus on 1429 households because 53 households either reported that they did not cultivate/plant any part of their land or had missing values on some of the key variables necessary for computing the measures of productivity. RALS includes both small- and medium-scale farms from 0 to 20 hectares of land while the ACS only has medium-scale farms between 5 and 100 hectares. In sum, the sample of 1429 households analyzed in this study includes farm households between 0 and 100 hectares. Both surveys captured the Geographical Positioning System (GPS) coordinates of surveyed households. This made it possible to generate Geographical Information Systems (GIS) data for soil and land quality variables included in our analysis.4 While these variables are deserving of caution as they are coarse estimates and may not correspond to local conditions, they are generally good proxies for dealing with the omitted variable problem prevalent in such studies. The data on soil were collected from the Harmonized World Soil Database v 1.2 (Nachtergaele & Batjes, 2012). In this study, we extracted data on soil nutrient availability that combines soil characteristics such as soil texture, soil organic carbon, soil pH and total exchangeable bases. We were able to also extract data for the length of the growing period 4 We would like to thank Jordan Chamberlin for extracting all the GIS data used in this study. 97 (LGP) from the GIS data – LGP combines information on temperature and available moisture to determine the length of time for adequate crop growth (Fischer, Velthuizen, Nachtergaele, & Jernelöv, 2000). Elevation and slope variables were extracted from the Shuttle Radar Topography Mission (SRTM) data.5 Finally, the extracted rainfall data is a time-series of decadal estimates collected from 1983 to 2013.6 Using these data, we defined rainfall as the total amount of estimated rainfall, in millimeters, received during the crop production season for each survey. 3.2.1. Computation of productivity indicators In the current paper, five distinct indicators are constructed as measures of agricultural productivity. The indicators are: (1) net value of crop production per hectare planted (land productivity); (2) net value of crop production per family labor day (labor productivity); (3) net value of crop production per farm labor day (labor productivity); (4) cost of production of maize per metric ton produced, and; (5) total factor productivity. Valuation of input costs and output values is in Zambian Kwacha based on 2011/2012 agricultural season prices.7 The first measure of productivity, net value of crop production per hectare planted (𝑌1 ), is computed as follows: (1) 𝑌1𝑖 = ∑ 𝐺𝑉1𝑖𝑗 −∑ 𝑉𝐶1𝑖𝑗 −∑ 𝐹𝐶1𝑖𝑗 ∑ 𝑎1𝑖𝑗 where 𝐺𝑉1𝑖𝑗 is the gross value of production, 𝑉𝐶1𝑖𝑗 is the measure of variables costs, 𝐹𝐶1𝑖𝑗 is the measure of additional costs for using fixed assets , 𝑎1𝑖𝑗 is the area planted to each crop and all these components are measured across each household i and crop j. Variable costs include the 5 The SRTM data are available here: http://srtm.csi.cgiar.org/ 6 Precipitation data are available from: http://www.cgiar-csi.org/data/climate/item/104-cru-ts-31climate-database 7 The average exchange rate prevailing at the time was US$ 1 = ZMW 5.3. 98 opportunity cost of family labor, imputed hired labor costs, seeds, fertilizers, chemicals, and rental costs for power. The opportunity cost of family labor is computed by multiplying the number of prime age (15-59 years old) household members working on each farm by the median days allocated to farming by the median daily agricultural wage rate prevailing in each district. Imputed hired labor costs are computed by multiplying the district level median daily agricultural wage rate by the number of hired labor days. Additional costs for using fixed assets are computed for owned agricultural-related assets used during the production season captured by the survey data. To compute additional costs for using fixed assets, we use the rental rate for assets with an active rental market. For example, if a household owns a tractor and uses it for land preparation, the tractor cost is the land preparation rental rate per hectare multiplied by the number of hectares cultivated. If the household used the tractor multiple times in a year, for example, for land preparation, weeding, and harvesting, etc., we valued all the uses of the tractor to get the cost attributable to the tractor for each household. While the cost measure is computed mainly using the rental rate approach, an alternative approach is also used for fixed assets with no rental market (e.g., irrigation equipment, pumps). For the ‘no rental market’ approach, the cost of an asset is computed as follows: (2) 𝐹𝐶 = 𝑐⁄𝑛 + (𝑐 ∗ 𝑟) where FC is the cost of an asset; c is the price or cost of an asset when it is new; n is the estimated asset’s usual life, and; r is the annual straight line depreciation rate. Assets considered in the computation of additional costs for using fixed assets (rental and non-rental market approach) included ploughs (ox drawn and tractor), sprayers, weighing machines, tractors, carts, trailers, water pumps, irrigation equipment, planters, trucks, water source, shelling and weeding machines. 99 The second measure of productivity, net value of crop production per family labor day (𝑌2 ), is computed as: 𝑌2𝑖 = (3) ∑ 𝐺𝑉2𝑖𝑗 −∑ 𝑉𝐶2𝑖𝑗 −∑ 𝐹𝐶2𝑖𝑗 ∑ 𝐿2𝑖𝑗 where 𝐿2𝑖𝑗 is the number of days taken for crop production activities by adult family labor during the crop production season for household i and crop j. All other components are defined in a similar way as explained for the net value of crop production per hectare planted. However, please note that 𝑉𝐶2𝑖𝑗 excludes the opportunity cost of family labor. The third measure of productivity, net value of crop production per farm labor (family and hired) day (𝑌3 ), is computed as: 𝑌3𝑖 = (4) ∑ 𝐺𝑉3𝑖𝑗 −∑ 𝑉𝐶3𝑖𝑗 −∑ 𝐹𝐶3𝑖𝑗 ∑ 𝐿3𝑖𝑗 where 𝐿3𝑖𝑗 is the number of days taken for crop production activities by adult family labor and hired labor during the crop production season for household i and crop j. All other components are defined in a similar way as explained for net value of crop production per hectare family labor. However, 𝑉𝐶3𝑖𝑗 excludes the opportunity cost of family labor and the cost of hired labor. This is because this measure of productivity calculates the returns to both family and hired labor. The fourth measure of productivity, cost of production of maize per metric ton produced (𝑌4 ), is computed as: (5) 𝑌4𝑖 = ∑ 𝑉𝐶4𝑖 +∑ 𝐹𝐶4𝑖 ∑ 𝑀𝑇4𝑖 where 𝑉𝐶4𝑖 measures the variables costs of maize production, 𝐹𝐶4𝑖 measures the additional costs for using fixed assets of maize production, 𝑀𝑇4𝑖 denotes the metric tons of maize produced and all these components are measured across each household i. 100 Our fifth measure of productivity, total factor productivity (TFP), comprehensively reflects the productivity of the whole crop production process. Based on the approach used by Li et al. (2013), which they adapt from Fan (1991) and Zhang and Carter (1997), we use the CobbDouglas production function to calculate TFP using the following functional form: 𝛼𝑀 𝐺𝑉𝑖 = 𝐴0 𝑒 𝜂𝑡 𝐾𝑖𝛼𝐾 𝐿𝛼𝐿 𝑖 𝑀𝑖 exp⁡(𝜀𝑖 ) (6) where 𝐺𝑉𝑖 is the gross value of crop production of farm i, 𝐾𝑖 , 𝐿𝑖 and 𝑀𝑖 represent the value of capital (all costs of production except imputed family labor costs), total number of labor days (hired and family labor), and land inputs (operated farm size) of farm i, respectively, 𝛼𝐾 , 𝛼𝐿 , 𝛼𝑀 are the output elasticities for capital, labor and land, correspondingly, t is the time trend term, and 𝜂 is the rate of technological progress. Using natural logarithm, equation (6) is estimated as follows: (7) 𝑙𝑛𝐺𝑉𝑖 = 𝑙𝑛𝐴0 + 𝜂𝑡⁡ + 𝛼𝐾 𝑙𝑛𝐾𝑖 + 𝛼𝐿 𝑙𝑛𝐿𝑖 + 𝛼𝑀 𝑙𝑛𝑀𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖 ⁡ Given that this production function is estimated with cross sectional data, the time trend variable is t=1 and thus the 𝑙𝑛𝐴0 + 𝜂𝑡⁡term becomes the constant term. To get the TFP indicator, we first compute the returns to scale (RTS) coefficient, which is the sum of factor output elasticities (𝑅𝑇𝑆 = ⁡ 𝛼𝐾 + 𝛼𝐿 + 𝛼𝑀 ). We then normalize each factor’s output elasticity and obtain ∗ 𝛼𝐾∗ = 𝛼𝐾 /𝑅𝑇𝑆, 𝛼𝐿∗ = 𝛼𝐿 /𝑅𝑇𝑆, and 𝛼𝑀 = 𝛼𝑀 /𝑅𝑇𝑆 and define TFP (𝑌5 ) as: (8) 𝑌5𝑖 = 𝐺𝑉𝑖 ∗ 𝛼∗𝐾 𝛼∗𝐿 𝛼𝑀 𝐾𝑖 𝐿𝑖 𝑀𝑖 101 3.2.2. Empirical framework and estimation strategy The standard empirical framework used in this study is the production function approach implemented by most studies testing the existence of the IR in farm production. In this article, the production function is estimated using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression as shown below: 𝒀𝒊 = 𝛽1 + 𝛽2 𝐴𝑖 + 𝒁𝒊 𝜷𝟑 + 𝑿𝒊 𝜷𝟒 + 𝜀𝑖 (9) where 𝒀𝒊 represents a vector of the five measures of productivity for each household i, 𝐴𝑖 is the operated farm size at household level, 𝒁𝒊 is a vector of exogenous variables such as household head characteristics, land and soil conditions and district fixed effects, 𝑿𝒊 denotes a vector of crop management practices that influence crop production, the 𝛽′𝑠 are the parameter estimates, and; 𝜀𝑖 is the error term. Table 13 lists and defines all the variables used in the estimation of the models specified in this study. However, in order to critically address the study’s underlying objectives, the study implements an empirical strategy that is different from previous studies on the topic. The empirical strategy for establishing the relationship between farm size and alternative measures of productivity in this paper is first econometrically specified in two ways. For each measure of productivity, we first specify a restricted model where each productivity measure is regressed on farm size, a quadratic term for farm size where applicable, household head characteristics, land and soil conditions, and district fixed effects. The quadratic term is not included in two production functions: net value of crop production per hectare and TFP regressions based on joint F-tests of the linear and quadratic terms. 102 Table 13: Variable explanation Name Variable input costs: Land rental Hired animal and machine use Fertilizer Seed Opportunity cost of family labor Imputed hired labor Additional costs for using fixed assets Net value of crop production per hectare Net value of crop production per family labor day Cost of maize production per metric ton Description Computed by multiplying the number of hectares rented by the district median land rental rate (2010/11 prices) Computed for main crop production activities where hired animals or machines were used. The main crop production activities include land preparation, planting, fertilizer application, weeding and harvesting. Multiplied each field area by 2010/11-district median cost per hectare for each activity and finally aggregated to household level. Computed amount of fertilizer used in each field and multiplied by total price to the farm gate Computed amount of seed used for each crop in each field and multiplied that by price to the farm gate Opportunity cost of family labor computed by multiplying three variables: (i) the number of prime age (15 – 59 years) household members working on each farm; (ii) family labor days allocated to crop production activities farming activities, and; (iii) district median daily agricultural wage rate. Hired labor costs computed by multiplying the district median daily agricultural wage rate by the number of hired labor days. The rental rate for assets with an active rental market was used to compute costs for fixed assets used in the production process. For example, if a household owned a tractor and used it for land preparation, the cost was the land preparation rental rate per hectare multiplied by the number of hectares cultivated. If the household used the tractor multiple times in a year (e.g., for land preparation, weeding, harvesting, etc.), we valued all the uses of the tractor to get the additional cost attributable to the tractor. Examples of other assets accounted for include: animal traction plows, tractor plows, oxen, planters, sprayers, carts and shellers. Value of crop production net of variable input and additional costs for using fixed assets divided by the operated farm size (Kwacha/hectare) Value of crop production net of variable input (excluding opportunity cost of family labor) and additional costs for using fixed assets divided by the number of days taken for crop production activities by family labor (Kwacha/day) Sum of variable input costs and additional costs for using fixed assets divided by the number of tons of maize produced (Kwacha/metric ton) 103 Table 13 (Cont’d) Name Total factor productivity indicator Operated farm size (ha) Landholding size (ha) Fallow land (ha) Basal fertilizer per hectare Top dressing per hectare Maize Beans and oilseeds Other cereals Traditional cash crops Roots and tubers Family labor days per hectare Hired labor days per hectare Manual Animal Mechanical Herbicide Insecticide Length of growing period Elevation Slope Rainfall Soil nutrient availability Male Age Employment Description Value of crop production (𝑌𝑖 ) divided by the product of three factors of production: value of capital (𝐾𝑖 ), total number of labor days (𝐿𝑖 ) - family and hired labor, and the total amount of land used for crop production (𝑀𝑖 ). Each factor was raised to the power of the normalized factor ∗ output elasticities (𝛼𝐾∗ , 𝛼𝐿∗ , 𝛼𝑀 ): 𝑌𝑖 = 𝛼 ∗ 𝛼∗ 𝛼∗ 𝐾𝑖 𝐾 𝐿𝑖 𝐿 𝑀𝑖 𝑀 Total area planted to crops during the reference year. Sum of uncultivated land (cleared and not cleared) and operated farm size during the reference year Cleared land not planted during the reference year Amount of compound fertilizer (NPK) applied in kilograms per hectare planted (kg/ha) Amount of Nitrogen fertilizer applied in kilograms per hectare planted (kg/ha) Share of area planted with maize (%) Share of area planted with beans and oilseeds (%) Share of area planted with other cereals (%) Share of area planted with traditional cash crops (%) Share of area planted with roots and tubers (%) Number of family labor days by prime age family members per hectare (days/ha) Number of hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) 1 = used manual power 1 = used animal draft power 1 = used mechanical power 1 = used herbicide for weed control 1 = used insecticide for pest control Number of months when moisture conditions are adequate for plant growth Meters above sea level Measure of steepness (degrees) Rainfall in millimeters received during the reference year Soil texture, soil organic carbon, soil pH, total exchangeable bases classified as: 1=No or slight constraints; 2=Moderate constraints; 3=severe constraints 1 = male head of household Age of household head (years) 1 = Household head currently of previously involved in salaried employment 104 Table 13 (Cont’d) Name Household head education Local Business Settlement Survey District fixed effects Description Level of education completed by the household head classified as: 1 = No formal education; 2 = basic education (Grade 1-9); 3 = high school education (Grade 10-12); 4 = tertiary education (higher education qualification) 1 = Household head considered a local 1 = Household head involved in off-farm business activities Number of years the head has lived in current settlement 1=Agricultural Commercialization Survey Unobserved effects captured by the six district dummy variables for our survey data After running each regression for all the measures of productivity that include both the linear and quadratic terms for farm size, a post estimation F-test (not reported in the tables section) is also conducted to see if the coefficients on farm size and farm size squared are jointly equal to zero. In the case of net value of crop production per hectare and TFP, we fail to reject the hypothesis that including the two terms is significantly different from zero. This implies that including the quadratic term does not add explanatory power and hence the reason why the term is dropped in the two aforementioned production functions. For the labor productivity regressions and cost of maize production per ton, the joint F-test of including both the linear and quadratic term is statistically significant. The second specification is a full model that includes variables included in the restricted model as well as crop management practices. In addition, a dummy variable for farms between 0-5 hectares is included in the full model as well as interaction terms between this dummy and the various crop management practices and input use variables. This approach is implemented to relax the assumption of CRS that is common to past empirical studies on the IR. Because we estimate a restricted and full model for each of the five measures of productivity, a total of 10 production functions are estimated in this paper. All parameter 105 estimates generated from these production functions are stored for later use during the prediction exercise described below. Overall sample means are then computed for all exogenous variables included in the restricted and full model specifications. Moreover, means for crop management practices are computed grouped by two farm size categories: 0-5 ha and >5 ha. For example, for total inorganic fertilizer application per hectare, two sample means are computed; one for observations with farm sizes between zero and five hectares and the other for observations with farm sizes above five hectares. We compute predicted values of each measure of productivity for the two separate models using two approaches. For the restricted specification, each parameter estimate obtained in the restricted model is multiplied by the overall sample mean of the relevant exogenous variable. We then sum up all the products together with the constant parameter estimate to obtain the predicted values. The only variable(s) that vary across observations are farm size and farm size squared. Please note that when computing predicted values, the farm size squared variable is only included in the labor productivity and cost of maize production per metric ton prediction equations. This is because it is only in those particular cases where a joint F-test for including both the linear and quadratic term during estimation, is significantly different from zero. For the full specification, the inclusion of the operated farm size dummy and the interaction terms between this dummy and various management practice and input use variables allows us to have coefficients that are different between the small- and medium-scale farms. Thereafter, we use different sub-sample means for crop management variables and multiply them with the different coefficient estimates obtained for 0-5 hectare versus 5 hectares and above farms. For both the restricted and full model specifications, only statistically significant right hand side variables are included in the computation of predicted values of each measure of productivity. 106 Finally, we graphically illustrate the relationship between operated farm size and alternative predicted values of each measure of productivity described above, and we relax the ceteris paribus assumption by allowing variation in crop management technologies. We present two separate line graphs in each figure appropriately labeled as: (i) ceteris paribus graphs (restricted), and (ii) with variations in crop management (full). In addition, a scatter plot showing individual observations are generated and superimposed on each of the five figures. The scatter plots depict the relationship between operated farm size and each measure of productivity. 3.3. Results and discussion The section begins with an extensive discussion of descriptive results and the econometric results testing the existence of the IR when different productivity indicators and data with a wide range of farms are used. The section also discusses potential reasons for productivity differences across farm sizes when the CRS assumption imposed by previous studies is relaxed. 3.3.1. Descriptive results The descriptive results are presented by four landholding size categories: (1) five hectares (ha) and below (0-5 ha); (2) five hectares to twenty hectares (5-20 ha); (3) twenty hectares to fifty hectares (20-50 ha), and; (4) fifty hectares to one hundred hectares (50-100 ha). This categorization is intended to mirror the way the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) in Zambia categorizes different scales of farming households, although in their case the categorization is based on area cultivated. Table 14 presents demographic, land and input use descriptive characteristics disaggregated by landholding size categories. Results indicate that the average age of household heads increases with landholding size. While there is no clear pattern with respect to the number 107 of years that the household has lived in the current settlement and how that relates to landholding size, household heads with landholding size between five and twenty hectares have on average lived the longest in the current settlement (32.9 years). This finding suggests that household heads with relatively longer years in current settlement do not necessarily have the largest landholding size. As expected, the majority of households are male-headed and the pattern suggests that the proportion of male-headed households increases with landholding size. Table 14: Demographic, land, and input use characteristics by landholding size categories 5 ha and Above 5 Above Above Full below to 20 ha 20 to 50 50 to sample Variables ha 100 ha Means and percentages Age of household head 45.1 48.5 51.2 53.1 47.3 Household head years in current 24.3 32.9 29.2 31.1 28.2 settlement Household settled in the current 26.5 13.2 14.7 6.0 19.6 settlement within the past 10 years (% yes) Male headed households (% yes) 77.8 91.8 91.4 90.0 84.9 Household head’s education attainment (% yes) No formal education 6.3 4.6 1.2 0 4.9 Basic (Grade 1 – 9) 77.4 73.3 64.4 50.0 73.5 Secondary (Grade 10-12) 11.8 18.8 23.3 32.0 16.4 Tertiary 4.5 3.3 11.0 18.0 5.2 Household head previously or currently 23.7 23.6 39.9 34.0 25.9 employed (% yes) Household head involved in off-farm 36.5 51.6 54.6 60.0 44.9 business activities (% yes) Household head considered local (% yes) 78.3 73.1 31.9 40.0 69.8 Operated farm size (hectares) 2.0 6.4 10.7 18.7 5.2 Operated farm size (% of total 85.7 60.9 31.2 25.1 45.2 landholding) Cleared land not cultivated (hectares) 0.2 2.4 10.0 24.4 3.0 Uncleared land (hectares) 0.1 1.6 12.8 29.0 3.1 Total landholding size (hectares) 2.3 10.6 34.2 74.3 11.5 Rented land (% yes) 4.8 3.4 5.5 4.0 4.4 Used basal fertilizer (% yes) 66.3 84.5 95.1 92.0 78.6 108 Table 14 (Cont’d) Variables Quantity of basal fertilizer (kg/ha) Used top dressing fertilizer (% yes) Quantity of top dressing fertilizer (kg/ha) Number of crops grown per holding Number of fields per holding Used family labor (% yes) Used hired labor (% yes) Used manual power (% yes) Used animal draft power (% yes) Used mechanical power (% yes) Used hired animal and machines (% yes) Used own productive fixed asset (% yes) Used herbicide (% yes) Used insecticide (% yes) Number of observations by landholding size 5 ha and below 67.1 68.6 66.7 2.2 2.3 93.8 18.6 32.7 73.4 3.2 46.9 29.9 8.9 17.4 695 Above 5 to 20 ha Above Above 20 to 50 50 to ha 100 ha Means and percentages 72.2 87.8 90.5 89.4 96.9 90.0 70.3 84.0 84.9 2.7 2.7 3.1 2.5 1.3 1.4 95.8 95.7 97.5 36.9 65.6 74.0 10.9 1.2 0 92.7 88.3 78.0 4.6 18.4 18.0 22.8 28.8 22.0 74.1 71.2 72.0 31.3 63.2 62.0 39.5 38.7 26.0 521 163 50 Full sample 72.2 80.2 70.6 2.5 2.3 95.1 32.5 20.0 82.3 6.0 35.2 52.2 25.1 28.2 1,429 Source: Authors’ own computation from ACS (2013) and RALS (2012) Household heads with secondary or tertiary education have comparably larger landholdings. An important aspect about the changes in farm structure currently being experienced in parts of SSA is that a significant proportion of medium-scale farmers comprise landowners who have or have had a salaried job besides farming. The results indeed confirm this, with more than 30 percent of household heads with landholding size of 20 hectares or greater indicating that they previously held or currently hold a salaried job. On the other hand, the results show that less than 25 percent of household heads in the bottom two landholding size categories (0-5 ha and 5-20 ha) were previously or currently employed in a formal job. One of the survey questions asked the respondents to state whether they were local or non-local in their current settlement. A household head is considered local