‘ :.-s.n-EE¥EE1WI1:IL.‘. E-' L‘ :iE I; jg! Ez. .{E‘lh ”WES;- | ”NJ .E EEEEEE Q-‘W‘EEEL .3] MY W. ‘ In '0 ‘ EU u ,n ‘i‘. '1": ‘ E31 C- u LE; ' l W, “nan-.. _ M... “3 V1.4 _ —. _ "a. w a. “m- k*".‘" n .— mar - u .. . -M a ' .flu ' . .-.,.-. - y.’ M {II A. . . r- ‘ . ,. ,. . . a ‘ . A -W n“ . . h f. . , ' . v ’v ' .1. 1%. - . n): :4" ‘ E ‘71:: de- 53'1va Km" ' {LEE ‘ “We“ 5:3; $1.?" IEAIE ~5§£31§ 1‘1 E: mam. E: mu ‘ ~ ‘ ‘ - A j . l *-“"“I"“‘ WE“, 3153.3 AW 1' gssgtdz.‘:!?-it*‘ez E ‘E z" E E1. $1.543?! 2-31.51 ;E. ‘:::' . :4 z E 214:3t1fi11'1‘E‘5W“ . .. E‘ W WW % 31.:‘131-33, «111 xiii : ‘I‘EIE'Wgh‘W'b 1. Hi. ‘inl ‘. ”QR-(49.341 WEE“ '-§"‘a{u«3~ :"lE “1‘ 2:43. is“; . 3E 'né‘vh‘WEEE Ej‘hE ' E,’ ': ‘ TEN In: EEIE a 9'1me " ‘ ' :E 411.131? 55mg"?- LE“ “WWW ' 1 ".13- ‘s‘.;gEE:;=.ir';lF 1‘53 W r~ .- O. " .A. . 7.. .. a «E- ° 35" A-v.—r- . ¢ » .,__.-... ~. . z‘dt'. v- p. Y E. E E .Ntf'E , , V M‘ J. ‘ "‘ ‘cfx‘afl’ v».- a,“ 2‘“ ”r... .-,A 1:1: 9 QIEEEZJE 1E 31} ." ‘5'; H“ ‘1‘, iElégi" "v '1“: . I E‘ r E:-. l . “v.9 (5:35"! .2“ 9' . :' E 1 . z_v ‘EE MEEWEHH . .. ‘EE‘E. _ E E.) _ 'EW .E E _ .. .33 3E {hf .. ‘ ' . “MEN ". 5115'; 1: JE‘: I ‘l :19. ”El .31”; .'| .t; ‘EE' ‘ D a” 3‘.“ I F” : W!‘ Y'EEIL l'.‘ . . ’1!le M' W4 3' .. ‘E' E E '.E‘.t..'i?-,E'EE;- ., {WEI ‘E gE-E- E 1; '.~.EE ‘ J E’E‘j.‘ "(-31" 534. l‘ 'J' ‘ "I. $1 I‘~“.“ (Iru E‘ I 4 'L-EI- :fl'E- IE; in: ‘I I E, "V.- . E" . l:_L, ‘SWE'Wf‘ ‘“ fill“ “it“ . EEEEEE “Ewing‘s“ m. ‘1" 1‘ .EEJEEEEE «E ‘EE:E‘! EELLEE E “1“" le EE'h E42: 1” BREW" EEEE: “EH 5?: EEEE: it ~ E‘EEEEEEE EEEE'EE A“ E: . ’:1!l1.:"‘3:!1~fl‘1-E7E1f21 E: EEEEEEEE‘ “213;" . ..... {1“ EE'EE‘E ‘ETEEE' E SN“: .“'1EE|1'3"“ EEEEE IEIEEE‘EEE :IEE‘E: l ttv'Ezgfl -PET'I!E“I'I}"'L!¢ ‘Elfiklhly‘j‘Lfl! “kw E ‘EM l - ~15Ehfi~hhinhm QM. {EMI‘V Hf m' h: ““1"“:in (““21'13kw. . .n . Ii'fi'vhm‘i‘mmlm'ilfil‘imf. E11 * .13L_____‘. WEI” This is to certify that the dissertation entitled AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF POLITICAL RISK ON THE MODE OF OPERATIONS IN FOREIGN MARKETS presented by SAMUEL CHIGOZIRI OKOROAFO has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for PhD nBUSINESS ADMINISTRATION degree i Date 7/? //K4 MS U i: an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 IVIESI_J BEIURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to LJBRARJES remove this checkout from Ala-23.3... your record. FINES will ——— a be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. 1 - l. -\ A a is“. \J - ‘— AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF POLITICAL RISK ON THE MODE OF OPERATIONS IN FOREIGN MARKETS BY Samuel Chigoziri Okoroafo A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Marketing and Transportation 1986 Copyright by Samuel Chigoziri Okoroafo 1986. ABSTRACT AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF POLITICAL RISK ON THE MODE OF OPERATIONS IN FOREIGN MARKETS BY Samuel Chigoziri Okoroafo The objective of this research was to examine the role of political risk (compared to market size and market growth rate) and its impact on the mode of operations decisions of U.S. manufacturing firms. Mode of operations, such as exporting, licensing, joint ventures and investing, was viewed as a behavioral pattern of multinational firms. The study was conceptualized within the framework of two schools of thought. The incremental school sees modes of operations as a passive, gradual and evolving process, while the strategic school views them as dynamic alternatives to access foreign markets. Cross-sectional and time series data was pooled in order to test hypothesized effects of political risk on the substitution of exporting for investing behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms. Personal interviews were also conducted with executives of Michigan firms with foreign operations from five industries: chemicals, computers, aircraft, agricultural, motor vehicles and transportation equipment industries. The analysis suggests that the role of political risk is different for developed and developing country-markets. In developed country-markets, political risk plays a minimal role in U.S. firms decisions to export or invest. For developing' country-markets Ihowevery political risk: was. a major factor in comparison to market size and market growth rate in the investment decision only. On the substitution of exporting for investing behavior in high risk markets, this research showed that in developing country-markets, political risk does not cause U.S. firms to substitute exporting for investing, rather, licensing and joint ventures were preferred. In developed country-markets, market size was more closely associated with exporting, not investment. This implies a preference by U.S. manufacturing firms for exporting in developed country- markets with relatively large market size. It is suggested that mode of operations is a behavior pattern and that the choice of either depends on some key variables. Firms do not have to initially export, then license, and finally invest to gain a foothold in a foreign market. Future research therefore should concentrate on factors that determine the mode of entry and their relative importance and not simply assume an evolution from exporting to investing. Also, attention should be paid to key factors that cause firms to switch modes to accomplish their goals. To my parents, Abel Chikwendu & Gladys Uchem for their love, encouragement, and support. You have taught me a lot. You are my idols. ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS It is difficult to complete a PhD jprogram and dissertation without placing reliance upon a number of professors, friends, colleagues, and family. First of all, I thank God with a deep sense of humility and gratitude for giving me good health , strength and perseverance. To 'my' Dissertation Committee :members, Professors Gilbert Harrell, Donald Taylor and especially John L. Hazard, my chairman, I am greatly indebted for improving the ideas of this research and their presentation. To the faculty in the Department of Marketing and Transportation, particularly Dr. D. J. Bowersox, Dr. Forrest "Sam" Carter, Dr. George Wagenheim, and Dr. David "Skip" Smith who have at one time or the other provided valuable assistance and advice, I thank very much. To my friends/mentors, Dean Richard J. Lewis, Dr.& Mrs. George Axinn, without their reposed confidence in me, this would not have been possible. To my Doctoral colleagues, Morris Perry, David Amponsah, Masaaki "Mike" Kotabe, Haksik Lee and Walter Zinn, it certainly has been a pleasure knowing and working with them. The exchange of ideas and personal experiences was an invaluable help. iii To the companies that agreed to participate in this research and their executives, I am also appreciative. I am. grateful to IMichigan State ‘University for providing an enlightening and enriching atmosphere for pursuit of academic knowledge. Finally I am grateful to my family. My wife, Jane and daughter, Katrina Uchem, thanks for the inspiration, concern and faith. They have been pillars of strength. While others assisted in various ways, I alone am responsible for the interpretation of the information presented in this dissertation. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ........ ... ....... ................... vii List of Figures... ....... .......................... ix CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The Problem..................... ...... ....... 1 Defining Mode of Operations.................. 7 Defining Political Risk...................... 12 Significance of the study.................... 18 Theoretical contribution................... 19 Practical contribution..................... 21 Limitations of the study..................... 22 Organization of the study.................... 23 Theoretical Framework........................ 24 Incremental school of thought.............. 24 Strategic school of thought................ 27 Cost based models.......................... 32 Business Reaction to Political Risk........ 36 Model Specification Market size and Growth rate.............. 42 Political Risk........................... 45 Conceptual framework....................... 51 II LITERATURE REVIEW............................. 55 Incremental School.......................... 58 Cross-country studies..................... 58 Cross-firm studies........................ 63 Strategic School............................ 71 Cross-country studies..................... 71 Cross-firm studies........................ 84 III METHODOLOGY Research design............................. 96 Rationale................................... 99 Theoretical Decision Rules.................. 102 Rules for selecting time periods.......... 105 Rules for selecting variables............. 106 Rules for selecting measures.............. 106 Hypothesis and their rationale.............. 107 The Variables and their Measures............ 115 Political Risk (RISK)..................... 115 Market Size (GDP)......................... 119 Market Growth Rate (MAGRO)................ 120 Exporting (EXPORT)........................ 121 v IV V VI Foreign Direct Investment (FODIV)......... Data Analysis Procedure..................... Homogeneity test.......................... How to pool data.......................... THE SUBSTANTIVE FINDINGS...................... Lag zeroMOdeIOO0............OOOOOOOOOOOC... Exports.........OIOOOOOOOOOO0.000.000.0000 Foreign Direct Investment................. Lag One Model............................... Exports................................... Foreign Direct Investment................. Lag Two Model............................... Exports................................... Foreign Direct Investment................. DISCUSSION OF RESULTS... ..... ................. Selecting the Appropriate Lag Model.......... Synopsis of Findings......................... Finding one...0....O......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO Finding Two................................. Finding Three............................... Finding Four................................ Finding Five................................ Finding Six................................. IMPLICATIONS OF RESULTS AND FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTION...C......OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO Glossary of Terms................................... Appendices A. B. C. D. E. F. G. H. I. J. K. L. List EXPORT DATA: SOURCE,COVERAGE,DEFINITIONS ..... U.S. FDI DATA: SOURCE,COVERAGE,DEFINITION .... NATIONAL ACCOUNTS STATISTICS,SOURCE,COVERAGE.. COUNTRIES SELECTED FOR THE STUDY.............. LETTER OF INVITATION SENT TO COMPANIES........ RESPONSE SHEET................................ FOLLOW-UP LETTER.............................. INTERVIEW SCHEDULE............................ DATA ON COMPANIES INTERVIEWED................. PERSONAL INTERVIEW QUESTIONS.................. BERI DATA COLLECTION METHOD................... LETTER OF THANKS............. ............ 2.... Of ReferenceSOOOOOOOOOOOOO0......0.00.00.00.00. vi 121 122 123 123 131 136 136 145 156 156 162 173 173 173 183 183 187 188 194 198 202 207 213 218 226 230 234 237 241 242 243 244 245 246 247 249 256 257 LIST OF TABLES 1. Three Major Taxonomies of Modes of Foreign Involvement.................................... 11 2. Conceptual Framework of the Political Process... 17 3. Comparison of Major Studies on Business Reaction to Political Risk..................... 37 4. Political Risk: A Conceptual Framework.... ..... . 50 5. Summary of Relevant Literature Reviewed......... 59 6. Summary of FDI-Political Risk Studies........... 60 7. Taxonomy of TimeSeries, Crosssectional Models... 124 8. Initial Correlation Coefficients................ 133 9. Final Correlation Coefficients.................. 134 10. OLS Timeseries Estimates for Exports, Fixed Intercept Model .......... ...................... 137 11. OLS Timeseries Estimates for Exports, Random Intercept Model ....... . ............. ........... 140 12. OLS Cross-sectional Estimates for Exports, Fixed Intercept Model ........ .................. 141 13. Export Regression Results with Lag = 0.......... 143 14. Anova Table for Exports (Lag = 0)........ ....... 144 15. OLS Timeseries Estimates for FDI, Fixed Intercept ModeIOOOOCOO......COOOOCOOOO0.0000... 146 16. OLS Timeseries Estimates for FDI, Random Intercept Model ..... . ...... ............. ....... 147 17. OLS Cross-sectional Estimates for FDI, Fixed Intercept Model ..... ....... ....... . ...... 149 18. FDI Regression Results with Lag = 0............. 150 19. Anova Table for FDI (Lag = 0)................... 151 20. Partial Correlation Coefficients Controlling for Market Size and Growth Rate (LDC).......... 154 21. Partial Correlation Coefficients Controlling for Political Risk and Market Growth Rate (DC). 155 22. OLS Timeseries Estimates for Exports, Fixed Intercept Model (Lag 1)........ ...... .... 157 23. OLS Timeseries Estimates for Exports, Random Intercept Model (Lag 1)................. 159 24. Export Regression Results with Lag = 1 ........ .. 161 25. Anova Table for Exports (Lag = 1)........ ...... . 163 26. OLS Timeseries Estimates for FDI, Fixed Intercept Model (Lag = 1). ....... ........ 164 27. OLS Timeseries Estimates for FDI, Random Intercept Model (Lag = 1)............... 165 28. FDI Regression Results with Lag = 1............. 167 29. Anova Table for FDI (Lag = 1)................... 168 30. Partial Correlation Coefficient Controlling for Market Size and Growth Rate (LDC).......... 171 31. Partial Correlation Coefficient Controlling for Political Risk and Growth Rate (DC)........ 172 32. Export Equation Regressio? Results (Lag = 2).....174 v1 33. Anova Table for Exports (Lag = 2)............... 175 34. FDI Regression Results (Lag = 2)................ 176 35. Anova Table for FDI............................. 177 36. Partial Correlation Coefficients Controlling for Market Size and Growth Rate (LDC).......... 180 37. Partial Correlation Coefficients Controlling for Political Risk and Growth Rate (DC)........ 181 38. Alternate Hypothesis Results for All Three Lag Models..................................... 184 39. Factors Motivating the Export Effort............ 215 viii 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. LIST OF FIGURES Distinction between International Channel of Distribution and Mode of Entry ........ ......... Distinction between Mode of Entry and Mode of Operations. ................... ........ ..... Relationship between U. S. Manufacturing Exports and FDI................................ Modes of Operations as a Function of Fixed and Variable Costs of Operation................ Exporting and Overseas Production as a Function of Demand............................. Alternative Models to be Tested....... ..... ..... Firm and Market Specific Factors that Determine Modes of Operations.................. Effect of Political Risk on Mode of Operations.. Order of Literature Review...................... Internal Determinants of Export Behavior........ IPLC from the Viewpoint of a Follower Nation.... Investment as a Function of Firm Size........... Modes of Operations, Competitive Position, and Country Attractiveness Grid................ Exporting as a Learning Experience.............. Revised Conceptual Framework.................... ix 3O 33 35 43 46 53 57 66 68 77 89 212 225 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION THE PROBLEM After a firm decides to seek profits and growth in foreign markets, the next concern is which markets to enter and what modes to use to access those markets. The mode of entry and operations then becomes an important determinant of the amount of resources to be committed and other operational issues. Investment will require commitment of large amounts of resources over an extended time period while exporting on the other hand requires relatively less resource commitment. What then determines the mode of operations which a firm will use? This study looks at the effects of political risk in influencing U.S. manufacturing firms mode of operations decisions. The objective is to develop and test some hypothesis concerning the role of political risk in the mode of operations decision. The mode of involvement and operations has been the subject of investigation for decades. Early theorists have been concerned with why nations trade, and the benefits from trade and the commodity composition of trade, etc. While these early trade theorists made significant contributions to the development of thought in international trade, they have created a research direction around which future studies in the area have followed. The assumption has been that a firm interested in foreign markets has to access the foreign market first via exports, then licensing, then joint ventures and finally full scale commitment of resources or foreign investment in order to minimize risk and accrue experience. OTHER STUDIES Researchers in international marketing have followed the trails of the trade theorists. The first studies have focused on initial involvement decisionsl: the result has been a multiplicity of studies on exporting.2 The studies on exporting have been concerned with the following questions: who initiates the export decision, what are the factors affecting export involvement and success, and how does a firm implement its decision? Recently the mode of operations decisions has been viewed as a strategic decision involving a choice among alternatives. (Ayal and Ziff 1978,1979):3 The choice of mode of operations therefore will depend on several factors. Neilson (1980) has related entry decisions to a firms differential advantage which he called a resource mix. Ayal and Ziff (1978) related a firms' choice of operations mode to the desire to pursue market expansion versus market concentration strategies. In a later study, Ayal and Ziff (1979) indicated that the choice of a market expansion strategy will be affected by ten key product-market factors. Goodnow and Hansz (1972) using an environmental temperature gradient concluded that the mode of entry into foreign markets by U.S. firms depends on the environmental attractiveness of the market.4 Their conclusions were that U.S. investors tended to use entry strategies involving the greatest/most commitment of resources (i.e. foreign. direct investment) in. markets that are environmentally attractive or hot, and exported to markets that are environmentally unattractive or cold' MaClayton, Smith & Hair (1980) arrived at the same conclusions using a sample of firms in the. U.S. health care products industry. According to MaClayton, Smith & Hair (1980), the dimensions used by these firms to evaluate foreign markets include: " market and marketing opportunity, legal barriers and their economic objectives, cultural unity' and physiographic ibarriers, political stability, and the level of economic development and performance of the industry."(p.45) Davidson & Harrigan (1977) in their study on new product introductions in foreign markets showed that licensing and FDI were used at roughly the same rate as means of introducing new products in foreign markets. Unfortunately in all these studies on mode of entry or operations, political risk has either not been included or its effect not isolated and tested. Yet surveys of international executives have ranked it a very important factor in the foreign involvement decision. In studies where political instability or risk has been considered it has however been empirically tested exclusively with one mode of operation primarily FDI as if other modes are not affected by political risk. (for instance see Bennett & Green 1972: Nigh 1985) In other studies, political risk and/or its consequences have only been considered with variables other than modes of operations. This study focuses on the U.S. manufacturing sector only. Kobrin (1980) argues that the probability of forced divestment (a consequence of political risk) is a function of three interrelated characteristics of investors: i.e. industrial sector, ownership structure, and level and maturity of technology. The political