if he or she has family ties in the area and is most likely to have ethnic ties to people in that settlement. Interestingly, the average proportion of households who consider themselves local in their current settlement 109 reduces with landholding size. In other words, households with larger landholdings are more likely to be individuals who are not considered local in the area they have settled. This finding supports the hypothesis that most medium-scale farms in Zambia are owned by people mostly based in urban areas or retirees who worked in the civil service (Sitko & Jayne, 2014). Although operated farm size is increasing with landholding size, results in Table 14 clearly show that the proportion of landholding that is operated reduces with landholding size. For example, farms with landholding size of 0-5 ha cultivate more than 85 percent of total landholdings while farms with 50-100 ha cultivate only 25 percent of total land. This finding suggests that farms with relatively large landholdings are underutilizing the land they own for crop production while farms with small landholdings are over utilizing the land they own and run the risk of exhausting soil fertility due to reduced fallows and low use of productivity-enhancing inputs. Results for input use characteristics by landholding size categories illustrate some interesting patterns. First, the proportion of households applying inorganic fertilizers (basal and top dressing) is increasing with landholding size. Second, households with landholding size of 50-100 ha are likely to apply more inorganic fertilizer (basal and top dressing) than households with smaller landholding sizes. In general, however, the average application rates for inorganic fertilizers for households surveyed are lower than the nationally recommended fertilizer application rates for maize production pegged at 300-400 kg/ha. Third, although the proportion of households using mechanized power is increasing with landholding size, results show that the proportion of households using mechanization is low across all landholding size categories. On the other hand, animal draft power seems to be a popular power method used by more than 70 percent of farms across all landholding size 110 categories. Fourth, both herbicide and insecticide use are positively correlated with landholding size. Fifth, use of family labor to conduct activities such as land preparation, planting, fertilizer application, weeding and harvesting is consistent across all landholding size categories. The proportion of households employing hired labor is positively related to landholding size, perhaps not surprisingly. In sum, this study shows that use of productivity-enhancing inputs, improved technologies, and allocation of hired labor are all positively associated with landholding size. Agriculture in Zambia is dominated by maize production primarily because of maize centric policies that have been pursued by successive governments since the country gained independence in 1964 (Chapoto, Kabaghe, & Zulu-Mbata, 2015). In this study, we analyze the crop production characteristics of maize and four other crop categories: (1) beans and oilseeds (groundnuts, soya beans, mixed beans, bambara nuts, cowpeas, velvet beans); (2) other cereals (sorghum, rice, millet, popcorn); (3) traditional cash crops (seed cotton, tobacco, coffee, sugarcane), and; (4) roots and tubers (sweet potatoes, potatoes, cassava). As shown in Table 15, more than 98 percent of households surveyed produce maize and this is true across all landholding size categories. The results also seem to suggest that larger farms are more likely to have greater diversity of crops compared to smaller farmers. Despite the crop diversification response by larger farmers, they still allocate a relatively bigger proportion of their land to maize production probably because of the policy incentives associated with maize production in Zambia. 111 Table 15: Crop production characteristics of main crop categories by landholding size categories 5 ha and Above 5 Above Above Full below to 20 ha 20 to 50 50 to sample ha 100 ha Means and percentages Households planting each crop category c (% of sampled households) Maize 96.1 100.0 100.0 100.0 98.1 Beans and oilseeds 56.7 75.2 73.0 90.0 66.5 Other cereals 2.6 2.9 4.9 12.0 3.3 Traditional cash crops 18.0 39.7 31.3 20.0 27.5 Roots and tubers 26.0 17.7 8.6 10.0 20.4 Households planting maize only (% of sampled households) Maize yield (MT/ha) Land allocation to main crop categories c (% of area planted) Maize Beans and oilseeds Other cereals Traditional cash crops Roots and tubers Total Gross value per hectare for households planting main crop categories c (ZMW/ha) Maize Beans and oilseeds Other cereals Traditional cash crops Roots and tubers Gross value of crop production per hectare (ZMW/ha) 26.3 11.9 15.3 6.0 19.1 2.0 2.3 2.7 3.1 2.2 70.9 13.3 0.9 10.9 4.0 100.0 71.2 13.4 0.7 12.4 2.5 100.0 73.5 12.7 0.6 11.5 1.7 100.0 75.6 12.2 0.6 10.4 1.2 100.0 71.5 13.3 0.8 11.5 3.0 100.0 2,184.0 1,594.0 1,067.0 2,458.0 2,785.0 2,551.0 1,145.0 964.0 2,505.0 1,619.0 3,367.0 1,521.0 563.0 983.0 879.0 4,123.0 1,273.0 1,142.0 1,698.0 1,564.0 2,527.0 1,384.0 958.0 2,402.0 2,306.0 2,074.0 2,167.0 2,495.0 2,596.0 2,174.0 112 Table 15 (Cont’d) Contribution of main crop categories c (% of gross crop value) Maize Beans and oilseeds Other cereals Traditional cash crops Roots and tubers Total 5 ha and below Above 5 to 20 ha Above Above 20 to 50 50 to ha 100 ha Means and percentages 74.6 8.8 0.3 11.6 4.8 100.0 79.0 7.1 0.2 11.6 2.1 100.0 82.6 6.4 0.2 9.4 1.4 100.0 Full sample 85.2 6.0 0.2 7.7 0.9 100.0 77.5 7.8 0.2 11.2 3.3 100.0 Number of observations by landholding 695 521 163 50 size Source: Authors’ own computation from ACS (2013) and RALS (2012) survey data 1,429 Notes: c Crop category/categories: 1 = Maize; 2=beans and oilseeds (groundnuts, soya beans, mixed beans, Bambara nuts, cowpeas and velvet beans); 3=other cereal grains (sorghum, rice, millet, popcorn); 4= traditional cash crops (seed cotton, tobacco, coffee and sugarcane); 5=roots and tubers (sweet potatoes, potatoes and cassava). Table 15 also reports the gross value of crop production per hectare. Two main patterns emerge with respect to gross value per hectare of main crop categories when analyzed across landholding size categories. First, there is a positive relationship between gross value of maize production per hectare and landholding size such that farms in the 50-100 ha category nearly generate double the value than farms in the 0-5 ha category. Second, the gross value per hectare for other crop categories does not follow a similar pattern as maize. In general, farms categorized in the 0-5 ha group have a greater gross value per hectare for beans and oilseeds, traditional cash crops and roots and tubers than those in the 50-100 ha group. However, when one critically analyzes the changes in gross value per hectare across the landholding size continuum, the results suggest a U-shaped or inverse U-shaped relationship between gross value per hectare and landholding size. 113 Table 16 reports crop production costs and the five indicators of productivity by landholding size categories. In our study, we account for seven individual cost items that build up the cost of crop production across farms in Zambia. The cost items include land rental, hired animal and machine use, hired labor, seed, fertilizer, family labor and additional costs for using fixed assets. The cost associated with family labor must be considered as an upper bound estimate and therefore need to be interpreted with caution. As noted by Burke et al. (2011), the wage assigned to family labor is likely to be well above the economic cost of that labor. Also, households tend to overestimate the amount of family labor spent on a given farming activity. Total production cost per hectare planted increases across landholding size categories, which provides the first indication that small farms are, on average, cost efficient relative to large farms in Zambia. The summary results of the five indicators of productivity reveal some interesting patterns. First, net value of crop production per hectare and the total factor productivity average values suggest a negative relationship between each measure of productivity and landholding size. Second, the labor productivity measures (net value of production per family labor day and net value of production per labor) results show a monotonic positive relationship across landholding size categories. This implies that large farms are more productive than small farms when the measures of productivity under consideration are family labor or total farm labor productivity. Third, cost of maize production per metric ton increases across landholding size categories. Put another way, smaller farmers are more cost efficient compared to larger farmers when it comes to maize production. 114 Table 16: Crop production costs and productivity measures by landholding size categories 5 ha and Above 5 Above Above Full below to 20 ha 20 to 50 50 to sample ha 100 ha Means Cost of production per hectare – all crops (ZMW/ha) Land rental Only HH with non zero values 221.0 154.0 223.0 151.0 200.0 All HH 10.5 5.3 12.3 6.1 8.7 Hired animal and machine use Only HH with non zero values 97.0 91.0 90.0 60.0 94.0 All HH 45.7 20.8 25.9 13.2 33.2 Hired labor Only HH with non zero values 473.0 573.0 658.0 609.0 572.0 All HH 103.0 332.0 610.0 585.0 261.0 Seed Only HH with non zero values 206.0 168.0 173.0 180.0 187.0 All HH 203.0 168.0 173.0 180.0 186.0 Fertilizer Only HH with non zero values 542.0 515.0 513.0 527.0 526.0 All HH 365.0 459.0 497.0 497.0 419.0 Family labor Only HH with non zero values 287.0 356.0 344.0 355.0 323.0 All HH 257.0 347.0 342.0 340.0 302.0 Additional costs for using fixed assets Only HH with non zero values 219.0 223.0 220.0 217.0 221.0 All HH 65.7 166.0 157.0 156.0 116.0 Total production costs (All HH) 1,050.0 1,497.0 1,817.0 1,778.0 1,326.0 Productivity measures Net value of production per hectare 1,025.0 670.0 678.0 818.0 (ZMW/ha) Net value of production per family labor 37.8 100.0 239.0 191.0 day (ZMW/day) Net value of production per labor day 34.6 89.3 212.0 212.0 (ZMW/day)* Cost of production per metric ton of 1,188.0 2,069.0 3,027.0 3,296.0 maize (ZMW/MT) Total factor productivity indicator 270.0 249.0 254.0 255.0 Number of observations by landholding 695 521 163 50 size Source: Author’s own computation from ACS (2013) and RALS (2012) survey data Notes: * This includes both family and hired labor days 115 848.0 91.3 83.2 1,804.0 260.0 1,429 Figure 3 illustrates the relationship between factor input ratios and landholding size using four factor input ratios, specifically the capital-labor, capital-land, labor-land, and labor-capital ratios. Capital is the sum of all costs of production excluding imputed family labor costs, and is presented in terms of Zambian Kwacha (ZMW); labor is the number of prime age members, between 15 and 59 years, living and participating in farming activities in a given household, and; land is the operated farm size. Both capital-labor and capital-land ratios exhibit a positive relationship while the labor-land and labor-capital ratios have a negative relationship when graphed against landholding size. Two main observations are made from these graphs. First, farms become more capital-intensive as landholding size increases. Second, farms become more land-using and labor-saving as landholding size increases, but particularly in the range of 1-10 hectares—there is a lot of substitution of factor inputs within this range, but not so much after 10 hectares. Figure 3: Bivariate relationships between factor input ratios and landholding size 116 The box plots in Figure 4 display boxes bordered at the 25th and 75th percentiles of the yvariable with a median line at the 50th percentile. Whiskers extend from the box to the upper and lower adjacent values and are capped with an adjacent line. The box plots clearly show that for each measure of productivity, there are variations in the level of productivity even within a given landholding size category. Consider the box plots for the net value of crop production per hectare depicted in the top left hand corner of Figure 4. For farms with landholding size less than five hectares, the range of the level of productivity between the 25th and 75th percentile is approximately ZMW 200 to ZMW 1600 with a median value of about ZMW 700. Similarly, the level of productivity for farms with landholding size above 50 hectares has high variation ranging between ZMW -600 and ZMW 1400 for the 25th and 75th percentiles respectively and a median of ZMW 450. This trend for within-category differences is true across all farm size categories and measures of productivity. In other words, farms within a defined category do not necessarily have similar levels of productivity. This suggests that differences in productivity are not necessarily driven by farm size but that there are other factors that play an important role other than the scale of farm. 117 Figure 4: Box plots of measures of productivity by landholding size categories Note: Box plots bordered at the 25th and 75th percentiles of the y-variable with a median line at the 50th percentile. Whiskers extend from the box to the upper and lower adjacent values and are capped with an adjacent line 3.3.2. Testing the IR with alternative productivity measures over a wide range of farms Ultimately, the relationships between operated farm size (𝐴𝑖 ) and the five outlined measures of productivity, conditional on control variables that potentially explain productivity differences, are of interest to this study. The sign on coefficient estimates will be interpreted differently for the various measures of productivity. For four measures of productivity—net value of crop production per hectare planted, net value of crop production per family labor day, net value of crop production per farm labor day, and TFP—a statistically significant negative coefficient on the operated farm size variable upholds the IR hypothesis, while a positive coefficient suggests otherwise. However, the interpretation of the coefficient on operated farm size when the measure of productivity is cost of maize production per metric ton is the opposite 118 of the other four measures. With this measure of productivity, the IR is upheld when the coefficient on the operated farm size variable is positive, while a negative coefficient would imply otherwise. Tables 17 to 20 present estimates of the OLS regression analysis exploring the operated farm size-productivity relationship using five measures of productivity. We first discuss the estimates for net value of crop production per hectare planted presented in Table 17. Results for the net value of crop production per hectare for both the restricted and full models uphold the IR hypothesis. However, the coefficient on the farm size variable is only statistically significant in the full model specification. For a one-hectare increase in farm size, the value of crop production per hectare reduces by ZMW 6. This result is significant at 10% confidence level. According to the restricted specification, factors associated with differences in net value of crop production per hectare could be summarized as follows. Male-headed households are more likely to have net value of crop production per hectare that is ZMW 190 higher than female-headed households. An increase by one year of living in a given settlement is negatively associated with productivity. Household heads with higher education (tertiary education) have significantly higher levels of productivity relative to those with only 7 years or less of primary education. Surprisingly, household heads’ currently or previously employed have a lower net value of crop production per hectare, relative to those with no formal job experience. 119 Table 17: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and net value of crop production per hectare Explanatory variables Dependent variable Net value of crop production per hectare (ZMW/ha) Restricted Full Operated farm size (ha) -5.26 -16.16* (-0.52) (-1.70) * Male head (1=yes) 190.57 219.84* (1.86) (1.93) Age of household head -3.70 0.44 (-1.30) (0.15) Years in current settlement -6.17** -3.92* (-2.48) (-1.67) Education of household head (base category: primary education) No formal education (1=yes) 45.60 99.38 (0.30) (0.73) Secondary education (1=yes) 117.55 60.38 (1.19) (0.62) Tertiary education (1=yes) 669.36*** 452.45** (2.97) (2.02) *** Formal employment (1=yes) -362.51 -251.40*** (-4.08) (-2.80) Local (1=yes) 355.77*** 285.92*** (4.02) (3.23) Length of growing period (months) 716.73*** 645.85** (2.86) (2.57) Elevation (meters) -1.06** -1.22** (-2.14) (-2.53) Slope (degrees) 28.48 31.80 (0.74) (0.92) Rainfall (millimeters) 6.12*** 6.18*** (3.68) (3.57) Soil nutrient availability (base category: no or slight constraints) Moderate constraints (1=yes) -73.61 -109.70 (-0.72) (-1.12) Severe constraints (1=yes) -244.54** -237.22** (-2.11) (-2.10) 120 Table 17 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables District fixed effects Operated farm size dummy (1=farms with 5ha and less) Total inorganic fertilizer (kg/ha) Share of area planted with: Maize area (%) Beans and oilseeds area (%) Other cereals area (%) Traditional cash crops area (%) Roots and tubers area (%) Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) Manual power (1=yes) Animal draft power (1=yes) Mechanical power (1=yes) Herbicide use (1=yes) Insecticide use (1=yes) Total fertilizer (kg/ha) X operated farm size dummy Maize area (%) X operated farm size dummy Beans and oil seeds area (%) X operated farm size dummy Other cereals area (%) X operated farm size dummy Traditional cash crops area (%) X operated farm size dummy 121 Dependent variable Net value of crop production per hectare (ZMW/ha) Restricted Full Yes Yes -1552.36* (-1.80) 4.12*** (3.80) 557.57 (1.25) 1646.83*** (2.79) 587.67 (0.67) 1120.95** (2.29) -202.46 (-0.17) -2.47 (-1.31) -2.31 (-0.36) -70.64 (-0.31) -913.59** (-2.02) -68.41 (-0.20) -194.31 (-1.48) 342.72** (2.17) -1.95* (-1.70) 919.11 (1.34) 572.34 (0.66) 251.35 (0.24) 1620.83** (2.18) Table 17 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Roots and tubers area (%) X operated farm size dummy Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Dependent variable Net value of crop production per hectare (ZMW/ha) Restricted Full 4027.48*** (2.85) -0.24 Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Manual power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Animal draft power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Mechanical power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Herbicide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Insecticide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy -7549.90*** (-2.81) 1479 0.15 0.14 Constant (-0.11) -3.17 (-0.36) 163.79 (0.58) 768.35 (1.57) -50.36 (-0.12) 528.71*** (2.61) -161.99 (-0.70) -7285.18** (-2.54) 1426 0.27 0.24 N R2 Adj. R2 Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012) and ACS (2013) Note: t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Length of growing period variable shows a positive association with our land productivity measure. We also find evidence that when farms are located on soils with somewhat severe constraints in terms of soil nutrient availability (e.g., soil texture, soil organic carbon, soil pH, total exchangeable bases), this is negatively associated with net value of crop production per hectare. According to the full model, the results show that the same variables that are significant in the vector of exogenous variables in the restricted specification are also important factors in 122 the full specification. For the vector of crop management and input use variables (only included in the full specification), the notable findings are as follows. A one-unit increase in total inorganic fertilizer applied per hectare is associated with an increase of ZMW 4 in net value of crop production per hectare and increasing the share of land planted to beans and oilseeds as well as traditional cash crops has a positive effect on net value of crop production per hectare. Households that use animal draft power as a land preparation technique are less productive relative to those not using the technique while application of insecticide has a positive effect on productivity. The estimates for the two measures of labor productivity are presented in Table 18. The results show that there is a positive and significant relationship between operated farm size and our labor productivity measures in all the specifications. These findings fail to uphold the IR hypothesis. For net value of crop production per family labor day, the estimated coefficients indicate that a one hectare increase in operated farm size increases labor productivity by ZMW 23 and ZMW 30 in the restricted and full model specifications respectively. For net value of crop production per labor day (family and hired labor), an increase of one hectare of operated farm size leads to a corresponding increase in labor productivity of ZMW 37 and ZMW 55 in the restricted and full model specifications respectively. Our findings imply that the returns to labor are higher on medium-scale farms relative to small-scale farms. 123 Table 18: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and net value of crop production per family labor/total labor day Explanatory variables Dependent variable Net value of crop Net value of crop production per family production per labor labor day (ZMW/day) day (family and hired) (ZMW/day) Restricted Full Restricted Full Operated farm size (ha) 22.71*** 30.32*** 36.54*** 55.48** (4.00) (3.87) (2.88) (1.97) Operated farm size squared -0.13 -0.28 -0.35 -0.73 (-0.51) (-1.08) (-1.41) (-1.61) Male head (1=yes) 12.23 21.05 -3.98 21.48 (0.83) (1.42) (-0.21) (0.79) Age of household head -0.26 0.21 -0.40 0.19 (-0.50) (0.46) (-0.75) (0.35) Years in current settlement -0.62 -0.36 -0.58 0.05 (-1.04) (-0.79) (-1.17) (0.09) Education of household head (base category: primary education) No formal education 27.82 14.56 54.40* 45.97 (1.57) (0.82) (1.72) (1.32) Secondary education 75.51** 51.14* 52.68* 52.83* (2.08) (1.72) (1.69) (1.94) Tertiary education 140.42* 74.22 431.46 376.09 (1.65) (1.15) (1.63) (1.39) Formal employment (1=yes) -7.59 -5.20 9.70 15.90 (-0.34) (-0.27) (0.41) (0.46) Local (1=yes) 18.52 16.81 12.69 -7.26 (0.83) (0.87) (0.58) (-0.24) Length of growing period (months) 157.01*** 123.22*** 138.13*** 83.69** (3.92) (3.44) (2.76) (2.11) Elevation (meters) -0.18 -0.16 -0.18 -0.13 (-1.42) (-1.37) (-1.54) (-1.18) Slope (degrees) 18.62** 8.04 14.57* 4.78 (2.31) (1.31) (1.90) (0.70) Rainfall (millimeters) 0.56** 0.46** 0.12 0.16 (2.54) (2.33) (0.46) (0.66) Soil nutrient availability (base category: no or slight constraints) Moderate constraints (1=yes) -29.11 -32.23 -79.95 -123.41 (-0.78) (-1.07) (-0.89) (-1.16) Severe constraints (1=yes) -39.92 -31.89 -82.65 -104.27 (-1.19) (-1.15) (-1.13) (-1.22) District fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Operated farm size dummy (1=farms 1.57 -462.98 with 5ha and less) (0.01) (-1.06) 124 Table 18 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Total inorganic fertilizer (kg/ha) Dependent variable Net value of crop Net value of crop production per family production per labor labor day (ZMW/day) day (family and hired) (ZMW/day) Restricted Full Restricted Full ** 0.74 1.59 (2.14) (1.50) Share of area planted with: Maize area (%) Beans and oilseeds area (%) Other cereals area (%) Traditional cash crops area (%) Roots and tubers area (%) Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) Manual power (1=yes) Animal draft power (1=yes) Mechanical power (1=yes) Herbicide use (1=yes) Insecticide use (1=yes) Total fertilizer (kg/ha) X operated farm size dummy Maize area (%) X operated farm size dummy Beans and oil seeds area (%) X operated farm size dummy 125 256.22** (2.02) 77.23 (0.40) 641.26* (1.65) 142.82 464.54* (1.66) 865.04 (1.20) 133.93 (0.25) 558.71 (1.22) -157.90 (-0.65) -2.42*** (1.23) 40.47 (0.10) -1.24*** (-4.15) -1.25 (-3.58) -6.44 (-0.44) 79.39 (0.68) -57.01 (-0.26) 154.78 (0.78) -21.64 (-0.61) 85.65 (1.23) -0.66* (-0.93) -79.18 (-0.50) -1136.45 (-1.25) -613.51 (-0.93) 46.21 (0.74) 5.48 (0.09) -1.54 (-1.94) -163.28 (-1.46) -367.25 (-1.24) 26.49 (-1.30) -716.24 (0.13) (-1.04) Table 18 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Other cereals area (%) X operated farm size dummy Dependent variable Net value of crop Net value of crop production per family production per labor labor day (ZMW/day) day (family and hired) (ZMW/day) Restricted Full Restricted Full * -654.48 -120.38 Traditional cash crops area (%) X operated farm size dummy Roots and tubers area (%) X operated farm size dummy Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Manual power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Animal draft power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Mechanical power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Herbicide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Insecticide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy (-1.65) 45.83 (-0.22) -371.34 (0.34) 263.83 (-0.90) 54.95 (1.06) 1.88*** (0.13) 0.71* (3.28) 1.89 (1.70) 5.14 (0.68) -93.44 (0.94) 71.24 (-0.81) 64.68 (0.44) 1146.15 (0.30) -156.69 (1.26) 578.18 (-0.79) 0.93 (0.92) -115.57 (0.02) -107.60 (-1.05) -22.94 (-1.51) (-0.39) *** *** Constant -1355.51 -1148.49 -883.46 -216.06 (-4.16) (-3.19) (-3.91) (-0.46) Inflection point (ha) 87.35 55.04 52.2 38.45 N 1479 1426 1479 1426 R2 0.15 0.26 0.09 0.15 Adj. R2 0.14 0.24 0.08 0.12 Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012) and ACS (2013) Note: t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 *** 126 We test the null hypothesis that including both the linear and quadratic term for farm size is not significantly different from zero. The null hypothesis is rejected and thus we conclude that the positive relationship between operated farm size and labor productivity is only true for farms cultivating in the 0-40 hectares domain depicted by the points of inflection reported in Table 18. To demonstrate the effects of both exogenous (demographic and farm characteristics) and endogenous (crop management and input use) variables, we focus mainly on the net value of crop production per family labor day. According to the restricted specification for net value of crop production per family labor day, education is an important explanatory variable as evidenced by the positive and significant coefficients on the variables “secondary education” and “tertiary education”. Length of growing period and rainfall received are also positively associated with labor productivity. According to the full model, the results show that the same variables that are significant in the vector of exogenous variables in the restricted specification are also important factors in the full specification. For the vector of crop management and input use variables, we find that the returns to family labor are positively associated with total inorganic fertilizer applied per hectare, share of land planted to maize and share of land planted to other cereals but negatively associated with family labor days per hectare. Results for the relationship between cost of maize production per metric ton and maize area planted, ceteris paribus, uphold the IR hypothesis (see Table 19). However, the coefficient on the maize area planted variable is only statistically significant in the restricted model specification. 