risks which a firm faces cannot be attributed to nationalism alone. Kobrin's study showed that forced divestment isn't simply a manifestation of "economic nationalism", reflecting national pride, an anti-foreign bias, or political opportunism. Forced divestment according to Kobrin is a policy instrument used to attempt to achieve national economic objectives by increasing control over economic factors. In the vast majority of countries in Kobrins' study (approximately 89%), forced divestment was selective. While political and/or ideological motives were certainly not absent, only a portion of foreign-owned firms were forced. to divest. Further' more, there, is sufficient evidence to conclude that the selection of firms forced to divest is far from a random process. Enterprise vulnerability is 21 function of industrial sector, ownership structure, and behavior. It is apparent that U.S. firms cannot take FDI in high risk environments for granted. As Bregsten, Horst, & Moran (1978) have suggested; with time the net result is a shift in power from multinationals to home countries that is cumulative, irreversible, and speeding up with time and thus resulting in unfavorable consequences. This study postulates that political risk, along with market size and market growth rate are major determinants of the mode of operations (exporting, licensing, joint venture, foreign direct investment-FDI) used by U.S. manufacturing firms in accessing foreign ‘markets. Moreover the process is dynamic. U.S. firms continue to adapt their strategies to changing political risk factors in markets. RECENT TRENDS As the world's leading supplier of foreign direct investment capital, U.S. companies have been sensitive to the shifts in the global investment climate. Feldman (1978a) attributes this to the "shifting perception"(p.2; and policies of host governments. Nation-States through their policies may constitute a barrier to achievement of the firms' goals . Between 1966 and 1976, the book value of American direct investments abroad grew steadily at an impressive average annual rate of about 10% per year: however, the composition of the annual increase in total U.S. foreign investment has undergone a gradual and revealing change. The proportion financed through capital outflows from U.S. parent companies have declined, with larger increments supplied from reinvested earnings of affiliates. In 1967, 67% of the added increment to book value of U.S. direct investments abroad was accounted for by net capital outflows from U.S. parents. Outflows continued to dominate until 1972, when for the first time reinvested earnings accounted for 64% of the net increment in book value. In 1976, only 35% of the increase in U.S. direct investments abroad came from capital outflows, while reinvested earnings accounted for nearly 60%. The remaining 5% was attributed to "international and unallocated" source.5 One might attribute this to U.S. government action in order to protect the balance of payments; however, the controls have been lifted and capital outflows have only rebounded moderately. The high political risk countries have accounted for only 20% of total investment.6 This suggests that American investors are evaluating their investment decision, and adjusting to political risk among other variables. The shift in the climate for foreign investment in most developing countries is more extreme than that of the developed world. This suggest that U.S. firms may be opting for other forms of investment such as rentals, licensing, franchising, service contracts and exports. DEFINING MODE OF OPERATIONS The conceptual definition of mode of operations starts with an understanding of a similar and sometimes substituted term - mode of entry. A foreign market entry mode according to Root (1982) is "an institutional arrangement that makes possible the entry of a company's products, technology, human skills, management, or other resources into a foreign country." (p.5) This definition distinguishes international channels of distribution from an entry mode. International channel of distribution is a broader term and deals with movement of products through domestic and foreign intermediaries from. producers to consumers within the foreign market. Mode of entry on the other hand deals with movement of factors of production, products, technology, and management across countrv boundaries. Figure 1 uses an adaptation of Cateora's international. channel of «distribution framework: 'to illustrate this difference. This study' also distinguishes between Wmode of entry" and "mode of operation." The former refers to the means used to initially access or enter a foreign market while the latter to mode used to continue operations in that market. A firm may decide to enter a market via joint ventures (mode of entry) but subsequently increases its' commitment of resources in the form of foreign direct investment (FDI). Using FDI as an example, mode of operations refers to initial investments, reinvestment and divestments. Figure 2 shows this distinction. Th feedback loop in Figure 2 represents a desire by management to adjust modes. While most authors refrain from offering formal definitions of mode of entry, there are numerous typologies or classifications. Table 1 compares three major classifications. Export entry mode probably is the .omm .m .A.ocH .chzuH .a enmnoflm "AH .mooBoEom. mafiboxumz HmcoflumcuoucH .muooumo afiaflnm Eoum povmmcd "mumoom >Hucm we owe: can cofiwsnfluumflo mo Hoccmnu HmcoflumcuoucH cwoBumm cofluocwumwoll.fi wusmfih mmomoommm mmmeo _ \\...I 4! Has LA mgHsm>hsmow_ W szmzmoazaz l— mmzomzoo mMH:EMm ezmo< - - onmmom onmmom onmmom oszzmqu — wooqozmoma 11— c c , _ I , - \ k 7...