127 Table 19: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and cost of maize production per metric ton Explanatory variables Dependent variable Cost of maize production per metric ton (ZMW/MT) Restricted Full Maize area planted (ha) 208.77*** 226.45 (3.92) (1.34) Maize area only squared -10.16*** -10.99** (-3.80) (-2.37) Male head (1=yes) -62.63 -143.74 (-0.33) (-0.77) Age of household head -7.07 -8.49 (-1.25) (-1.64) Years in current settlement 20.27*** 16.24*** (4.39) (3.84) Education of household head (base category: primary education) No formal education 38.79 5.74 (0.10) (0.02) Secondary education -167.91 -241.45 (-0.63) (-0.78) *** Tertiary education -879.22 -692.15*** (-3.15) (-2.61) Formal employment (1=yes) 474.19* 366.88 (1.93) (1.41) Local (1=yes) -990.97*** -862.70** (-2.60) (-2.45) Length of growing period (months) -431.30** -335.98 (-2.16) (-1.39) Elevation (meters) 1.15 2.05 (0.53) (0.72) Slope (degrees) 59.65 86.77 (0.55) (0.61) Rainfall (millimeters) -5.23 -3.91 (-1.35) (-0.85) Soil nutrient availability (base category: no or slight constraints) Moderate constraints (1=yes) 190.84 205.88 (0.97) (0.85) * Severe constraints (1=yes) 652.93 664.01* (1.80) (1.79) District fixed effects Yes Yes Operated farm size dummy (1=farms with 5ha and less) 2408.95 (1.01) 128 Table 19 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Dependent variable Cost of maize production per metric ton (ZMW/MT) Restricted Full -4.52*** (-2.67) Total inorganic fertilizer (kg/ha) Share of area planted with: Maize area (%) Beans and oilseeds area (%) Other cereals area (%) Traditional cash crops area (%) Roots and tubers area (%) Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) Manual power (1=yes) Animal draft power (1=yes) Mechanical power (1=yes) Herbicide use (1=yes) Insecticide use (1=yes) Total inorganic fertilizer (kg/ha) X operated farm size dummy Maize area (%) X operated farm size dummy Beans and oil seeds area (%) X operated farm size dummy Other cereals area (%) X operated farm size dummy Traditional cash crops area (%) X operated farm size dummy Roots and tubers area (%) X operated farm size dummy 129 548.98 (0.21) -2412.33* (-1.92) 7596.00 (1.11) 4715.75 (0.90) 5415.98 (1.53) 4.78 (1.11) 39.85 (0.95) -1066.78 (-1.55) 814.91** (2.12) -603.06 (-0.74) 737.56 (0.84) -904.52* (-1.83) 2.42 (1.39) -658.18 (-0.26) 1535.09 (0.84) -7764.06 (-1.13) -5101.43 (-1.00) -6199.86* (-1.66) Table 19 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Dependent variable Cost of maize production per metric ton (ZMW/MT) Restricted Full -3.81 (-0.86) -24.55 Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Manual power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Animal draft power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Mechanical power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Herbicide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Insecticide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Constant 7028.55 (1.64) 10.27 1407 0.04 0.03 (-0.63) 311.16 (0.42) -1183.43** (-2.13) 896.63 (0.80) -784.06 (-0.95) 604.47 (0.99) 2972.63 (0.43) 9.83 1383 0.08 0.04 Inflection point (ha) N R2 Adj. R2 Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012) and ACS (2013) Note: t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 For a one-unit increase in maize area planted, the cost of maize production per metric ton increases by over ZMW 209. This result is significant at 1% confidence level. When we test the null hypothesis that including both the linear and quadratic term for maize area planted is not significantly different from zero, we reject the null hypothesis but we conclude that the positive relationship between maize area planted and cost of maize production per metric ton is true for farms cultivating maize between 0 and 10 hectares (points of inflection reported in Table 19). Beyond this range, the cost of maize production begins to drop. 130 According to the restricted specification, factors that significantly increase the cost of maize production per metric ton include the household head’s number of years in current settlement, whether the head had a formal job, and whether the farm is located on severely constrained soils. On the other hand, the household head attaining tertiary education, whether the head is local, and length of the growing period are all associated with reduction in the cost of maize production per metric ton. For the full model, the results show that the same variables that are significant in the vector of exogenous variables in the restricted specification are also important factors in the full specification. The full model further shows that quantity of total inorganic fertilizer, share of beans and oilseeds area, and whether the farmer used insecticides are variables that are negatively associated with cost of maize production per metric ton produced. On the other hand, share of roots and tubers and whether the household used animal draft power are variables that are positively associated with cost of maize production per metric ton. To fully capture the comprehensive use of different inputs during the crop production process, we estimate the relationship between operated farm size and total factor productivity (Table 20). The results for both the restricted and full model specifications show a negative but insignificant relationship between operated farm size and TFP.8 These results fail to uphold the IR and suggest that, when the measure of productivity is TFP, there is no adequate evidence to support the argument that small farms are more productive than large farms. This finding is similar to that observed in China by Li et al. (2013) where they found that while the relationship between their land size measurement and TFP was negative, it was not statistically negative. 8 Cobb-Douglas production function estimates used to compute TFP at household level are in Table 22. 131 Table 20: Parameter estimates (OLS) of the relationship between operated farm size and total factor productivity Explanatory variables Dependent variable Total factor productivity Restricted Full Operated farm size (ha) -0.58 -1.49 (-0.80) (-1.55) Male head (1=yes) 39.60*** 28.86** (3.25) (2.21) * Age of household head -0.63 -0.26 (-1.86) (-0.78) Years in current settlement -0.35 -0.20 (-1.20) (-0.74) Education of household head (base category: primary education) No formal education 2.41 14.89 (0.13) (0.88) Secondary education 14.32 1.86 (1.28) (0.17) Tertiary education 72.64*** 41.37* (3.14) (1.82) *** Formal employment (1=yes) -38.96 -27.39*** (-3.79) (-2.76) *** Local (1=yes) 35.31 28.27*** (3.48) (2.81) Length of growing period (months) 70.89** 63.19** (2.56) (2.44) Elevation (meters) 0.00 -0.09 (0.01) (-1.50) Slope (degrees) -0.28 3.92 (-0.06) (0.99) Rainfall (millimeters) 0.52*** 0.59*** (2.80) (3.32) Soil nutrient availability (base category: no or slight constraints) Moderate constraints (1=yes) -14.23 -17.62 (-1.21) (-1.53) Severe constraints (1=yes) -43.20*** -39.74*** (-3.19) (-2.98) District fixed effects Yes Yes 132 Table 20 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Operated farm size dummy (1=farms with 5ha and less) Total inorganic fertilizer (kg/ha) Share of area planted with: Maize area (%) Beans and oilseeds area (%) Other cereals area (%) Traditional cash crops area (%) Roots and tubers area (%) Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) Manual power (1=yes) Animal draft power (1=yes) Mechanical power (1=yes) Herbicide use (1=yes) Insecticide use (1=yes) Total inorganic fertilizer (kg/ha) X operated farm size dummy Maize area (%) X operated farm size dummy Beans and oil seeds area (%) X operated farm size dummy Other cereals area (%) X operated farm size dummy Traditional cash crops area (%) X operated farm size dummy Roots and tubers area (%) X operated farm size dummy 133 Dependent variable Total factor productivity Restricted Full -165.26* (-1.81) 0.55*** (5.70) 142.71*** (3.06) 177.99*** (2.80) 18.29 (0.19) 157.48*** (2.73) 11.57 (0.09) 0.06 (0.34) -0.23 (-0.36) -8.18 (-0.30) -86.82* (-1.82) -8.16 (-0.22) -19.56 (-1.39) 37.39** (2.28) -0.20** (-1.99) 100.25 (1.40) 119.21 (1.30) 129.90 (1.08) 211.71** (2.48) 410.66** (2.57) Table 20 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Family labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Dependent variable Total factor productivity Restricted Full -0.01 Hired labor days per hectare (days/ha) X operated farm size dummy Manual power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Animal draft power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Mechanical power (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Herbicide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy Insecticide use (1=yes) X operated farm size dummy -636.55** (-2.14) 1479 0.13 0.12 Constant (-0.03) -0.28 (-0.31) 17.56 (0.51) 59.79 (1.13) -7.56 (-0.16) 67.35*** (3.00) -18.91 (-0.74) -682.09** (-2.38) 1426 0.28 0.25 N R2 Adj. R2 Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012) and ACS (2013) Note: t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Without going through the details of similarities or differences between the restricted and full specifications, the pattern is similar to that observed for our first measure of productivity (net value of crop production per hectare), in particular the signs and levels of significance of the coefficients on the explanatory variables. Table 21 provides a summary of the key findings from this study; whether or not the IR is upheld for each measure of productivity. 134 Table 21: Summary of key findings for the relationship between each measure of productivity and operated farm size Measure of productivity Is the IR upheld? Level of statistical significance Restricted Full Net value of crop production per hectare Yes Yes Only significant in full specification at 10% confidence level Net value of crop production per labor No No Significantly positive farm day (family labor only) size—productivity relationship in both specifications at 1% confidence level Net value of crop production per labor No No Significantly positive farm day (family and hired labor) size—productivity relationship in both specifications at 1% confidence level Cost of maize production per metric ton Yes Yes Only significant in restricted specification at 1% confidence level Total factor productivity Yes Yes Not significant in both specifications 3.3.3. Understanding productivity differences across farm sizes A key aspect of our study is to understand why there are productivity differences between small- (0-5 ha) and medium-scale farms (5-100 ha). To implement this, it is vital to relax the assumption of CRS that is imposed in a number of studies that have hypothesized the IR. As already discussed in the methods section, we relax the assumption of CRS by including interaction terms between a dummy variable for operated farm size (1 = farms with 5 ha or less; 0 = otherwise) and crop management practices/input use variables. The interaction terms test the following hypothesis: the relationship between crop management practices/input use and each measure of productivity is different between small-scale producers and medium-scale producers in our data. Results in Table 17 show that the interaction term between total inorganic fertilizer per hectare and operated farm size dummy is negatively associated (-1.95) with net value of crop 135 production per hectare. This suggests that small-scale farms are less efficient relative to mediums-scale farms in terms of inorganic fertilizer application. However, our results show that the interaction term between herbicide use dummy and operated farm size dummy is positively associated with net value of crop production per hectare and is statistically significant at 1% confidence level. Applying herbicides for weed control increases net value of crop production per hectare more for small-scale farms than medium-scale farms by ZMW 529. These results suggest that when small-scale farmers use a labor saving technology like herbicides, the increase in productivity is relatively higher probably because they are now able to complete weeding tasks faster than medium-scale farms. The other source of difference in net value of crop production per hectare is explained by the allocation of land to traditional cash crops (e.g., cotton) and roots and tubers (e.g., sweet potatoes). The results show that increasing the allocation of land to traditional cash crops and roots and tubers increases net value of crop production per hectare more for small-scale farms than for medium-scale farms by ZMW 1,620 and ZMW 4,027, respectively. What could explain differences in net value of crop production per family labor day between small- (0-5 ha) and medium-scale (5-100 ha) farms? Based on the estimates on interaction terms included in our full model specification (Table 18), we find that differences in labor productivity between the two categories of farms are driven by differences in total inorganic fertilizer use but only by a small magnitude as demonstrated by the coefficient (-0.66). However, other inputs like herbicides and insecticides do not drive labor productivity differences between small- and medium-scale farms (estimates are not statistically significant). Allocating additional land to other cereals (e.g., sorghum) reduces the net value of crop production per family labor day by ZMW 654 for small-scale farms relative to the medium-scale farms. On the 136 other hand, allocating additional family labor per hectare is more beneficial to small- than medium-scale farms (approximately ZMW 2 per labor day increase in net value of crop production per family labor day). For cost of maize production per metric ton (Table 19), we find that differences in the cost of maize production per metric ton between the two categories of farms are not driven by differences in fertilizer use or other inputs like herbicides and insecticides (estimates are not statistically significant). We only find that use of animal draft power is more beneficial to smallthan medium-scale farms (approximately ZMW 1,300 reduction in the cost of maize production per metric ton). We also find that differences in total factor productivity between small-scale and medium-scale farms can be explained by differences in the effects of: (1) inorganic fertilizer application (additional units of inorganic fertilizer are negatively associated with changes in TFP on small-scale farms relative to medium-scale farms); (2) the allocation of an additional unit of land to traditional cash crops (e.g., cotton) which increases total factor productivity by over 200 TFP units more for small-scale farms than medium-scale farms; (3) the allocation of an additional unit of land to roots and tubers (e.g., sweet potatoes) which increase total factor productivity by over 400 TFP units for small-scale farms relative to medium-scale farms; (4) herbicide use (herbicide use is positively associated with changes in TFP on small-scale farms relative to medium-scale farms). Lastly, we report findings from graphs (Figures 5 to 9) which depict the relationship between operated farm size and alternative predicted values of each measure of productivity: (1) predicted values obtained from the ceteris paribus restricted model, and; (2) predicted values obtained from the full model when crop management practices vary across farms. This empirical 137 approach helps us to compare IR hypothesis tests between the scenarios when the CRS assumption is still imposed (first set of alternative predicted values) and when the assumption is relaxed (second set of alternative predicted values). Figure 5 shows that although farm size is negatively associated with net value of crop production per hectare when using predicted values from the ceteris paribus restricted model, the relationship is negatively steeper when predicted values obtained from the full model are used. This finding suggests that relaxing the CRS assumption further strengthens the IR hypothesis in the case of land productivity. Figure 5: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of net value of crop production per hectare (with and without CRS assumption) Figures 6 and 7 illustrate the relationship between operated farm size and alternative predicted values of the two labor productivity measures constructed in this study. Both figures show that when the constant returns-to-scale assumption is imposed, the relationship between operated farm size and each measure of labor productivity is positive and steeper than when the CRS assumption is relaxed. This finding suggests that relaxing the CRS assumption actually 138 weakens the argument that large farms are more productive than small farms in terms of labor productivity. Figure 6: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of net value of crop production per family labor day (with and without CRS assumption) Figure 7: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of net value of crop production per labor day (with and without CRS assumption) 139 Figure 8 shows that when the CRS assumption is imposed, the cost of maize production is positively related with maize area planted between 0 - 10 hectares but the relationship reverses beyond ten hectares. The graph depicting the relationship between cost of maize production per metric ton produced and maize planted when the assumption of constant returns-to-scale is relaxed reveals a similar pattern as in the case when the assumption is imposed. This means that in the case of the fourth measure of productivity—cost of maize production per metric ton produced—relaxing the constant returns-to-scale assumption is not that different from the case when the assumption is imposed. Figure 8: Operated farm size versus alternative predicted values of cost of maize production per metric ton produced (with and without CRS assumption) The last figure (Figure 9) demonstrates that the relationship between TFP and operated farm size is negative in both scenarios (imposed/restricted model and relaxed/full model). However, similar to net value of crop production per hectare, relaxing the CRS assumption reveals a negative but steeper relationship between TFP and operated farm size, which 140 strengthens the argument for the existence of an inverse relationship between farm size and productivity. Figure 9: Operated farm size and alternative predicted values of total factor productivity (with and without CRS assumption) In sum, Figures 5 – 9 demonstrate that relaxing the CRS assumption either strengthens the IR hypothesis (in the case of net value of crop production per hectare and TFP) or weakens the argument that large farms are more productive than small farms (in the case of the two labor productivity measures). This important finding points to the fact that previous studies looking at the farm size-productivity hypothesis have probably understated the extent of the existence of an IR because they have generally imposed the CRS assumption. Therefore, apart from extending the methodological approach used in the literature, the current study further proposes that studies looking at this topical issue in development should lift the CRS assumption in order to get better insights. 