\\\ /I\\\ ‘, fl ozHemomxm _\ n F meoooomm 1— wmezsoo onmmom smezm mo ago: smezsoo mzom mm>HB¢2mMBA¢ ZOHBDmHmBmHQ ho AMZZMBZDOU TABLE 1. 11 Three Major Taxonomies of Modes of Foreign Market Involvement S T U D Y Mode of Operations or Entry Mason, Miller, We1ge1 Root (1982) Cateora (1983) (1975) 1. Export 1. Export Entry Modes 1. Export Indirect 2. License, technical Direct Agent/ 2. Licensing aid Distributor Management contract Direct branch/ 3. Joint Subsidiary Venture 3. Joint venture with Other minority interest 4. Manufactur- 2. Contractual Entry Modes ing 4. Joint venture with Licensing majority interest Franchising 5. Management Technical agreement Contracts 5. Wholly owned Service contracts subsidiary Management contracts Construction/turnkey Contract manufacture Coproduction agreement Other 3. Investment Entry Modes Sole Venture: new establishment Sole Venture: acquisi- tion Joint Venture; new establishment Source: R. H. Mason, R. Miller, and R.HD. Weigel. (1975). The Economics of International Business (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Franklin Root. (1982). Foreign Market Entry Strategies Amacon. Philip Cateoria. (1983). International Marketing. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc. 12 major classifications. Export entry mode probably is the only distinguishable mode since the company's final or intermediate product is nmnufactured outside the target country and subsequently transferred to it. Investments involves some percentage of ownership by an international company of manufacturing plants in the target country. Mason, Miller & Weigel (1975) have argued that intermediate modes such as licensing could be considered a form of exporting i.e. "export of know-how."(p225) Also a joint venture agreement could be termed investment if the foreign firm owns a high equity share. Thus although these modes are conceptually different, they provide measurement difficulties. We shall now turn our attention to defining political risk. DEFINING POLITICAL RISK This study defines political risk as the "perception of international business executives that host governments will take actions that will affect the firms' profit, earnings potential or competitive, position in that market." That perception is based on sources of information concerning the host environment. Information can be obtained from internal or external sources. The concept of risk implies uncertainty about the outcome of an event, which is a function of the interaction of variables affecting the event. Most 13 authors in defining political risk focus on the aspect of the environment which interests them. Political risk has thus been equated to political instability, non-business risks and expropriation. What follows is a discussion of the current vieWpoints on political risk, political instability, political events, etc. Lee Nehrt's study on the political climate for private investment views the investment climate as a composite of economic, social, administrative, and political factors.7 The political climate encompasses risks of nationalization or expropriation. Root (1968) appropriately' defines political risk as those "beyond normal business risks that are generated by the attitudes, policies and overt behavior of host governments and other local power centers such as rival political parties, labor unions, and nationalist groups."(p.72) Cracco (1972) defined political risk as the "subjective probability that certain political decisions will be taken (or certain political events will occur) which will perceptibly change the present business environment."(p.6) The implication of this definition is that political risk can lead to favorable and unfavorable outcomes. As Kobrin (1978) put it "one can only say that political events may affect the firm: whether they do so is a function of both environmental conditions and industry and firm specific factors. A coup for example 14 may place a radical socialist government in power which expropriates all foreign-owned firms (as in Ethiopia); or it may result in a conservative government which actually returns expropriated property (as in Chile in 1973) or may simply replace governing elites without affecting foreign investors at all."(p.114) Boddewyn and Cracco (1972) say that the strategy used in multinational markets is dependent on national policy and functional areas within the organization, a viewpoint not shared by Kobrin. The conclusion can only be that the consequences of any political risk for the foreign investor depends upon its nature, the conditions under which it occurs and the characteristics of the specific investment in question. (Kobrin, 1976:p.69) Political Instability Whether political instability is equated to political risk depends upon a number of considerations. Theoretically political instability does not equate political risk. Thus Kobrin (1978) claims that many, perhaps most, attempts to control foreign investment are motivated by economic factors. However a closer evaluation of management views of political risk points to the fact they tend to equate the occurrence of specific events with political instability and 15 consequently political risk. This leads to the issue of managerial assessment and evaluation of the political environment. MANAGEMENT VIEWS Managers have consistently rated political instability and political risk as one of the major influences on the foreign investment decision. Further, managers have been observed: 1) to consider political instability or political risk, typically loosely defined, 2) to be an important factor in the foreign investment decision, 3) and they seldom do any rigorous and systematic assessment and evaluation of the political environment. Most analysis is superficial and subjective, not integrated formally into the decision-making process so they assume instability and risk to be one and the same, and 4) to rely primarily on internal sources for environmental information. When. they look for outside data they are most likely to go to their banks or the general business media. Cracco (1972) added to these conclusions by stating that "at the organizational level, headquarters have a more conceptual, principle oriented view of political risk, while the subsidiary views it more from an operational vantage point."(p.145) In other words, headquarter's perception of the risk of certain 16 types of political events is higher than the perception of indigenous executives. He further determined that the perception of political risk varies by nationality. The heart of political risk seems to depend on events which culminate in these major business obstacles. When an unfavorable consequence such as expropriation occurs, it is too late to react. Political risk studies have focused on sources of political influence and on the channeling institutions which. translate influence into decisions. Cracco (1972) has attributed the sources of political influence to three factors: ideological, social, and economic. In his conceptual framework (Table 2) these influences are channeled through institutions such as government and national legislatures to influence the business environment. The business environment in turn affects different firm's functional areas such as marketing, financial, management and production. The relationship between political risk and political instability could depend on whether the analyst seeks a reactive or proactive stance (offensive or defensive strategies). A proactive stance focuses on events that have the probability of resulting in potentially unfavorable consequences to business. A proactive stance equates political risk with political instability. A reactive stance on the other hand focuses 17 TABLE 2.--Conceptual Framework of the Political Process Sources of Institutions Types of Firm's Political Channeling influence Dependent Influences Political on Variables Influence BUSiPeSS Political Environment Structure 1. Ideological Marketing Variables Socialism _*National '_‘ '—_fil. Price Communism *fiLegislature k“ R-—-2. Product Nationalism (Legislative 3. Promotion Capitalism body) 4. P. Distribution 5. Environment 2. Social Government Institutional (Executive Financial V Groups body) Regulate 4 Army 1. Capital Structu Church 2. Remittance Bureaucracy _* Agencies h* policy ‘ . . . PF' (adminis- n-iMaintain 3. Investment Non1nst1tut1onal tration) P011CY Groups 4. Environment Middle Class 5. Accounting Elites Legal 6. Taxation Peasants Legislature . (regional Mold Management V 3. Economic body GNP/capital level City 1. Foreign pers. Balance of government} policy payments ..J _4 2. Local pers. GNP Growth Rate ,_J r— policy Unemployment 3. Labor level legislation 4. Taxation Prodgction V 1. Inputs 2. Plant layout 3. Machinery 4. Prod. design Source: Etienne Cracco. (1972). "The Nature and Perception of Political Risk for the International Corporation: An Exploratory Analysis with Special Reference to Brazil." Unpublishied Ph.D. Dissertation, Michigan State University. 