141 3.4. Conclusions and implications for policy The interest by development scholars to revisit the IR hypothesis is mainly driven by the need to guide policy on whether smallholder-led agriculture remains a viable pathway to achieve the much-needed changes in the economic fortunes for the majority of rural SSA. Equally important is the need to examine the hypothesis under conditions with very different relative factor abundance than where most of the other studies have been done. Very few studies have been comprehensive in terms of using alternative measures of productivity other than land productivity, to explore the relationship between farm size and productivity. Moreover, as observed by Collier and Dercon (2014) and demonstrated by our review of past empirical literature, a critical number of studies conducted in Africa have on one hand included very few farms outside the zero to ten hectare range while on the other hand have extrapolated their findings beyond this farm size range. Furthermore, past empirical studies have been modeled on the assumption that returns to scale in agricultural production are constant. While the assumption may have been appropriate for studying the IR across small farms, it is less relevant when extending beyond this range to include medium- and large-scale farms. The current study addressed these gaps and the following findings emerged. First, when the IR hypothesis was tested using representative data with about 15 percent of farms with landholding sizes of 20 hectares or more, the results were not uniform across the five measures of productivity used in the study. The relationship between farm size and productivity upheld the IR, rejected the IR or was uncorrelated depending on the measure of productivity. Results showed that when net value of crop production per hectare was regressed on farm size ceteris paribus, the IR was upheld at 10 percent significance level. This modest level of significance 142 could be attributed to the fact that, unlike in past studies where input use intensity has been found to be higher on small relative to large farms, the opposite was true in the case of this study. When the outcome variable was a labor productivity measure, we found a strong positive relationship between farm size and labor productivity similar to Li et al. (2013). In the case of cost of maize production per metric ton produced, we found that the cost of maize production per ton increased with maize area planted of up to 10 hectares. This result upheld the IR because small farms were able to produce a ton of maize at a cheaper cost than large farms, but only for the 0 – 10 hectares domain. The estimation results for TFP showed that this comprehensive measure of productivity was negatively associated with operated farm size albeit not statistically significant. Second, we found that differences in crop management practices played a key role in driving productivity differences between small- and medium-scale farms. Management practices that were prominent in explaining productivity differences were total inorganic fertilizer use, herbicide use, animal draft power use and the nature of land allocation to different crop types. Third, relaxing the CRS assumption either strengthened the IR hypothesis (in the case of net value of crop production per hectare and TFP) or weakened the argument that large farms are more productive than small farms (in the case of the two labor productivity measures). Overall, the following insights were gleaned from the key findings. Research that focuses on making comparisons of productivity across farm sizes should extend beyond idiosyncratic indicators of productivity that only assess land productivity. As shown in this study, results emanating from using a more comprehensive set of productivity measures are not exactly identical. This study shows that while small farms are more productive when considering net value of crop production per hectare and the cost of producing a staple food crop like maize, 143 large farms are productive in terms of labor productivity associated with aggregate crop production on farm. What do these findings imply especially at the time when smallholder-led agricultural growth strategies have been questioned? In truth, findings on the relationship between productivity and operated farm size, while important, should not be the decisive factor in guiding agricultural development and land policies in SSA because there are many other important considerations. The challenges of rural poverty that continue to bedevil SSA are better addressed by pursuing broad based development strategies whose central focus should remain smallholder farmers. This entails promoting policies that would enhance productivity growth among smallholders, as this is crucial to poverty reduction and development. Moreover, an inclusive smallholder form of agricultural growth will clearly generate employment growth in both farm and non-farm sectors than a comparable rate of agricultural growth concentrated among a few large farms. This is very clear from the factor-intensity graphs in Figure 3 showing how laborland and labor-capital intensities fall dramatically as farm size increases beyond five hectares. As argued by Jayne et al. (2014, p48), “the employment effects and growth multipliers resulting from broadly based agricultural growth are likely to contribute much more to economic growth and poverty reduction than from any potential efficiency advantages that large farms might have…”. Pioneering work by Mellor and Johnston (1984) contrasting employment effects from smallholder Asia versus Latifundia Latin America as well as more recent work by Christiaensen, Demery, and Kuhl (2011) show that inclusive forms of agricultural growth generate much greater growth and employment multipliers than agricultural growth concentrated among relatively few large farms. However, the challenges of achieving broad-based inclusive forms of agricultural growth remain daunting. 144 While migration from farm to non-farm sectors, and from rural to urban areas will provide the brightest prospects for the transformation and modernization of Africa’s economies, it will happen only as fast as educational advances and growth in the non-farm job opportunities will allow. The rate of growth of non-farm jobs in turn depends on the rate of income growth among the millions of families still engaged in smallholder agriculture. So there is a symbiotic relationship between inclusive agricultural growth, nonfarm sector growth, and poverty reduction. 145 APPENDIX 146 Figure 10: Map of Zambia showing location of ACS and RALS households 147 Table 22: Production function estimates used for TFP estimation Estimated results 9.16*** (28.71) 0.36*** (12.58) 0.01 (0.27) 0.79*** (28.71) 1.16 𝑙𝑛𝐴0 + 𝜂𝑡 𝛼𝐾 𝛼𝐿 𝛼𝑀 𝑅𝑇𝑆 = 𝛼𝐾 + 𝛼𝐿 + 𝛼𝑀 𝛼𝐾∗ 0.31 𝛼𝐿∗ 0.01 ∗ 𝛼𝑀 0.69 R2 0.63 F-statistic 826.18 Source: Authors’ computation from RALS (2012) and ACS (2013) Note: t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 148 REFERENCES 149 REFERENCES Ali, D. A., & Deininger, K. (2015). Is There a Farm Size–Productivity Relationship in African Agriculture? Evidence from Rwanda. Land Economics, 91(2), 317–343. Assunção, J. J., & Braido, L. H. B. (2007). Testing Household-Specific Explanations for the Inverse Productivity Relationship. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89(4), 980–990. Barrett, C. B. (1996). On price risk and the inverse farm size-productivity relationship. Journal of Development Economics, 51(2), 193–215. https://doi.org/10.1016/S03043878(96)00412-9 Barrett, C. B., Bellemare, M. F., & Hou, J. Y. (2010). Reconsidering conventional explanations of the inverse productivity–size relationship. World Development, 38(1), 88–97. Berry, R. A., & Cline, W. R. (1979). Agrarian Structure and Productivity in Developing Countries: A Study Prepared for the International Labour Office Within the Framework of the World Employment Programme. John Hopkins University Press. Bhalla, S. S., & Roy, P. (1988). Mis-Specification in Farm Productivity Analysis: The Role of Land Quality. Oxford Economic Papers, 40(1), 55–73. Binswanger, H. P., Deininger, K., & Feder, G. (1995). Chapter 42 Power, distortions, revolt and reform in agricultural land relations. In J. B. and T. N. Srinivasan (Ed.), Handbook of Development Economics (Vol. 3, Part B, pp. 2659–2772). Elsevier. Retrieved from http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1573447195300198 Block, S. (2010). The decline and rise of agricultural productivity in sub-Saharan Africa since 1961. National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w16481 Carletto, C., Savastano, S., & Zezza, A. (2013). Fact or artifact: The impact of measurement errors on the farm size–productivity relationship. Journal of Development Economics, 103, 254–261. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.03.004 Carter, M. R. (1984). Identification of the Inverse Relationship between Farm Size and Productivity: An Empirical Analysis of Peasant Agricultural Production. Oxford Economic Papers, 36(1), 131–145. Chapoto, A., Kabaghe, C., & Zulu-Mbata, O. (2015). The Politics of the Maize Sector in Zambia. In A. Chapoto & N. J. Sitko (Eds.), Agriculture in Zambia: Past, Present, and Future (pp. 55–71). Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI). 150 Chen, Z., Huffman, W. E., & Rozelle, S. (2011). Inverse Relationship Between Productivity and Farm Size: The Case of China. Contemporary Economic Policy, 29(4), 580–592. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7287.2010.00236.x Christiaensen, L., Demery, L., & Kuhl, J. (2011). The (evolving) role of agriculture in poverty reduction—An empirical perspective. Journal of Development Economics, 96(2), 239– 254. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.10.006 Collier, P., & Dercon, S. (2014). African Agriculture in 50Years: Smallholders in a Rapidly Changing World? World Development, 63, 92–101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.10.001 Deininger, K., & Byerlee, D. (2012). The Rise of Large Farms in Land Abundant Countries: Do They Have a Future? World Development, 40(4), 701–714. Diao, X., Hazell, P. B. R., Resnick, D., & Thurlow, J. (2007). The Role of Agriculture in Development: Implications for Sub-Saharan Africa. Intl Food Policy Res Inst. Dorward, A. (1999). Farm Size and Productivity in Malawian Smallholder Agriculture. Journal of Development Studies, 35(5), 141. Eswaran, M., & Kotwal, A. (1986). Access to Capital and Agrarian Production Organisation. Economic Journal, 96(382), 482–98. Fan, S. (1991). Effects of Technological Change and Institutional Reform on Production Growth in Chinese Agriculture. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73(2), 266–275. https://doi.org/10.2307/1242711 Feder, G., Just, R. E., & Zilberman, D. (1985). Adoption of Agricultural Innovations in Developing Countries: A Survey. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 33(2), 255–298. https://doi.org/10.1086/451461 Fischer, G., Velthuizen, H. V., Nachtergaele, F. O., & Jernelöv, A. (2000). Global AgroEcological Zones Assessment: Methodology and Results. Hazell, P. B. R. (2005). Is there a future for small farms? Agricultural Economics, 32, 93–101. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0169-5150.2004.00016.x Heltberg, R. (1998). Rural market imperfections and the farm size—productivity relationship: Evidence from Pakistan. World Development, 26(10), 1807–1826. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(98)00084-9 Holden, S., & Fisher, M. (2013). Can area measurement error explain the inverse farm size productivity relationship? Centre for Land Tenure Studies, Norwegian University of Life Sciences. Retrieved from http://www.researchgate.net/publication/257526369_Can_Area_Measurement_Error_Ex plain_the_Inverse_Farm_Size_Productivity_Relationship/file/3deec5255aa9f2f5ff.pdf 151 Jayne, T. S., Chamberlin, J., & Muyanga, M. (2012). Emerging Land Issues in African Agriculture: Implications for food security and poverty reduction strategies (Stanford Symposium Series on Global Food Policy and Food Security in the 21st Century). Stanford University. Jayne, T. S., Chamberlin, J., Traub, L., Sitko, N., Muyanga, M., Yeboah, F. K., … Kachule, R. (2016). Africa’s changing farm size distribution patterns: the rise of medium-scale farms. Agricultural Economics, 47(S1), 197–214. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12308 Jayne, T. S., Chapoto, A., Sitko, N., Nkonde, C., Muyanga, M., & Chamberlin, J. (2014). Is the Scramble for Land in Africa Foreclosing a Smallholder Agricultural Expansion Strategy? Journal of International Affairs, 67(2), 35–53. Kevane, M. (1996). Agrarian Structure and Agricultural Practice: Typology and Application to Western Sudan. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78(1), 236–245. https://doi.org/10.2307/1243794 Kimhi, A. (2006). Plot size and maize productivity in Zambia: is there an inverse relationship? Agricultural Economics, 35(1), 1–9. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2006.00133.x Lal, R. (1995). Erosion-Crop Productivity Relationships for Soils of Africa. Soil Science Society of America Journal, 59(3), 661. https://doi.org/10.2136/sssaj1995.03615995005900030004x Lamb, R. L. (2003). Inverse productivity: land quality, labor markets, and measurement error. Journal of Development Economics, 71(1), 71–95. https://doi.org/10.1016/S03043878(02)00134-7 Land Matrix. (2015). Zambia - LAND MATRIX. Retrieved June 19, 2015, from http://www.landmatrix.org/en/get-the-detail/by-targetcountry/zambia/?order_by=&starts_with=Z Larson, D. F., Otsuka, K., Matsumoto, T., & Kilic, T. (2014). Should African rural development strategies depend on smallholder farms? An exploration of the inverse-productivity hypothesis. Agricultural Economics, 45(3), 355–367. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12070 Li, G., Feng, Z., You, L., & Fan, L. (2013). Re-examining the inverse relationship between farm size and efficiency: The empirical evidence in China. China Agricultural Economic Review, 5(4), 473–488. https://doi.org/http://dx.doi.org.proxy2.cl.msu.edu/10.1108/CAER-09-2011-0108 Lombard, C. S. & T., A. H. C. (1972). Agriculture in Zambia since Independence. Neczam. Mellor, J. W., & Johnston, B. F. (1984). The World Food Equation: Interrelations Among Development, Employment, and Food Consumption. Journal of Economic Literature, 22(2), 531. 152 Mosley, P. (2002). The African green revolution as a pro-poor policy instrument. Journal of International Development, 14(6), 695–724. https://doi.org/10.1002/jid.912 Nachtergaele, F., & Batjes, N. (2012). Harmonized world soil database. FAO. Retrieved from http://www.fao.org/nr/water/docs/harm-world-soil-dbv7cv.Pdf Sen, A. (1962). An Aspect of Indian Agriculture. Economic Weekly, Annual Number 14. Sitko, N. J., & Jayne, T. S. (2014). Structural transformation or elite land capture? The growth of “emergent” farmers in Zambia. Food Policy, 48, 194–202. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2014.05.006 Sitko, N. J., Jayne, T. S., & Hichaambwa, M. (2013). Emergent Farmer Growth Trajectories in Zambia: Land Accumulation and its Implications for Poverty Reduction. Presented at the Annual World Bank Conference on Land and Poverty, Washington, D.C. Toufique, K. A. (2005). Farm Size and Productivity in Bangladesh Agriculture: Role of Transaction Costs in Rural Labour Markets. Economic and Political Weekly, 40(10), 988–992. Verschelde, M., D’Haese, M., Rayp, G., & Vandamme, E. (2013). Challenging Small-Scale Farming: A Non-Parametric Analysis of the (Inverse) Relationship Between Farm Productivity and Farm Size in Burundi. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64(2), 319– 342. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-9552.2012.00373.x Zhang, B., & Carter, C. A. (1997). Reforms, the Weather, and Productivity Growth in China’s Grain Sector. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79(4), 1266–1277. https://doi.org/10.2307/1244283 153 CHAPTER 4: AGRICULTURAL MECHANIZATION IN ZAMBIA: TRENDS AND EFFECTS ON HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION 4.1. Introduction Access to improved technologies by agricultural households in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) engenders increased agricultural production and productivity, which are important conditions for reducing high poverty rates and persistent food insecurities (Minten & Barrett, 2008). Where investment in agricultural research and development (R&D) has been made, delivery of improved technologies to farmers has largely been successful which in turn has spurred agricultural total factor productivity growth (Fugile & Rada, 2013). Improved seed varieties and inorganic fertilizers have received particular attention in harnessing desired productivity improvements in Africa. As such, research examining the African agricultural transformation process has focused more on adoption of these technologies, and the policies needed to promote their adoption (Houssou et al., 2013). Yet, agricultural mechanization—the application of powered machinery to agricultural production—and the potential role it can play to enhance agricultural production, has not been a prominent feature in recent research on agricultural development in SSA. This lack of prominence could be attributed to two reasons explained below. First, most mechanization programs promoted by African governments in the 1980’s and prior to that, failed (Binswanger & Pingali, 1988; Houssou et al., 2013). Logically, tractors were thought to be appropriate for SSA given the region’s land abundance at the time (Binswanger & Pingali, 1988). Practically, the transition from hand cultivation through animal traction to greater use of tractors had to be driven by population pressure increases and gradual changes in cropping patterns from bush or forest fallow to intensive agricultural production (Pingali, Bigot, & Binswanger-Mkhize, 1987). Further, the transition from hand tools was only achievable if 154 alternatives (animal traction or tractors) were perceived to be cost-effective by farmers. Unfortunately, policy makers in SSA imposed alternatives through subsidized mechanization programs that disregarded the criteria for adoption. This led to a higher failure rate of these programs. As a result, mechanization was essentially pushed to the bottom of the agricultural development priority list. This contributed to lower levels of agricultural mechanization promotion and use across the region compared with the rest of the developing world. For example, of the total area cultivated for crop production in SSA at the turn of this century, about 65 percent was achieved through the use of hand tools while 25 percent was by animal draft power, and 10 percent was by tractors (Takeshima & Salau, 2010). Meanwhile, tractor use in other developing regions was significantly higher (35 percent) than SSA during the same period. Second, the re-emergence of input subsidy programs (ISPs) across SSA in recent years has helped to enhance the promotion of improved seed varieties and chemical fertilizers (RickerGilbert, Jayne, & Shively, 2013). Mechanization, on the other hand, has not been part of the package of technologies promoted alongside these ISPs. In light of the high cost of these ISPs, policy makers and development experts in SSA have been more concerned with investigating the impacts of associated technologies (seed and fertilizer) on livelihoods of individual agricultural households, the rural economy and overall national welfare. In view of these reasons, it is not surprising that agricultural mechanization has not been given much attention by researchers concerned with agricultural transformation and development in SSA. However, current anecdotal evidence indicating that farm labor costs in SSA have been increasing (Takeshima et al., 2013) and recent empirical estimates in countries like Zambia showing that labor (family and hired labor) accounts for more than 60 percent of the cost of 155 production of maize (Burke et al., 2011) suggests that mechanization deserves more attention. Coincidentally, there has been a rise in the number of agricultural mechanization initiatives in parts of SSA (including Zambia) that involve the public sector, the private sector and farmer organizations aimed at promoting mechanization among small- and medium-scale farming households. In light of the rise of domestic medium-scale land investors in parts of SSA (Jayne et al., 2016) who might be more inclined to demand mechanization services, the need for research that reassesses the role of agricultural mechanization in enhancing agricultural development has become imperative. The aims of this paper is to examine agricultural mechanization trends, effects on agricultural household production and the factors contributing to recent developments aimed at enhancing mechanization in SSA based on the case study of Zambia. This study contributes to the emerging research aimed at guiding policy on mechanization in SSA (Mrema et al., 2008; Houssou et al., 2013; Takeshima et al., 2013; Diao et al., 2014). Further, it provides useful insights to private sector actors, farmers and farmer organizations on the sustainability of agricultural mechanization initiatives that have recently been promoted in parts of SSA and Zambia in particular. Consequently, this research investigates three main questions as stated below using the case study of Zambia: 1. How has mechanization use for agricultural production across small- and medium-scale farming households evolved in recent years? What is the level of tractor-hiring service provision and use among small- and medium-scale farming households for agricultural production? 156 2. What is the effect of mechanization on the following indicators: (i) area cultivated, and; (ii) net value of crop production per hectare? Is mechanization likely to have a positive effect on both of these indicators? 3. What are the factors contributing to the rise of agricultural mechanization initiatives in Zambia? Are changes in factor price ratios inducing demand for these services? Alternatively, what opportunities on the supply side are encouraging the rise of these services? The rest of this paper is organized follows. The following section reviews the background literature on the historical perspectives and recent developments of agricultural mechanization within the context of SSA and Zambia. Next, the data and methods used in the current study are described while the results are presented and discussed in the penultimate section. The last section concludes and provides implications for agricultural mechanization policy. 4.2. Background 4.2.1. Agricultural mechanization in SSA and Zambia: historical perspective Promotion and use of agricultural mechanization is not new to SSA. During the early colonial period (before the second world war), tractor use was mainly among European settler farms and government-run farms (Pingali, 2007). After the Second World War, African farmers also started using tractors because financing of tractor imports was made possible by a fund for farm machinery established through the Marshall Plan (ibid). When African countries gained political independence from the 1960’s through the 1970’s, some of the governments were directly involved in the supply of tractors during the early stages of independence until the 1980’s (Houssou et al., 2013). Overall, there were three significant waves during which agricultural mechanization use was actively promoted in Africa from the colonial period up to 157 the 1980’s (Pingali, 2007). The three waves could be classified as follows: (1) colonial influenced agricultural mechanization initiatives (1945-1955); (2) state sponsored agricultural mechanization initiatives promoted during the initial stages of political independence (19581970), and; (3) state sponsored agricultural mechanization initiatives promoted as a consequence of gains from mineral resource exports (1970-1980). Interestingly, the number of tractors in SSA during the post-independence period (second wave) was higher than other developing regions of the world (for example Asia and Latin America), which suggested at the time that SSA was on a trajectory of enhancing agricultural mechanization at a faster rate than the rest of the developing world. To put this in perspective, SSA had approximately two, three and six times more tractors in use than in Brazil, India and China respectively (Mrema et al., 2008). However, the level of mechanization in these three countries steadily increased and surpassed SSA in part because the increase in factor prices for labor and animal draft power was relatively higher in the aforementioned countries. By the year 2000, Brazil, India and China now had consecutively, four, seven, and four times more tractors in use than the entire SSA region (ibid). As a consequence, some agricultural indicators such as profitability in other parts of the developing world have steadily improved relative to SSA because of increased use of improved technologies including mechanization. In China, for example, productivity has increased over time, in part because of the rapid increase in farm mechanization ownership and provision of farm mechanization services for labor-intensive activities such as land preparation and harvesting (Yang et al., 2013). In India, it has been shown that farm mechanization has led to increased use of other productivity enhancing inputs, increased cropland, improved labor productivity and enhanced profitability of agriculture (Verma, 2008). 158 The situation in SSA has, however, been different. Despite the fact that mechanization has several benefits—timeliness of field operations, reducing the drudgery associated with farm work and can be used for numerous tasks on and off the farm—the level of agricultural mechanization use in most of SSA has remained low. Moreover, data from countries where tractor use showed promise during the three waves discussed above, suggests that levels of mechanization have remarkably reduced (Pingali, 2007). The reason for the persistently low levels of agricultural mechanization has been attributed to low agricultural intensification and lack of incentives for increasing productivity growth in SSA (ibid). Where countries showed promise in terms of enhancing agricultural mechanization (countries that experienced the three waves discussed above), the initiatives largely failed due to direct involvement by governments in the supply of mechanization services, which undoubtedly contributed to low efficiency and high cost without sustainability (Pingali, Bigot, & Binswanger-Mkhize, 1987). Zambia, to a larger extent, presents an interesting case study because the country experienced the three waves of agricultural mechanization use discussed above. Pingali (2007) identifies four countries in SSA, including Zambia, where promotion of tractor use could be traced back to the colonial period (first wave). After independence (second and third wave), the Zambian government wanted to modernize the agriculture sector by establishing various tractor schemes that distributed tractors, implements and tools to small-scale farmers (Jonsson, 1985). While there were a few exceptions, most tractor schemes established in Zambia, like in the case of other SSA countries, performed poorly and became very expensive to sustain. By mid-1980’s, government policy had shifted away from active promotion of tractors to promotion of animal draft power as summarized below: 159 “Animal [draft] power will form a basis for mechanization in Zambia because animals involve very little foreign exchange and they are appropriate for most of the farm operations required by the majority of the farming sector in Zambia who own between five to 40 hectare[s] of land” (Tembo, 1985, p. 32). 4.2.2. Agricultural mechanization in SSA and Zambia: recent developments Although agricultural mechanization has remained low on the policy agenda of most SSA countries till today, some governments have begun to reemphasize the need to establish mechanization initiatives that are funded either publicly, privately or both. A good example of a country in SSA where mechanization initiatives have resurfaced is Ghana. According to Houssou et al. (2013), the Government of Ghana (GoG) initiated the Agricultural Mechanization Service Enterprise Centers (AMSECS) concept as a response to increasing demand for mechanization services by farmers who could not afford required machinery for land preparation. Support to the AMSECs started in 2007 which involved subsidies to the privately run centers for the purchase of tractors, implements such as plows and harrows, and haulage equipment (trailers). The GoG subsidized 30 percent of the purchase price of the equipment while each AMSEC made an up-front payment of 20 percent with the remainder paid in installments for two to three years. Other countries that have begun to support agricultural mechanization initiatives in the last five to ten years include Nigeria, Tanzania, Mali and the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC) with financial support from emerging economies such as Brazil, China and India (Diao et al., 2014). Similarly, there has been a recent drive to enhance agricultural mechanization promotion and use among small- and medium-scale farms in Zambia through initiatives spearheaded by agribusiness firms, farmer organizations, financial institutions and the Zambian government. In 160 2012, three pilot initiatives were operational in Zambia, one promoted by Dunavant Cotton (now NWK Agri-services), the second by AFGRI with the support of Conservation Farming Unit (CFU) and Musika Development Initiatives Limited, and the third by the Ministry of Agriculture (MoA) and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations with a total of 58 Tractor Service Providers (TSPs) operating at the time (Aagaard, 2012). These initiatives have since been remodeled to include other partners and products on offer, and have expanded the number of TSPs; about 448 TSPs are operating in the field (Kasanda, 2016). Although each initiative may vary from the other, they typically involve selection of suitably qualified farmers—those with good entrepreneurial skills and credit history—to access available credit facilities intended for TSPs. The organization with presence in the farming areas—usually a farmer organization or non-governmental organization—is responsible for selecting beneficiaries (identified TSPs) and providing technical and business training to them. Financing the purchase of equipment proceeds as follows. First, financial institutions provide loans once it is established that selected beneficiaries meet the general terms and conditions of the bank. Second, selected beneficiaries are expected to pay a deposit (over 20 percent in most cases) towards the purchase of the equipment from a tractor supplier. Third, selected beneficiaries are expected to repay the loan, with interest, within a period not exceeding three years. Fourth, most of these initiatives include a provision of first loss guarantee, which is managed by one of the parties to the agreement. Existing mechanization initiatives have been designed in such a way that selected TSPs choose their preferred combination of equipment needed. Equipment includes tractors (various sizes between 37 to 100 horsepower), rippers (most mechanization initiatives are promoting minimum tillage), planters and trailers for haulage. Because these initiatives have been designed 161 to facilitate the growth of TSPs, one of the key indicators of whether TSPs are performing according to expectations is the number farmers/hectares serviced for land preparation. According to a model developed in 2012, a single TSP can reasonably provide land preparation services (ripping) to a total of 180 farmers (180ha) (ACF, 2012). In addition, the same model estimates that a single TSP can provide services for planting, spraying and transportation to 165, 60 and 78 farmers respectively. Therefore, a TSP meeting the aforementioned targets could be considered to be operating optimally. In sum, recent developments aimed at enhancing agricultural mechanization in SSA demonstrate that countries in the region recognize the important role that mechanization plays in improving agriculture. Whether these new initiatives represent the right business model that would address challenges of mechanization programs of yesteryear is an issue that is of empirical significance and hence the relevance of this study. 4.3. Data and methods This research combines qualitative and quantitative methods to examine agricultural mechanization in Zambia in line with three research questions. First, how has mechanization use for agricultural production (including the level tractor-hiring service provision) evolved in recent years? Second, what has been the effect of mechanization on area cultivated and net value of crop production per hectare? Third, what are the factors contributing to the rise of agricultural mechanization initiatives in Zambia? An explanatory sequential mixed-methods approach was used during this research and this involved the following steps. The first step involved collecting both secondary (national level data) and primary (six districts) household survey data. The survey data were initially analyzed and the findings from this analysis informed the subsequent development of interview 162 guides for the qualitative phase of the study. Each of these approaches is discussed in turn and the section concludes with a detailed description of data analysis techniques used to answer each research question. 4.3.1. Phase 1: quantitative data collection The quantitative data were collected using secondary and primary data sources. The secondary data sources were drawn from two nationally representative surveys conducted in Zambia in the last decade or so. The first nationally representative source of secondary data that the study relied on was various years of the Crop Forecast Surveys (CFS) of small-, mediumand large-scale farms in Zambia beginning from 2001. The Central Statistical Office (CSO) of Zambia conducts the CFSs on an annual basis in collaboration with the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL). The CFSs are designed to collect data from an average of 12,000 households on key agricultural production parameters during each agricultural season that runs from October 1 to September 30 the following year. Because it is not practical to collect all policy-relevant information in this annual survey, this study relied on another secondary source of nationally representative data—the Rural Agricultural Livelihoods Survey (RALS) of small and medium-scale farming households in Zambia collected in 2012 and 2015. The RALS is a longitudinal survey conducted by the Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI) in conjunction with the two aforementioned public offices. The RALS used the new sampling frame derived from the 2010 population census of Zambia. A total of 8,839 and 7,934 households were interviewed during the 2012 and 2015 surveys respectively. The survey collected data on a number of questions related to the following main themes: demographic characteristics of household members; farmland and use; crop sales from own production; input and credit acquisition; livestock ownership and marketing; off-farm 163 income sources; food security indicators, and; other themes such as kinship ties of the household head. In addition, soil samples were collected from largest maize fields of sub-sampled households during the 2012 survey. The final source of quantitative data used in this study was primary data collected through the Agricultural Commercialization Survey (ACS). The ACS mainly targeted mediumscale farms in Zambia and had a more elaborate module dedicated to agricultural mechanization among this group of relatively land-endowed farmers. The ACS of 2013 was a follow-up to a survey of medium-scale farms conducted in Zambia in 2011 by Sitko & Jayne (2012) with assistance from the author of this paper. The main objective of the ACS was to understand the history, characteristics, land use decisions and patterns, and level of commercialization of medium-scale farmers observed to be a growing class of farmers in Zambia. Similar to the first survey, the 2013 ACS survey purposively selected research sites (administrative districts) based on the concentration and number of medium-scale farms as reported in the 2010/2011 CFS. Two main criteria were used to select the districts included in the survey. First, at least 3 percent of farming households had to be classified as medium-scale farms in order to ensure a reasonable population from which to sample. Second, the research sites were selected along a continuum of concentrations to ensure geographical diversity. But as noted by Sitko & Chamberlin (2015), because medium-scale farms are concentrated along what is referred to as the ‘line of rail’ in Zambia, the selected districts were in close proximity to this region. The line of rail is a region of Zambia that is served by the railway linking the Copperbelt province with Lusaka, and with the border town Livingstone that is south of the country. 164 Therefore, the six selected districts were Chibombo, Choma, Chongwe, Kalomo, Mpongwe and Mumbwa. A total of 482 households were randomly selected from a list of medium-scale farms generated in consultation with the Zambia National Farmers’ Union (ZNFU) and the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) district offices. The Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock (MAL) block areas were identified as the sampling units with help from local district offices. Whereas the sampling procedure was supposed to ensure reasonable representativeness of farmers in the 5-100 hectare category within the selected districts, the sample may have not been statistically representative of all medium-scale farmers in Zambia. This is because medium-scale farmers were not sampled from the other 65 districts. But we can say that the chosen districts are understood to contain the highest proportions of farms in this size class. 4.3.2. Phase 2: qualitative data collection Qualitative data were collected through key informant interviews of 48 purposively sampled respondents. These interviews targeted: (1) farmers (small- and medium-scale farmers); (2) community leaders and relevant district officials, and; (3) national level stakeholders. The study also conducted additional in-depth interviews with specific stakeholders involved in mechanization service provision in Zambia. For each interview, detailed notes were taken and where the interviewee consented, an audio recorder was used to capture the full interview. At the end of each day, the field notes and audio recordings were fully transcribed in readiness for analysis. Each source for qualitative data is described here in turn. 165 4.3.2.1. Farmer in-depth interviews The in-depth interviews with farmers allowed the researcher to get further insights on issues not adequately addressed during the survey such as the following: (1) why they became farmers and what motivated them to acquire land; (2) agricultural land use and farmers’ perception of critical drivers; (3) agricultural technology choices, and; (4) relationship between farm structure change and prevailing institutions and policies. The component of the interview that asked questions on agricultural technology choices primarily focused on sources of power for land preparation used by the farmers and the role that agricultural mechanization plays in enhancing farmers’ production levels. A total of 24 farmer in-depth interviews were conducted, with 12 small-scale farmers and 12 medium-scale farmers. The in-depth interviews were conducted in the six districts were household survey data was collected using the ACS. The study first identified two medium-scale farmer in-depth interview participants per district using the ACS list. Selection of the participants was based on the trajectory the household followed to achieve medium-scale farmer status: organic growth through small-scale farming or lateral entry through non-farm income. Using snowball sampling, the study then selected small-scale farmers who were neighbors to the medium-scale farmers who participated in the in-depth interviews. 4.3.2.2. Community leader in-depth interviews While a significant part of the interviews was dedicated to land acquisition patterns in respective communities, the community leaders selected for this study also had to have extensive knowledge on agricultural mechanization development in the community. The community leader interviews targeted two community leaders in each of the six districts. In each district, the study undertook interviews with one village headman from the agricultural blocks visited during the 166 survey and one high level official working for one of the key government ministries at district level with knowledge about the evolution of farm ownership and agricultural mechanization use in the district. In total, the study interviewed 12 community leaders. 4.3.2.3. Interviews with national-level stakeholders The national level stakeholders helped to give a national perspective on agricultural mechanization development in Zambia. A total of twelve national level stakeholder interviews were conducted with senior officials at relevant government ministries (Ministry of Agriculture, Ministry of Lands etc.), civil society organizations dealing with land issues in Zambia such as the Zambia Land Alliance (ZLA), farmer organizations such as the Zambia National Farmers’ Union (ZNFU), private sector firms and experts on agricultural development issues in Zambia. 4.3.2.4. Interviews of mechanization service providers To supplement the researcher’s understanding of opportunities and constraints associated with agricultural mechanization on the supply side, the study conducted additional interviews with main actors involved in recent mechanization initiatives in Zambia. These interviews were implemented to get a much more detailed picture of what is driving mechanization initiatives, successes realized so far, constraints likely to undermine mechanization efforts and sustainability of these initiatives as perceived by those implementing them. A total of six interviews were conducted with key actors in mechanization service provision in Zambia. The actors were identified after a thorough review of program evaluation reports on mechanization availed to the author by the Zambia National Farmers’ Union (ZNFU). 167 4.3.3. Data analysis The quantitative methods used to analyze the data assembled included descriptive and regression analysis using Stata 14 software. Analysis of the secondary data accounted for the survey design by using the svy command available in Stata. Details of all the quantitative analysis are presented separately by each research question. The qualitative data analysis methods employed in the study are collectively described at the end of the section. 4.3.3.1. services RQ1: Quantitative analysis of trends in mechanization use and tractor hiring In order to quantitatively explore the trends in agricultural mechanization use and tractor hiring services in Zambia and how they have evolved in recent years, the study analyzed both secondary and primary sources of survey data available. Specifically, the following analyses were conducted: (1) a comparison of the proportion of small- and medium-scale farming households using mechanization for land preparation by province over a three-year period; (2) a cross sectional comparison of the proportion of medium-scale farming households using mechanization for agricultural land preparation in selected districts; (3) estimation of the number of tractors available per thousand hectares cultivated in Zambia; (4) a comparison of the demographic and agricultural production characteristics of households using mechanization versus non-users over a three year period, and; (5) a characterization of tractor hiring services access and provision among medium-scale farming households in selected districts of Zambia. 4.3.3.2. production RQ2: Quantitative analysis of effects of mechanization on household level To analyze the contemporaneous effects of mechanization on area cultivated and net value of crop production per hectare (a measure of crop productivity), this research used and extended the analytical framework adapted by Houssou & Chapoto (2014). Their study assessed 168 the impacts of agricultural mechanization on cropland expansion and farm input intensification in Northern Ghana. To make the assessment, the aforementioned study recognized that agricultural mechanization is driven by various factors and that it requires a comprehensive framework to understand the ways through which these factors interact. The factors broadly include agricultural policies, the market environment, farming systems and farmers’ own behavioral strategies. In this study, a similar approach was used to assess the effects of mechanization on area cultivated in Zambia and extended the analysis by assessing the effects of mechanization on crop productivity. The study only assessed contemporaneous effects using a cross sectional dataset— ACS (2013). The empirical procedure used in this study was an endogenous switching regression model (Maddala, 1983). The model accounts for potential challenges—endogeneity and sample selection—that may arise in assessing the effects of a technology such as tractor use on area cultivated and net value of crop production per hectare cultivated. To illustrate these challenges, I begin by stating the underlying relationship of interest. Suppose the following regression is estimated at household level: (1) 𝑦 = 𝑋 ′ 𝛽 + 𝛿𝐼 + 𝑢 where 𝑦 represents an outcome variable of interest such as area cultivated or net value of crop production per hectare, 𝑋 is a vector of exogenous characteristics, 𝐼 is a dummy variable defined as 𝐼 = 1 if the household used a tractor for land preparation and 0 otherwise, and 𝑢 is the error term. In this study, area cultivated is defined as the total number of hectares prepared by the farmer for crop production. Net value of crop production per hectare cultivated is the monetary value of crop production net of variable input costs divided by the number of hectares cultivated. 169 The regression model outlined above assumes that 𝐼 is uncorrelated with the error term (exogeneity condition). This approach might lead to biased parameter estimates (𝛽, 𝛿) because of this strong exogeneity assumption. In reality, some unobserved characteristics that influence the probability that a farmer decides to use a tractor for land preparation could also influence the other outcome variables of interest. The endogenous switching regression model is designed to circumvent these challenges. The model consists of two parts. The first part is a selection equation, which models the decision to use or not to use tractors for land preparation using a standard limited dependent variable method. The second part presents the production outcome equations estimated for each group (users and non-users of tractors). Thus, the model is specified as follows: 1⁡⁡⁡⁡⁡𝑖𝑓⁡⁡⁡⁡𝐼𝑖∗ > 0 0⁡⁡⁡⁡⁡𝑖𝑓⁡⁡⁡⁡𝐼𝑖∗ ≤ 0 (2.1) Selection equation 𝐼𝑖∗ = 𝑍𝑖 𝛾⁡ + ⁡ 𝜀𝑖 , 𝐼𝑖 = { (2.2) Regime 1 (users) 𝑦1𝑖 = 𝑋1𝑖 𝛽1 ⁡ + ⁡ 𝑢1𝑖 ⁡𝑖𝑓⁡𝐼𝑖 = 1 (2.3) Regime 2 (non-users) 𝑦2𝑖 = 𝑋2𝑖 𝛽2 ⁡ + ⁡ 𝑢2𝑖 ⁡𝑖𝑓⁡𝐼𝑖 = 0 where, in the selection equation, 𝐼 ∗ is a latent variable for choice of land preparation technology, 𝐼 is what is observed (𝐼 = 1 if the household used tractor for land preparation and 0 otherwise), 𝑍 is a vector of observed farm and non-farm characteristics determining the decision to use or not to use tractors for land preparation, and 𝑢 is the error term. For the second part, 𝑦 represents the two outcome variables (area cultivated and net value of crop production per hectare cultivated), 𝑋 is a vector of variables that capture household characteristics, market environment, district fixed effects and the agricultural policy environment. 170 Based on Lokshin & Sajaia (2004), this study implements the full information maximum likelihood method (FIML) to simultaneously estimate the selection equation and the two regime equations outlined above. This is done to correct the inefficiencies inherent in other estimation methods like the two-step least square or maximum likelihood estimation. The FIML yields consistent standard errors. The empirical strategy for modeling the effect of mechanization on the two outcome variables of interest proceeded as follows. First, in order to identify the model, a test for exclusion restrictions was conducted; isolating variables that go into the selection equation but are excluded from the outcome equations. Based on Di Falco, Veronesi, & Yesuf (2011), the test for exclusion restrictions involved running a probit model for the whole sample on variables conjectured to determine whether or not a household uses mechanization for land preparation. Next, an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression was estimated for each outcome variable (area cultivated and net value of crop production per hectare cultivated) where the right hand side variables only included the significant variables from the probit model estimated earlier. The OLS was only estimated for sample households that did not use mechanization. The variables that were not statistically significant in the second stage (OLS) constituted the possible candidates for the exclusion restrictions. The second step of the empirical strategy involved estimating the endogenous switching regression model using the movestay command in Stata 14. We also did counterfactual analysis by comparing the expected values for the two outcome variables under the actual and counterfactual cases that farmers used or did not use mechanization for land preparation (ibid). Further, treatment and heterogeneity effects were computed to understand the differences in area cultivated and net value of crop production per hectare between farm households that were users 171 and those that were non-users of mechanization. The counterfactual and treatment effects analysis relied on post-estimation procedures available in Stata. We provide a detailed description of this analysis when presenting our findings. 4.3.3.3. RQ3: Quantitative analysis of the rise of agricultural mechanization services Although the induced innovation hypothesis may not be a perfect fit, this paper relied on this widely used concept of technical change in development economics to explain recent developments related to agricultural mechanization in Zambia. Formalized by Hayami & Ruttan (1970, 1985), the hypothesis explains that development and adoption of technology to save an input, is induced by the input’s relatively higher price. Put another way, the hypothesis posits that “alternative agricultural technologies are developed to facilitate the substitution of relatively abundant (hence, cheap) factors for relatively scarce (hence, expensive) factors” (Ruttan, 2002, p. 163). Hayami & Ruttan (1985) illustrate the process of induced technical change in Japan and the United States using historical data (1880-1980) of the following variables: price of fertilizer, price of land, amount of fertilizer applied per hectare of land, price of draft power, price of labor and the amount of draft power per worker. For both countries, the price of fertilizer declined relative to the price of land and the price of draft power declined relative to the price of labor. As a consequence, fertilizer use per hectare and power per worker rose in both countries. Based on this illustration, fertilizer would be regarded as “land saving” because increased fertilizer use substitutes for land, while draft power or mechanization is “labor saving” because it substitutes power and machinery for labor (Binswanger, 1978a; Ruttan, 2002). Binswanger (1978b) demonstrated that a shift to tractor use could only be economically induced under rapidly rising prices of factors of production that tractors have the potential to 172 replace—labor or animal draft power. A more recent application of the induced innovation hypothesis is by Diao et al. (2014) who assessed the rise of mechanization services in Ghana. Their study found that rising wage rate and increased opportunities for rural workers in nonfarm sectors has induced the demand for labor-saving technology and demand for certain mechanized farming operations, particularly plowing, has emerged even among small-scale farmers. Equipped with the induced innovation hypothesis, the current study assessed the changes in two factor prices—agricultural wage labor and rental prices for mechanization—in Zambia and whether or not these changes were likely to induce a shift to labor-saving technologies. Using the CFS data (2012 – 2015), the following steps were followed to estimate the factor price ratios. First, median mechanization rental rates and agricultural wage rates were computed by province and agricultural activities (for example, land preparation, planting, harvesting). Only the factor prices for land preparation were used for subsequent analysis because they directly reflect tractor use, the focus of this study. Second, the factor prices were adjusted for inflation using available CPI indices. Third, factor price ratios were generated for each year by province by dividing the median rental rate of mechanization by the median agricultural wage rate. Graphs were generated to further interpret the findings. 4.3.3.4. Qualitative data analysis The data collected using key informant and case study interviews were used to gain further insights for this research. Transcripts were developed for each of the interviews captured through either audio recordings or handwritten notes. Based on grounded theory approach (Strauss & Corbin, 1994), the study used an iterative process to develop a coding scheme in NVivo 10 software. The coding scheme specified the concepts and themes, their definition and the rules for applying the codes. The codes developed enabled the researcher to easily retrieve 173 similar information across individual transcripts. Summary statements were written to represent the diversity of responses and where possible, quotes from the respondents were used to clearly represent their perspectives. 4.4. Results and discussion 4.4.1. Trends in agricultural mechanization use and tractor hiring services The following analyses were conducted to help with understanding the trends in agricultural mechanization use and tractor hiring services in Zambia. First, a comparison of the proportions of small- and medium-scale farming households using mechanization for land preparation was done by province over a three-year period to give both a spatial and overall picture. Second, the study also compared the proportions of medium-scale farming households using mechanization for agricultural land preparation by selected districts in Zambia. Third, the study estimated the number of tractors available per thousand hectares cultivated in Zambia. Fourth, the study compared demographic and agricultural production characteristics of households using mechanization versus non-users over a three-year period. Fifth, this research also characterized access to and provision of tractor-hiring services by medium-scale farming households in selected districts of Zambia. The results are presented and interpreted in turn. 4.4.1.1. Mechanization use of small- and medium-scale farmers by province Figure 11 presents results for the proportions of small- and medium-scale farming households that used mechanization for agricultural land preparation by province between 2012 and 2015. First and foremost, these results clearly show that agricultural mechanization use among small- and medium-scale farmers has remained low in Zambia. The aggregate proportion of farming households using mechanization for land preparation stood at 1.5 percent in 2012 and marginally increased to 1.6 percent in 2015. Second, except for Western province, the other 174 provinces where the proportion of farming households using agricultural mechanization was close to or above the national average of 1.5 percent were provinces—Central, Copperbelt and Lusaka—located along Zambia’s ‘line of rail’. This finding only goes to confirm that development of mechanization has primarily happened in parts of the country where there is better infrastructure and modest availability of agricultural support services. 10.0% 9.0% 8.0% 7.0% 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 3.3% 3.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.7% 1.2% 1.0% 0.4% 0.3% 0.6% 0.4% 1.6% 0.9% 0.0% 0.0% % using mechanization for land preparation (2012) % using mechanization for land preparation (2015) Figure 11: Proportion of small- and medium-scale farming households using mechanization for agricultural land preparation by province between 2012 and 2015 Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012, 2015) 4.4.1.2. Mechanization use of medium-scale farmers by selected districts Reported in Figure 12, we make a cross sectional comparison of the proportion of medium-scale farming households that used mechanization for agricultural land preparation by selected districts. The aggregate proportion of medium-scale farm households using mechanization was above eight percent. This is above the 1.5 percent and 1.6 percent national 175 average reported among small- and medium-scale farms in 2012 and 2015 respectively. This result suggests that medium-scale farms (specifically those located in the selected districts) were more likely to use mechanization for land preparation relative to both small- and medium-scale farms at national level. Further, the highest proportion of mechanization users was reported in two districts located in Central and Copperbelt provinces; Mumbwa and Mpongwe where about 11 percent and approximately 14 percent respectively of medium-scale households stated that they used mechanization for land preparation. Nevertheless, these numbers still fall short of levels of mechanization reported in other parts of SSA such as Ghana where farm power use rates in some regions of the country have been reported to be above 90 percent of farming households (Houssou & Chapoto, 2014). 20.0% 18.0% 16.0% 13.7% 14.0% 11.3% 12.0% 10.0% 8.3% 8.2% 8.0% 6.0% 4.0% 3.7% 2.6% 2.4% 2.0% 0.0% Chibombo Mumbwa Mpongwe Chongwe Choma Kalomo Aggregate % using mechanization for land preparation (2013) Figure 12: Proportion of medium-scale farming households using mechanization for agricultural land preparation by selected districts Source: Author’s computation from ACS (2013) 176 4.4.1.3. Tractor use per area cultivated in Zambia The study also assessed the level of tractor use relative to the area cultivated in Zambia. Table 23 below shows the number of tractors per one thousand hectares cultivated in Zambia based on the RALS (2012 and 2015). To compute this statistic, the analysis relied on available sampling weights in the two secondary datasets that made it possible to estimate the national level number of tractors available for use, the number of hectares cultivated and thereafter compute the number of tractors per one thousand hectares cultivated. Results show that tractor use in Zambia over the three-year period remained relatively the same; about 1.3 and 1.2 tractors per one thousand hectares cultivated in 2012 and 2015 respectively. This finding is consistent with estimates presented by Pingali (2007) that indicate that tractor use in SSA was around 1.3 tractors per one thousand hectares cultivated in 2002. In the same period, however, the number of tractors per one thousand hectares was around 9.1 in South Asia and 10.4 in Latin America (ibid). Findings from the current study imply that tractor use per area cultivated in Zambia has remained stagnant when compared to other developing regions of the world. However, we recognize that these differences in tractor use per one thousand hectares have to be interpreted cautiously since this outcome might be a function of social, economic and environmental conditions (conditions not controlled for in this analysis) that are regional specific. Table 23: Tractor use per thousand hectares cultivated in Zambia Year 2012 Total number of tractors (weighted) Total number of hectares cultivated (weighted) Tractor use/1000 hectares cultivated Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012, 2015) 177 2,990 2,282,021 1.3 2015 3,612 3,079,826 1.2 4.4.1.4. Demographic and production characteristics of users versus non-users of mechanization Table 24 presents difference in means comparisons of demographic and agricultural production characteristics of users versus non-users of mechanization for land preparation in 2012 and 2015. The table clearly shows that the number of users of mechanization in both years was significantly lower relative to non-users. Only 134 out of 8839 households (1.5 percent) and 122 out of 7747 households (1.6 percent) interviewed in 2012 and 2015 respectively, used mechanization for agricultural production. The key findings worth noting from these results are the following. First, farmers who used mechanization were more likely to be older than those who did not and this was evident across both years. In 2012, for example, the average age of household heads who used mechanization was 50 years while those who did not was 45 years and the result was significant at one percent level. This finding could be attributed to the fact that older farmers have accumulated enough experience and enhanced their status in order to adopt use of mechanization for land preparation. Second, the results show that the level of education of the household head is positively related with use of mechanization both in 2012 and 2015. This result is not surprising. This indicates that households with better education were able to easily access and understand information that pertains to the relative benefits of mechanization. Third, households that used mechanization for land preparation had a higher likelihood of having a member earning income from wages than those who did not use mechanization. For instance, in 2015, about 44 percent of mechanization using households had someone who earned income from wages while only 29 percent of those not using mechanization had such income sources. The interpretation of this result is that wage income probably helped farmers enhance their ability to pay for the cost of either hiring tractor services or acquiring their own equipment for use on the farm. 178 Table 24: Comparison of demographic and agricultural production characteristics of households using mechanization versus non-users over a three-year period Variable 2012 2015 Users Nont-test Users Nont-test users users Number of observations 134 8705 *** 122 7626 *** Age of household head (years) 50.3 45.4 *** 51.9 48.6 ** Male headed households (% yes) 85.1 80.7 82.8 78.7 Education of head (years) 9.4 6.1 *** 8.6 5.9 *** Household size (count) 6.5 5.8 *** 6.6 6.2 Did the household earn income 53.7 45.9 * 54.9 48.2 from business activities? (% yes) Did the household earn income 44.0 20.6 *** 44.3 28.8 *** from wages? (% yes) Did the household also use 15.7 38.3 *** 27.0 41.2 *** animal draft power for land preparation? (% yes) Did the household also use 25.4 67.6 *** 38.5 67.7 *** manual labor for land preparation? (% yes) Did the household use its own 33.6 0 *** 33.6 0 *** tractor for land preparation (% yes) Did the household use tractor 64.4 0 *** 67.2 0 *** hiring services for land preparation (% yes) Area cultivated (hectares) 3.0 2.3 *** 3.7 2.4 *** Source: Author’s computation from RALS (2012, 2015) Significance levels for t-test are as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Fourth, the average area cultivated by users of mechanization was significantly higher than that cultivated by non-users in 2012 and 2015. In 2012, the average area cultivated by users of mechanization was 3 hectares while the area cultivated by non-users was 2.3 hectares. The average area cultivated by both users and non-users of mechanization increased slightly in 2015 with the former cultivating 3.7 hectares and the latter 2.4 hectares. Although the average area cultivated by those using mechanization does not seem to be much higher than those not using mechanization in absolute terms, this finding is the first indication of the likely positive effects of 179 mechanization on area cultivated. This essay returns to this discussion when presenting the econometric results in section 4.4.2. 4.4.1.5. Access to and provision of tractor hiring services in selected districts Both rounds of the RALS (2012 and 2015) did not go into the details of tractor-hiring services available in the respective communities surveyed across the whole of Zambia. The ACS, on the other hand, had a specific module that asked respondents questions that included information about the household’s proximity to tractor-hiring services, whether the household used nearby tractor-hiring services, and whether the household provided tractor-hiring services in case of those who owned tractors. Table 25 presents information about access to and provision of tractor-hiring services by medium-scale farming households in six selected districts of Zambia. Except for Choma where less than 40 percent of the respondents indicated that they had tractor-hiring services within or nearby their villages, more than 50 percent of the respondents in each of the other five districts indicated that they had such services nearby. This result generally suggests that access to tractor-hiring services was relatively good and in close proximity to farmers to use conditional on their ability to pay for the service. 180 Table 25: Access to and provision of tractor hiring services among medium-scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia Variable District Chibombo Choma Chongwe Kalomo Mpongwe Tractor hiring services nearby? (% yes) 61.1 37.7 64.3 61.5 51.5 Proportion of households with nearby tractor hiring services 7.6 40.9 3.7 4.2 20 using the services? (% yes) Distance to the nearest tractor hiring service (km) 5.6 10.3 6.3 5.8 5.1 Owned tractor in the past that is no longer used? (% yes) 3.7 4.9 2.4 5.1 11.1 How was this tractor that is no longer used acquired? Inheritance (%) 25.0 33.3 100 0 23.1 Purchased using income from sales of own farm 75.0 0 0 50 61.5 produce (%) Purchased using income from off-farm sources (%) 0 33.3 0 50 15.4 Purchased using a loan obtained through a bank (%) 0 33.3 0 0 0 Own tractor that that is currently used? (% yes) 1.0 3.3 0 2.5 16.2 How was this tractor that is currently used acquired? Inheritance (%) 0 0 0 0 0 Purchased using income from sales of own farm 0 50 0 1 94.7 produce (%) Purchased using income from off-farm sources (%) 0 0 0 0 5.3 Purchased using a loan obtained through a bank (%) 100 50 0 0 0 If you own a tractor, do you hire it out? (% yes) 100 50 0 0 42.1 Number of observations 108 61 42 39 117 Source: Author’s computation from ACS (2013) 181 Mumbwa 69.6 30 8.6 15.7 22.2 72.2 5.6 0 5.3 14.3 85.7 0 0 66.7 115 From the perspective of most respondents interviewed during the qualitative field research, the consensus was that the steady increase in the number of actors providing mechanization services since 2011 had played a critical in improving availability of and access to mechanization for farmers. They gave examples of mechanization service providers available in their communities. One of the community leaders explained it this way: “[access to mechanization] is on the rise. For example, the ZNFU have started a credit facility where they give tractors to emergent farmers. The program is working very well.” However, what clearly came out of the interviews especially with the farmer respondents was that use of mechanization services was still very low despite improved availability and access. This observation was also confirmed by the quantitative analysis reported in Table 24. Three of the six survey districts reported that less than 10 percent of medium-scale farming households who said they lived within or nearby tractor-hiring services actually used these services. On further inquiry of why the majority of respondents did not use available tractor hiring services, the main reason given during the in-depth interviews was that tractor-hiring services were very expensive. One farmer explained, “Tractor hiring is expensive ….. oxen are readily available in the area and cheaper than tractor.” In other cases, the respondents stated that the time they had to wait in order to be serviced by available providers jeopardized their chances of planting on time given the rain fed nature of agriculture production in Zambia. Therefore, most decided not to use available tractor-hiring services for fear of losing out on doing other subsequent farming activities on time. With the exception of Mumbwa district where about 16 percent of sampled households stated that they owned a tractor that they currently used, less than 5 percent did so in the other five districts. On the other hand, hiring out of own tractors did not follow a similar pattern. In 182 some districts, a large proportion of tractor owners hired out their tractors while in others, very few to none hired out tractors. The study further asked those who did not hire out to explain why they did not do so. The main explanations given had to do with past experiences of tractors breaking down when hired out or that the tractors were not in very good condition to be hired out. 4.4.2. Effects of mechanization on area cultivated and net value of crop production Before presenting the results for the econometric model used to estimate the effects of mechanization on the two outcome variables, the explanatory and dependent variables used are briefly highlighted. Table 26 presents the comparison of means between users and non-users of mechanization among medium-scale farmers in selected districts of Zambia. The results show that when users of mechanization are compared with non-users, they were statistically more likely to have: (1) a higher level of education; (2) a member earning wage income; (3) owned a tractor in the past that they no longer use; (4) title to their land; (5) hired labor for agricultural production; (6) relied less on animal draft power for land preparation; (7) more land; (8) more area under cultivation, and; (9) a higher net value of crop production per hectare. 183 Table 26: Comparison of means between users and non-users of mechanization among mediumscale farmers in selected districts of Zambia Variable Means Users Non-users t-test Age of household head (years) 51.0 50.0 Male headed households (% yes) 86.4 91.8 Education of head (years) 10.5 8.5 *** Number of years settled in the area 32.8 33.2 Household earned income from business activities? 63.6 58.4 (% yes) Household earned income from wages? (% yes) 43.9 33.7 * Household owned tractor in the past that it no longer 22.7 6.3 *** uses? (% yes) Household has title to land? (% yes) 30.3 12.2 *** Household used hired labor for agricultural 86.4 60.6 *** production? (% yes) Household used animal draft power for land 39.4 96.1 *** preparation? (% yes) Proportion of area planted to maize1 (%) 75.8 73.9 Proportion of area planted to beans and oilseeds2 (%) 12.2 13.5 Proportion of area planted to other cereals3 (%) 0.2 0.7 4 Proportion of area planted to traditional cash crops 11.0 10.6 (%) Proportion of area planted to roots and tubers5 (%) 0.8 1.3 Total landholding size (hectares) 92.1 32.6 *** Area cultivated (hectares) 16.9 9.1 *** Net value of crop production per hectare cultivated 1568.5 695.2 *** (Kwacha/hectare) Number of observations 66 416 Source: Author’s computation from ACS (2013) Significance levels for t-test are as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Notes: Crop category/categories: 1 = Maize; 2=beans and oilseeds (groundnuts, soya beans, mixed beans, Bambara nuts, cowpeas and velvet beans); 3=other cereal grains (sorghum, rice, millet, popcorn); 4= traditional cash crops (seed cotton, tobacco, coffee and sugarcane); 5=roots and tubers (sweet potatoes, potatoes and cassava). 4.4.2.1. Effects of mechanization on area cultivated Table 27 reports the full information maximum likelihood estimates of the endogenous switching regression for area cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users. The selection equation column reports the estimated coefficients on variables that determine the household’s decision to use or not to use mechanization. The column for the outcome variable, 184 area cultivated, presents estimated coefficients on variables conjectured to influence the level of area cultivated conditional on whether or not the farmer used mechanization or not. Moreover, the dependent variable underwent logarithmic transformation while all the explanatory variables were in levels. The main interest of this study was to estimate the effect of mechanization on area cultivated. For brevity, we do not focus on explaining the ceteris paribus relationships reported in Table 27 but on the expected value estimates reported in Table 28 as these help to show the effects of mechanization on area cultivated. Table 28 presents the expected log of area cultivated in hectares for users versus non-users of mechanization under the actual and counterfactual conditions. The values of expected log of area cultivated observed in the sample for mechanization users and non-users are represented by cells (a) and (b) respectively. Cell (c) represents the area that users of mechanization would cultivate if they did not use mechanization while and cell (d) represents the expected log of area cultivated for non-users if they had decided to use mechanization. 185 Table 27: Full information maximum likelihood estimates of the endogenous switching regression for area cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users Explanatory variables Selection equation Users Non-users Dep. Var: 1 = used Dep. Var: Log of hectares mechanization; 0 = cultivated otherwise Age of household head -0.017 0.012 -0.004 (-1.59) (0.64) (-0.90) Male head (1=yes) -0.029 0.261 0.827*** (-0.08) (0.48) (4.12) Years in formal education of the 0.022 -0.039 -0.002 household head (0.73) (-0.89) (-0.11) Formal employment (1=yes) 0.089 0.179 -0.107 (0.38) (0.45) (-0.86) Involved in business activity -0.105 0.045 0.212* (1=yes) (-0.50) (0.14) (1.88) * *** Total landholding (hectares) 0.002 0.005 0.007*** (1.79) (3.06) (5.81) Owned tractor before that is no -0.064 0.232 0.378 longer used (-0.19) (0.59) (1.64) Has title deed (1=yes) 0.559* 0.269 -0.240 (1.65) (0.62) (-1.23) *** Hired labor for agricultural 0.745 0.701 0.294** production (1=yes) (2.86) (1.42) (2.48) Annual expected rainfall -0.005 0.005 -0.011** (millimeters) (-0.72) (0.49) (-2.54) Maize area (%) 0.000 0.036 0.006 (0.01) (0.60) (0.62) Beans and oilseeds area (%) -0.006 0.044 0.006 (-0.29) (0.73) (0.62) Other cereals area (%) -0.027 -0.024 0.027* (-0.78) (-0.22) (1.73) Traditional cash crops area (%) 0.006 0.042 0.008 (0.26) (0.70) (0.76) Cost of land preparation per hectare 0.107*** 0.030 0.081*** using animal draft power (ZMW/ha) (3.12) (0.61) (5.15) 186 Table 27 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Cost of land preparation per hectare using mechanical draft power (ZMW/ha) Years in current settlement Animal draft power (1=yes) District fixed effects Constant Selection equation Dep. Var: 1 = used mechanization; 0 = otherwise -0.057*** Users Dep. Var: Log of hectares cultivated Non-users -0.014 -0.046*** (-2.92) 0.012* (1.85) -2.373*** (-8.41) Yes 0.326 (0.07) (-0.48) (-5.51) Yes -6.139 (-0.75) 0.119 -0.140 66 Yes 8.077*** (2.69) 0.067* -0.569* 416 Sigma Rho N Source: Author’s computation from ACS (2013) Note: (1) Wald test of independence of equations: Chi2(19) = 34.64 Prob > chi2 = 0.0154 (2) t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Table 28: Expected log of hectares cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users Decision stage To use Not to use Mean difference mechanization mechanization (within) Users of (a) 4.47 (c) 3.60 (TT) 0.87*** mechanization Non-users of (d) 3.74 (b) 3.47 (TU) 0.27*** mechanization Mean difference (BH1) 0.73 (BH2) 0.13 (TH) 0.60 (across) Notes: Significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. TT: the effect of the treatment (i.e., use of mechanization) on the treated (i.e., farm households that used mechanization); TU: the effect of the treatment (i.e., use of mechanization) on the untreated (i.e., farm households that did not use mechanization); BHi : the effect of base heterogeneity for farm households that used mechanization (i =1), and did not use mechanization (i =2); TH = (TT TU), i.e., transitional heterogeneity. 187 A typical way of assessing effects of an intervention is to compare the outcome variable for the actual cases, in this case cell (a) for the adopters and cell (b) for the non-adopters. However, such a simple comparison could lead to overestimating the effects of an intervention. Here, it suggests that the area cultivated by farmers using mechanization was 100 percent more than that for non-users (cell (a) – cell (b)).9 A better approach is to use the mean differences (treatment effects) reported in the last column of Table 28. Suppose users of mechanization decided not to use mechanization, they would have cultivated about 87 percent less area (TT = (c) - (a)). On the other hand, if farmers that did not use mechanization decided to use mechanization, mechanization would have had a positive effect of 27 percent increase in area cultivated (TU = (d) - (b)). These results imply that use of mechanization significantly increases area cultivated by farmers. In addition, the transitional heterogeneity effect is positive (60 percent difference), that is, the effect of mechanization on area cultivated is significantly higher for those who used mechanization relative to those that did not use it. One important issue that a researcher needs to account for is the potential for heterogeneity that makes those farmers using mechanization cultivate larger areas compared to those not using, irrespective of the availability of mechanization. The results show that households that used mechanization would significantly increase area cultivated by 73 percent (BH1 = (a) – (d)) relative to non-users had they (non-users) used mechanization. Moreover, had the users decided not to use mechanization, they would still cultivate more area (about 13 percent difference) relative to non-users. These results (BH1 and BH2) suggest existence of unobserved heterogeneity; there are other unaccounted for factors that make users of mechanization more likely to cultivate larger areas. 9 Since the expected values are in logs, the difference between two values can be interpreted as percentage differences. 188 4.4.2.2. Effect of mechanization on net value of crop production per hectare Table 29 reports the full information maximum likelihood estimates of the endogenous switching regression for net value of crop production per hectare of users of mechanization versus non-users. The selection equation column reports the estimated coefficients on variables that determine the household’s decision to use or not to use mechanization. The column for the outcome variable, net value of crop production per hectare, presents estimated coefficients on variables conjectured to influence the level of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated conditional on whether or not the farmer used mechanization or not. The dependent variable underwent logarithmic transformation while all the explanatory variables were in levels. Similar to the previous estimation of the effects of mechanization on area cultivated, the focus of discussion in this section is on the expected value estimates. Table 30 presents the expected log of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated for users versus non-users of mechanization under the actual and counterfactual conditions. The values of expected log of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated observed in the sample for mechanization users and non-users are represented by cells (a) and (b) respectively. Cell (c) represents the net value of crop production per hectare cultivated that users of mechanization would realize if they did not use mechanization while and cell (d) represents the expected log of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated for non-users if they had decided to use mechanization. 189 Table 29: Full information maximum likelihood estimates of the endogenous switching regression for net value of crop production per hectare of users of mechanization versus nonusers Explanatory variables Selection equation Users Non-users Dep. Var: 1 = used Dep. Var: Log of net value of crop mechanization; 0 = production per hectare cultivated otherwise Age of household head -0.017 -0.011 -0.002 (-1.52) (-0.43) (-0.18) Male head (1=yes) -0.232 0.294 0.305 (-0.67) (0.41) (0.74) Years in formal education of the 0.030 0.032 -0.034 household head (0.94) (0.54) (-1.00) Formal employment (1=yes) 0.086 -1.422*** -0.020 (0.36) (-2.70) (-0.08) Involved in business activity -0.081 0.197 -0.019 (1=yes) (-0.38) (0.45) (-0.08) Total landholding (hectares) 0.003** -0.002 0.000 (2.08) (-1.07) (0.19) Owned tractor before that is no -0.083 -0.593 0.234 longer used (-0.25) (-1.11) (0.49) Has title deed (1=yes) 0.367 -0.474 0.418 (1.15) (-0.83) (1.02) Hired labor for agricultural 0.816*** -0.493 0.530** production (1=yes) (2.96) (-0.72) (2.18) Annual expected rainfall -0.004 0.009 -0.007 (millimeters) (-0.54) (0.75) (-0.77) Maize area (%) -0.003 0.144* 0.020 (-0.13) (1.77) (1.02) Beans and oilseeds area (%) -0.007 0.145* 0.005 (-0.32) (1.79) (0.23) Other cereals area (%) -0.043 0.110 -0.009 (-1.19) (0.78) (-0.29) Traditional cash crops area (%) 0.001 0.112 -0.017 (0.04) (1.39) (-0.79) Years in current settlement 0.011* (1.70) Animal draft power (1=yes) -2.369*** (-8.17) 190 Table 29 (Cont’d) Explanatory variables Cost of land preparation per hectare using animal draft power (ZMW/ha) Cost of land preparation per hectare using mechanical power (ZMW/ha) District fixed effects Constant Selection equation Dep. Var: 1 = used mechanization; 0 = otherwise Non-users 0.109*** Users Dep. Var: Log of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated -0.122* (3.04) -0.058*** (-1.87) 0.061 (-1.46) 0.031* (-2.84) Yes -0.377 (-0.07) (1.60) Yes -1.488 (-0.14) 0.405*** -0.148 66 (1.82) Yes 16.871*** (2.69) 0.795*** -0.200 416 -0.047 Sigma Rho N Source: Author’s computation from ACS (2013) Note: (1) Wald test of independence of equations: Chi2(19) = 64.92 Prob > Chi2 = 0.000 (2) t statistics in parentheses, significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 Table 30: Expected log of net value of crop production per hectare cultivated of users of mechanization versus non-users Decision stage Used mechanization Did not use Mean difference mechanization (within) Users of (a) 13.50 (c) 12.28 (TT) 1.22*** mechanization Non-users of (d) 14.51 (b) 12.47 (TU) 2.04*** mechanization Mean difference (BH1) -1.01 (BH1) -0.19 (TH) -0.82 (across) Notes: Significance levels as follows: * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. TT: the effect of the treatment (i.e., use of mechanization) on the treated (i.e., farm households that used mechanization); TU: the effect of the treatment (i.e., use of mechanization) on the untreated (i.e., farm households that did not use mechanization); BHi : the effect of base heterogeneity for farm households that used mechanization (i =1), and did not use mechanization (i =2); TH = (TT TU), i.e., transitional heterogeneity. 191 The last column of Table 30 presents the mean difference or treatment effects within each category of users or non-users of mechanization. Suppose users of mechanization decided not to use mechanization, they would have realized about 122 percent less of the net value of crop production per hectare cultivated ((c) – (a)). On the other hand, if farmers that did not use mechanization decided to use mechanization, their net value of crop production per hectare would have increased by 204 percent ((d) – (b)). As a consequence, the transitional heterogeneity effect is negative (82 percent difference). This implies that the effect of mechanization on net value of crop production per hectare is significantly lower for those who used mechanization relative to those that did not use it. The last row of Table 30 shows results after adjusting for potential heterogeneity in the sample. We observe that households that used mechanization would realize a lower net value of crop production per hectare (101 percent less) relative to non-users had they (non-users) used mechanization. Moreover, had the users decided not to use mechanization, they would realize a lower net value of crop production per hectare (19 percent difference) relative to non-users. These results suggest existence of unobserved heterogeneity; there are other unaccounted for factors that make non-users of mechanization more likely to enjoy net productivity gains. Overall, our findings point to what has been observed in the literature that mechanization on its own does not have an unequivocal positive yield effect. There are other important factors that are clearly linked with productivity enhancement such as use of improved seed, soil nutrient improvement and others. 4.4.3. Explaining the rise of agricultural mechanization services in Zambia Results for the third research question are presented in two sections. The first section highlights the changes in factor price ratios and shows whether these changes could have 192 potentially induced a shift from labor-using to labor-saving technologies. The second section reports key insights from actors involved in promoting mechanization initiatives and questions the extent to which the supply side has played a pivotal role in the rise of these initiatives. The findings are discussed in turn. 4.4.3.1. Factor price ratios: are they changing enough to induce demand for mechanization? The current drive to mechanize has mainly been targeted towards farmers in three provinces—Central, Eastern and Southern. Thus, this study only reported the changes in factor price ratios of mechanization rental rates and agricultural wage rates for land preparation over a four-year period (2012 – 2015) in the three provinces. Figure 13 illustrates the changes in factor price ratios (adjusted for inflation) computed by dividing median mechanization rental rates by median agricultural wage rates. Each line represents changes in factor price ratios for each of the three provinces. A monotonic downward sloping curve implies that the cost of labor is increasing by a greater margin relative to mechanization rental rates. This would in turn favor a shift to labor saving technologies such as tractor use. The opposite scenario is also true that a monotonic upward sloping curve implies that the cost of renting mechanization is increasing by a greater margin relative to labor costs. This would maintain the status quo of labor using technologies such as hand tools. According to Figure 13, the following findings emerged. First, factor price ratios in the three provinces did not remain the same over the four-year period. Second, Central province experienced a monotonic downward sloping trend in factor price ratios suggesting that this could have induced demand for mechanization in the province. Third, Southern province saw a marginal increase in the mechanization/labor factor price ratio in the earlier years (2012 – 2013), 193 which would have made mechanization less attractive. However, from 2013 to 2015, the province experienced a downward trend in factor price ratios, which could have induced demand for mechanization. Fourth, Eastern province had price ratios favorable to mechanization from 2012 to 2014 but conditions changed in favor of labor using technologies from 2014 to 2015. In sum, these results suggest that there have been changes in mechanization/labor factor price ratios that may have worked in favor of a shift to labor saving technologies especially in the case of Central and Southern provinces. However, one needs to be cautious when interpreting these results because most small- and medium-scale farming households rely on family labor and less on hired labor. And since it is difficult to account for the opportunity cost of family labor, it is unclear whether the computed changes in factor price ratios would bring about an unequivocal Mechanization rental rate/agricultural wage rate (inflation adjusted) shift to mechanization. 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 2012 2013 2014 2015 YEAR Central Eastern Southern Figure 13: Changes in factor price ratios for mechanization and agricultural labor (adjusted for inflation) by selected provinces in Zambia Source: Author’s computation from CFS (2012 - 2015) 194 4.4.3.2. Insights from supply side actors and their role in the rise in mechanization The study interviewed six key actors involved in mechanization service provision identified through interaction with agricultural industry actors in Zambia and available evaluation reports availed to the researcher. Three thematic areas were covered during each of these interviews: (1) drivers of current mechanization initiatives; (2) performance of these initiatives, and; (3) constraints likely to affect sustainability of these initiatives. The key issues arising from the interviews are discussed by theme in turn. 4.4.3.2.1. Drivers of current mechanization initiatives There was general consensus among the respondents that development works in trends. One key concept that has been embraced by the private sector, development agencies, equipment suppliers and financial lending institutions is the shared value initiative. They have adapted this initiative from Porter & Kramer (2011) who define it as “policies and operating practices that enhance the competitiveness of a company while simultaneously advancing the economic and social conditions in the communities in which it operates.” These actors have recognized that in order for them to generate gains from working with farmers, they need to be involved in promoting technologies that enhance farmer productivity (a win-win situation). One of the respondents (representing a cotton agribusiness) indicated that their motivation for getting into mechanization stems from the fact that alternative methods (hand tools and animal draft power) introduce inefficiencies: late completion of tasks and high labor costs. With increased mechanization targeted towards their farmers, the company envisaged that this would circumvent the aforementioned inefficiencies, increase farmer productivity and hence increase the company’s profitability. 195 Another important factor that was mentioned by two of the respondents was that smalland medium-scale farmers in parts of Central, Eastern and Southern provinces have begun to look at farming as a business through the trainings they have received. According to these respondents, this exposure has contributed to farmers’ expansion of area cultivated therefore enhancing the need for mechanization. Other factors that were highlighted during the interviews included the issue of availability of financing options to purchase mechanized equipment, and increased demand for farm products produced in Zambia both local and internationally. 4.4.3.2.2. Performance of these initiatives The interviews with supply side actors revealed divergence of opinions on the performance of these initiatives, which were evenly split between the six respondents. On the one hand, some respondents pointed to increase in the number of farmers accessing mechanization services, improved yields for maize in the areas they operate and the increase in number of farmer TSPs. On the other hand, some respondents argued that adoption of mechanization has been low, primarily because the farmers identified to be TSPs do not have a strong business background to stimulate demand for these services. This latter view conforms to the findings from the quantitative analysis that showed that mechanization use has remained low among small- and medium-scale farmers. 4.4.3.2.3. Constraints The interviews revealed two main constraints. First, the respondents argued that a number of TSPs lack business skills needed to provide the service. Given that most of these TSPs receive the mechanization equipment through lease agreements, the poor business skills directly have an impact on the TSPs profitability, which in turn affects their ability to pay back the loan for the equipment. 196 Second, the instability in important economic indicators such as exchange rates and lending rates has affected demand for equipment. Because tractors and associated equipment are imported, the pricing structure is denominated in U.S. dollars. From, June 2015 to May 2015, the Zambian Kwacha depreciated by more than 40 percent against the U.S. dollar. Interest rates almost doubled from about 23 percent to 40 percent. The respondents strongly thought that these constraints, if not addressed, would threaten the sustainability of mechanization initiatives. 4.4.3.2.4. Summary Overall, the insights from supply side actors shed more light on the developments in mechanization service provision in Zambia. It was clear from the extensive discussions with the different actors and review of the literature that those on the supply side are primarily driving mechanization initiatives in Zambia. In 2012, the total number of TSPs stood at 58 (Aagaard, 2012) while the number of TSPs in 2015 increased to 448 (Kasanda, 2016). Based on conservative estimates that show that one TSP can provide land preparation services of up to 180 hectares per farming season, the increase in the number of TSPs should have translated to an increase in area cultivated by TSPs alone of more than eight times. The evidence from the analysis of household level data suggests otherwise; the level of mechanization use has not increased correspondingly. It is crucial for their survival that mechanization initiatives should critically look at how demand for land preparation services could be stimulated besides looking at only the supply side constraints. 197 4.5. Conclusions and recommendations Research examining the African agricultural transformation process has focused mainly on adoption of productivity enhancing inputs such as improved seeds and fertilizers. Yet, agricultural mechanization and the complementary role it plays in enhancing agricultural production and productivity has received little research attention in SSA. Recent evidence has, however, shown that agricultural labor costs in the region have been increasing (a condition that is necessary for a shift to labor saving technologies). Moreover, development agencies, the private and public sectors have initiated collaborative efforts designed to enhance mechanization service provision for agricultural production. Therefore, this essay examined the trends and effects on agricultural household production of agricultural mechanization and explored the factors contributing to recent developments aimed at enhancing mechanization in Zambia. The following were the key findings from this study. First, the evidence across a three-year period (2012-2015) showed that agricultural mechanization use by small- and medium-scale farming households has remained low and stagnant with only 1.5 percent of these households reporting that they used mechanization for land preparation. When the data where spatially analyzed, provinces with better infrastructure had a relatively higher proportion of households using mechanization. Other results examining trends in agricultural mechanization use showed that tractor use in Zambia ranged between 1.2 and 1.3 tractors per one thousand hectares cultivated; a result that demonstrates low use of mechanization and is consistent with estimates presented by previous studies on tractor use in SSA. The study found that availability of tractor hiring services was generally good in some communities but the low use of mechanization was attributed to the high cost of hiring available services. 198 Second, the study found that use of mechanization for land preparation increased farmers’ area cultivated by about 60 percent relative to those who did not use mechanization. This was not a surprising result because mechanization is expected to break the power constraint associated with more labor-intensive technologies such as hand tools and animal draft power to a lesser extent. However, the study found that mechanization use did not necessarily translate into net gains in productivity—measured as net value of crop production per hectare cultivated—for farmers. The study attributed this to low levels of intensification by farmers in Zambia of productivity enhancing inputs such as improved seed, fertilizer and others. Third, from the demand side, the results indicated that the price ratios for rental of mechanization relative to labor costs had changed over time in favor of a shift to labor saving technologies. This was particularly true in two of the three regions where mechanization initiatives have been actively promoted. But because most small- and medium-scale farming households rely on family labor and less on hired labor, this could explain why demand for mechanization had not correspondingly increased. The study established that mechanization initiatives in Zambia have mainly been driven by the supply side. The study found that constraints identified during the implementation of existing mechanization initiatives and the low demand for mechanization services are likely to impinge on the sustainability of these initiatives. Based on these key findings, we offer four sets of recommendations. First, mechanization initiatives should be targeted in regions where there is scope for expansion. From our findings, Central and Copperbelt provinces are the two leading provinces in terms of mechanization use. The two regions have also demonstrated that mechanization use has increased over the three-year period between 2012 and 2015. Therefore, promoters of mechanization should streamline their activities by targeting such regions with relative potential. 199 Second, promoters of tractor services need to promote them alongside productivity enhancing inputs. This is because mechanization does not necessarily translate into improved productivity. Third, training of farmers through private driven mechanization initiatives should be facilitated alongside the widespread government extension service system. It is commendable that the Zambian government has not played a leading role in terms of providing mechanization services to small- and medium-scale farmers. Experiences from the past have shown that government driven mechanization services failed and could not be sustained. But training is one area where public intervention could be vital. As noted by one of the key informants, farmers continue to grapple with completing activities on a timely basis, are not adequately trained on the aspects of minimizing costs of production and rarely get updates on improved technologies likely to enhance productivity. Therefore developing a mechanization-training program that involves the government extension service is likely to stimulate demand among farmers for existing mechanization services. Research in Zambia has shown that close to 60 percent of the government’s allocation to agriculture goes to supporting input and output subsidy programs that are maize centric. Unfortunately, very little is allocated for strengthening of the extension service (an important department for farmer training), research and development. Reallocating some of these funds to farmer training might help to stimulate farmer demand and engender improvements in production (stemming from cropland expansion) and ultimately help reduce poverty. The fourth recommendation arose from the discussions with different actors involved on the supply side of mechanization initiatives. From the perspective of most of these actors, they acknowledge that they have not done enough to generate demand for mechanization services by 200 small- and medium-scale farmers in the areas they operate. They argued that unlike programs related to promotion of other productivity enhancing inputs such as improved seeds and fertilizers that are quickly embraced by a reasonable proportion of farmers, mechanization initiatives and therefore use of available services take time. To ensure effectiveness of these initiatives, efforts by supply side actors should: (1) target potential tractor service providers that already have a business background; (2) continue to enhance business training of identified service providers, and; (3) work closely with the government extension system to stimulate demand among farmers who are likely to benefit from mechanization initiatives. 201 REFERENCES 202 REFERENCES Aagaard, P. (2012). Small and medium scale agriculture and mechanisation. Lusaka, Zambia: Conservation Farming Unit (CFU). ACF. (2012). Tractor mechanization of conservation agriculture - Remodelling study report. Agricultural Consultative Forum (ACF). Binswanger, H. P. (1978a). Induced Technical Change: Evolution of Thought. In H. P. Binswanger & V. W. Ruttan, Induced Innovation: Technology, Institutions, and Development. (pp. 13–43). Johns Hopkins University Press. Binswanger, H. P. (1978b). The economics of tractors in South Asia. Retrieved from http://oar.icrisat.org/id/eprint/630 Binswanger, H., & Pingali, P. (1988). TECHNOLOGICAL PRIORITIES FOR FARMING IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA. The World Bank Research Observer, 3(1), 81–98. https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/3.1.81 Burke, W. J., Hichaambwa, M., Banda, D., & Jayne, T. S. (2011). The Cost of Maize Production by Smallholder Farmers in Zambia (Working Paper No. No. 50). Lusaka, Zambia: Food Security Research Project. Retrieved from http://saipar.org:8080/eprc/handle/123456789/207 Di Falco, S., Veronesi, M., & Yesuf, M. (2011). Does Adaptation to Climate Change Provide Food Security? A Micro-Perspective from Ethiopia. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 93(3), 829–846. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aar006 Diao, X., Cossar, F., Houssou, N., & Kolavalli, S. (2014). Mechanization in Ghana: Emerging demand, and the search for alternative supply models. Food Policy, 48, 168–181. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2014.05.013 Fugile, K., & Rada, N. (2013, May 6). USDA Economic Research Service - Research Raises Agricultural Productivity in Sub-Saharan Africa. Retrieved March 27, 2014, from http://www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2013-may/research-raises-agriculturalproductivity-in-sub-saharan-africa.aspx#.UzRXIF660oY Hayami, Y., & Ruttan, V. W. (1970). Factor prices and technical change in agricultural development: The United States and Japan, 1880-1960. Journal of Political Economy, 78(5), 1115–1141. Hayami, Y., & Ruttan, V. W. (1985). Agricultural development: an international perspective. Johns Hopkins University Press. 203 Houssou, N., & Chapoto, A. (2014). The changing landscape of agriculture in Ghana: Drivers of farm mechanization and its impacts on cropland expansion and intensification. Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2539595 Houssou, N., Diao, X., Cossar, F., Kolavalli, S., Jimah, K., & Aboagye, P. O. (2013). Agricultural Mechanization in Ghana: Is Specialized Agricultural Mechanization Service Provision a Viable Business Model? American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 95(5), 1237–1244. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aat026 Jayne, T. S., Chamberlin, J., Traub, L., Sitko, N., Muyanga, M., Yeboah, F. K., … Kachule, R. (2016). Africa’s changing farm size distribution patterns: the rise of medium-scale farms. Agricultural Economics, 47(S1), 197–214. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12308 Jonsson, L.-O. (1985). Agricultural Mechanization. In Structural readjustments and Zambia’s self-reliance in farm equipment (pp. 25–29). Lusaka, Zambia: International Labour Office. Kasanda, E. (2016). Email message to author. Lokshin, M., & Sajaia, Z. (2004). Maximum likelihood estimation of endogenous switching regression models, 4(3), 282–289. Maddala, G. S. (1983). Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. New York: Cambridge University Press. Minten, B., & Barrett, C. B. (2008). Agricultural Technology, Productivity, and Poverty in Madagascar. World Development, 36(5), 797–822. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.05.004 Mrema, G. C., Baker, D. C., & Kahan, D. (2008). Agricultural mechanization in Sub-saharan Africa: time for a new look. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization on the United Nations. Pingali, P. (2007). Chapter 54 Agricultural Mechanization: Adoption Patterns and Economic Impact. In R. Evenson and P. Pingali (Ed.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics (Vol. Volume 3, pp. 2779–2805). Elsevier. Retrieved from http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1574007206030544 Pingali, P. L., Bigot, Y., & Binswanger-Mkhize, H. P. (1987). Agricultural mechanization and the evolution of farming systems in sub-Saharan Africa. Baltimore: Published for the World Bank, Johns Hopkins University Press. Porter, M. E., & Kramer, M. R. (2011). Creating Shared Value. Harvard Business Review, 89(1/2), 62–77. Ricker-Gilbert, J., Jayne, T., & Shively, G. (2013). Addressing the “Wicked Problem” of Input Subsidy Programs in Africa. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 35(2), 322–340. https://doi.org/10.1093/aepp/ppt001 204 Ruttan, V. W. (2002). Productivity Growth in World Agriculture: Sources and Constraints. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(4), 161–184. Sitko, N., & Chamberlin, J. (2015). The Anatomy of Medium-Scale Farm Growth in Zambia: What Are the Implications for the Future of Smallholder Agriculture? Land, 4(3), 869– 887. https://doi.org/10.3390/land4030869 Sitko, N. J., & Jayne, T. S. (2012). The Rising Class of Emergent Farmers: An Effective Model for Achieving Agricultural Growth and Poverty Reduction in Africa? (Working Paper No. 69). Lusaka, Zambia: Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI). Retrieved from http://www.aec.msu.edu/fs2/zambia/wp69.pdf Strauss, A., & Corbin, J. (1994). Grounded Theory Methodology: An Overview. In N. K. Denzin & Y. S. Lincoln (Eds.), Handbook of Qualitative Research (pp. 273–285). SAGE Publications. Takeshima, H., Nin--Pratt, A., & Diao, X. (2013). Mechanization and Agricultural Technology Evolution, Agricultural Intensification in Sub-Saharan Africa: Typology of Agricultural Mechanization in Nigeria. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 95(5), 1230– 1236. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aat045 Takeshima, H., & Salau, S. (2010). Agricultural mechanization and the smallholder farmers in Nigeria (Policy note No. 22). Abuja, Nigeria: International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI). Retrieved from http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/nssppn22_0.pdf Tembo, G. (1985). Agricultural Mechanisation Policy. In Structural readjustments and Zambia’s self-reliance in farm equipment (pp. 31–33). Lusaka, Zambia: International Labour Office. Verma, S. R. (2008). Impact of agricultural mechanization on production, productivity, cropping intensity income generation and employment of labour. Status of Farm Mechanization in India, Punjab Agricultural University, Ludhiana, 133–153. Yang, J., Huang, Z., Zhang, X., & Reardon, T. (2013). The Rapid Rise of Cross-Regional Agricultural Mechanization Services in China. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 95(5), 1245–1251. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aat027 205 CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSIONS This dissertation explored an important issue that has re-emerged in the development discourse—farm structure change—and whether this change represents an opportunity for countries in SSA to address the myriad of challenges confronting agricultural development. The general focus of scholars studying farm structure change in the current agricultural development literature has largely been on the development implications of large-scale land acquisitions of foreign origin (typically own thousands of hectares of land but cultivate more than 100 hectares) and less on farm structure change associated with the rise of domestic medium-scale farmers (landholding between 5 and 100 hectares). While foreign driven large-scale land acquisitions have played a role in altering the agricultural landscape in SSA, the increase in pace at which land is being acquired by domestic land investors has completely changed the farm structure outlook. As a result, the domestic land investor dynamic has ignited interest in the development discourse to understand whether or not this new phenomenon signals an alternative pathway for achieving agricultural development in parts of SSA. In this light, this dissertation examined farm structure change associated with domestic medium-scale investor farms and its implications for agricultural development in sub-Saharan Africa. The study had three specific objectives: (1) to investigate the causes and consequences of the rise of domestic medium-scale investor farms; (2) to re-examine the inverse farm sizeproductivity (IR) relationship hypothesis in the context of farm structure change, and; (3) to explore the trends and effects on agricultural production of agricultural mechanization use and determine what is driving the rise in mechanization initiatives. The study was conducted in Zambia because the country has been experiencing major changes in farm structure, the most 206 salient of which is a major increase in cultivated area under the control of farms between 5 and 100 hectares. This dissertation makes three key contributions to literature on agricultural development. First, it adds to the emerging literature on farm structure change by extending the depth of understanding related to the causes and consequences of farm structure change associated with medium-scale investor farms in SSA. This is achieved through a mixed-methods analytical framework that combines political economy insights and the new institutional economics paradigm. Second, it proposes and empirically implements a methodological approach not fully exploited in studies examining the inverse farm size-productivity hypothesis in SSA. The definition of productivity is extended beyond land productivity to include alternative measures and the hypothesis is tested on a sample with farm size data outside the zero to ten hectare range; the latter is done to address recent criticism of the IR literature that has extrapolated findings beyond the ten-hectare range. The constant-returns-to-scale assumption upheld in most IR empirical work is also relaxed in this study. Third, this dissertation research contributes to the emerging literature aimed at guiding policy of mechanization in SSA. We discuss the key findings of this research in line with each main objective. Five key findings emerged from the first objective. First, the study identified three main drivers of farm structure change: (1) a positive change in society’s perception of agriculture; (2) a change in enforcement of informal rules of customary land governance; and; (3) unintended consequence of public spending in agriculture. In terms of change in society’s perception of agriculture, for example, the consensus among the key informants was that perception had changed from looking at agriculture as a domain for those who are poor to a domain that is viewed as a profitable venture for anyone with interest in agriculture and has adequate financial resources. In terms of 207 change in the governance of customary land, the main issue that was raised by the key informants was that informal land markets had been allowed to take root contrary to established norms. They indicated that the development of the informal market for land had significantly contributed to individual land acquisitions especially between 10 and 50 hectares in rural areas closer to urban centers of Zambia. With respect to the unintended consequence of public spending in agriculture, the general consensus among the key informants was that the two main subsidy programs in agriculture—the input support program (FISP) and the output subsidy initiative (FRA)—had continued to operate under numerous implementation challenges and hence distorting the incentive structure. Put together, all the three drivers identified by this study had contributed to the rise of medium-scale farms and change in farm structure in Zambia. Second, the study reinforced the finding by previous studies that the change in farm structure had been characterized by expansion of medium-scale farms and land concentration in Zambia. In particular, the study found that the change in the number of farms of five hectares and above had been more rapid than farms below five hectares between 2001 and 2015. Further, the study also showed that average landholding decreased the most for the smallest category of farms examined (less than 2 hectares) while the largest category (20-100 hectares) saw an increase in average landholding of more than 10 percent at national level. In addition to the characterization of farm structure change, the study found that expansion of medium-scale farms in Zambia had not only been by individuals who are local to the community but also individuals migrating from other parts of the country. Moreover, individuals with access to wage income and urban-based households had also driven the expansion in medium-scale farms and that this surge in land acquisitions had gathered momentum in the last 20-25 years. 208 Third, while the analysis showed that medium-scale farms cultivated relatively large portions of land, the study on the other hand showed that they left significant portions of land idle. This has implications for prospects of small-scale agricultural expansion especially when recent evidence has clearly shown that small-scale farmers face serious land constraints. Further, the results from both the quantitative and qualitative analysis indicated that the agricultural sector had become maize centric in the context of farm structure change. Fourth, the study found that titling of agricultural land had remained relatively low and was more likely to be taken up by farmers who fall within the medium-scale farmer category. Moreover, where traditional leaders had put in place traditional landholding certification as a way of reducing land disputes in customary land, households with relatively large landholdings were more likely to obtain these certificates. The study linked the low levels of titling to lack of awareness of the process of obtaining title, traditional leaders unwillingness to allow conversion of customary land to titled land and the bureaucracy associated with processing titles. The study also found that land rental and sales markets have begun to emerge in customary land areas and had been a consequence of the involvement of those with the financial capacity to induce transactions reminiscent of a market based system. Fifth, the study found that although more than 80 percent of farmers in Zambia fall within the small-scale farming category, medium- and large-scale farms had steadily increased their share of national crop production especially non-maize crop production. In terms of crop marketing (maize and non-maize crop sales), small-scale farms continued to contribute to national marketed output. However, the high level of participation in marketing of all crop types by medium- and large-scale farming households suggested that relatively large farms had a more important role in Zambia’s agricultural growth and development. 209 The key findings from the second objective were as follows. First, when the IR hypothesis was tested using representative data with about 15 percent of farms with landholding sizes of 20 hectares or more, the results were not uniform across the five measures of productivity used in the study. The relationship between farm size and productivity upheld the IR, rejected the IR or was uncorrelated depending on the measure of productivity. Results showed that when net value of crop production per hectare was regressed on farm size ceteris paribus, the IR was upheld at 10 percent significance level. This modest level of significance could be attributed to the fact that, unlike in past studies where input use intensity has been found to be higher on small relative to large farms, the opposite was true in the case of this study. When the outcome variable was a labor productivity measure, the study found a strong positive relationship between farm size and labor productivity. In the case of cost of maize production per metric ton produced, the study found that the cost of maize production per ton increased with maize area planted of up to 10 hectares. This result upheld the IR because small farms were able to produce a ton of maize at a cheaper cost than large farms, but only for the 0 – 10 hectares domain. The estimation results for TFP showed that this comprehensive measure of productivity was negatively associated with operated farm size albeit not statistically significant. Second, the study found that differences in crop management practices played a key role in driving productivity differences between small- and medium-scale farms. Management practices that were prominent in explaining productivity differences were total inorganic fertilizer use, herbicide use, animal draft power use and the nature of land allocation to different crop types. Third, relaxing the constant returns to scale assumption strengthened the IR hypothesis (in the case of net value of crop production per hectare and TFP) or weakened the 210 argument that large farms are more productive than small farms (in the case of the two labor productivity measures). The last objective had three main findings. First, the evidence across a three year period (2012-2015) showed that agricultural mechanization use by small- and medium-scale farming households had remained low and stagnated with only 1.5 percent of these households reporting that they used mechanization for land preparation. When the data where spatially analyzed, provinces with better infrastructure had a relatively higher proportion of households using mechanization. Other results examining trends in agricultural mechanization use showed that tractor use in Zambia ranged between 1.2 and 1.3 tractors per one thousand hectares cultivated; a result that demonstrates low use of mechanization and is consistent with estimates presented by previous studies on tractor use in SSA. The study found that availability of tractor hiring services was generally good in most of the communities but the low use of mechanization was attributed to the high cost of hiring available services. Second, the study found that use of mechanization for land preparation increased farmers’ area cultivated by about 60 percent relative to those who did not use mechanization. This was not a surprising result because mechanization is expected to reduce the drudgery associated with more labor-intensive technologies such as hand tools and animal draft power to a lesser extent. However, the study found that mechanization use did not necessarily translate into net gains in productivity—measured as net value of crop production per hectare cultivated—for farmers. The study attributed this to low levels of intensification by farmers in Zambia of productivity enhancing inputs such as improved seed, fertilizer and others. Third, on the demand side, the results indicated that the price ratios for rental of mechanization relative to labor costs had changed over time in favor of a shift to labor saving 211 technologies. This was particularly true in two of the three regions where mechanization initiatives have been actively promoted. But because most small- and medium-scale farming households rely on family labor and less on hired labor, this probably explains why demand for mechanization has not correspondingly increased. The study established that mechanization initiatives in Zambia have mainly been driven by the supply side. This is because the different actors on the supply side have embraced the principles of shared values that entail a win-win situation for both their clients (farming community) and themselves as service providers. What do these findings imply for policy? The first study demonstrates that there are a number of political economy factors that have contributed to the change in farm structure. The consequences of this change are that agricultural growth and subsequently development have not been widespread. Policy strategies should address not only the inequalities that exist in terms of land access and ownership by small-scale farmers but also address the bottlenecks associated with obtaining title or indeed traditional landholding certificates. Although there is considerable debate on the link between agriculture productivity and tenure status, this paper demonstrates that the process of obtaining title is mainly being exploited by farmers who are categorized as medium-scale farmers. If small-scale farmers are not part of this process, there is a danger that, with time, some households may become landless. To enhance small-scale farmers’ role in agricultural markets, policy should also endeavor to promote research and development initiatives that would uplift their production levels and generate surplus for markets. Obviously, this strategy should not be maize centric but should extend to other crops or livestock suitable for small-scale agriculture. Findings on the relationship between productivity and operated farm size, while important, should not be the decisive factor in guiding agricultural development and land policies 212 in SSA because there are many other important considerations. The challenges of rural poverty that continue to bedevil SSA are better addressed by pursuing broad based development strategies whose central focus should remain smallholder farmers. This entails promoting policies that would enhance productivity growth among smallholders, as this is crucial to poverty reduction and development. Moreover, an inclusive smallholder form of agricultural growth will clearly generate employment growth in both farm and non-farm sectors than a comparable rate of agricultural growth concentrated among a few large farms. Based on the findings of the third study that demonstrate that mechanization use has remained low and that the supply side has identified constraints that are likely to undermine the sustainability of recent efforts to enhance mechanization, this research offers the following recommendations. First, the study recommends policy action that is geared towards enhancing provision of training to farmers on the benefits of using technologies such as mechanization for land preparation. Farmers continue to grapple with completing farming activities on a timely basis, are not adequately trained on the aspects of minimizing costs of production and rarely get updates on improved technologies likely to enhance productivity. Therefore developing a mechanization-training program that involves the government extension service could assist with stimulating demand among farmers for existing mechanization services. Research in Zambia has shown that close to 60 percent of government’s allocation to agriculture goes to supporting input and output subsidy programs that are maize centric. Reallocating some of these funds to farmer training might help to stimulate farmer demand and engender improvements in production (stemming from cropland expansion) and ultimately help reduce poverty. Second, to ensure effectiveness of mechanization initiatives, efforts by supply side actors should: (1) target potential tractor service providers that already have a business background; (2) 213 continue to enhance business training of identified service providers, and; (3) work closely with the government extension system to stimulate demand among farmers who are likely to benefit from mechanization initiatives. 214