18 on outcomes due to changes in the political process, such as expropriation. Under such posture political risk is not equated to political instability. Robock (1971) has suggested that the decision maker, in order to anticipate changes in the business environment, should recognize the evolutionary path along which changes are occurring, identify the principal motivating forces behind the change and make judgments as to timing. SIGNIFICANCE OF THE STUDY Firms that decide to seek profits and competitive advantage by entering foreign markets are faced. with political as well as normal business risks. Normal business risks address issues such as, will consumers buy the products, What are the effects of marketing programs, What 'will be the competitive response, etc.‘ Root (1968) has suggested three responses to political risk by firms he surveyed. The three responses are avoidance, adaptation and risk transfer. (p.73) U.S. businesses through the decade of the 1980's have been facing increasing global competition from emerging industrialized nations such as Japan, Korea, Taiwan, Brazil (to mention a few) and cannot afford to completely avoid rather than adapt in foreign markets where political risks are high. As Shapiro (1981) put 19 it: "The real issue is the degree of political risk a company is willing to tolerate and the return required to bear it. A policy of staying away from countries considered to be politically unstable ignores the potentially’ high returns available and the extent to which a firm can control these risks."(p.64) Firms can 'avoid' a market before involvement , but once it commits itself it has to 'adapt' to changes in political risk. This study suggests that the common mode of adaptation is via mode of operations. As risk increases, firms can firms would opt for licensing, joint venture or exporting strategies rather' than FDI. The substitutability of exporting for investment is used to test the adaptation strategy of U.S. manufacturing firms. The connection between risk resulting form political influences and investment has significance for international executives. The consequences of political risk can be substantial. It could range from. mild inconvenience to confiscation and violence. What follows is a delineation of the theoretical and practical contributions of this study. THEORETICAL CONTRIBUTION First, this study would help resolve some of the contradiction in findings8 between survey studies and cross-country studies.9 Also by looking at the 20 relationship of political risk to modes of operation from a strategic choice decision process and using the same methodology as the cross-country studies, some of the interesting findings of cross-country studies can be explained. This conceptual approach in itself is unique to this area of study. Secondly, this study contributes to the understanding of the role of political risk in the strategic choice decision of mode of operation when compared to market size and market growth rate (both significant influencers on the decision to invest). While international executives of multinational firms consider political risk before entering into foreign markets, the role of political risk has not been shown as influencing the choice of mode of operations after entry. The contention of the author is that political risk plays a significant role in the strategic choice decision of mode of operations. The survey studies have indeed shown that political risk is a major consideration in the choice of nations to invest in. The author further suggests that political risk results in adaptation policies through modes of operations in that nation rather than complete avoidance. Thirdly, the consideration of modes of operation as an incremental process Ihas for' a long time. been the 10 dominant approach or conceptualization. Following the 21 works of Adam Smith, Bertil Orlin and subsequent economists and marketers, the multinational firm is seen as going through a gradual and incremental process in internationalization, ‘Very little attention ihas been paid to the fact that mode of operation are and could be dynamic strategies or actively pursued alternatives. This study therefore tries to show that multinationals have for a long time used these modes of operations as strategies to access their chosen foreign markets. This suggests a need to reconsider mode of operation as active alternatives rather than as passive incremental processes. Finally, this study provides a comprehensive review of current literature on political risk and mode of operations. PRACTICAL CONTRIBUTION First, the role of political risk in the mode of operation decision affects a host of business decisions relating to the following areas: 1) intermediaries used 2) production levels 3) horizontal and vertical integration 4) desired locus of control So the findings will be relevant to multinational firms planning. ‘ ~ .- M '22 Secondly this study has practical implications for public policy makers. It suggests policies to pursue to attract investment and achieve economic objectives. The success of such policies may depend on the political risk in that nation as perceived by international investors. LIMITATIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH DIRECTION There are a number of limitations of the research. First, the focus of the study is on mode of "operation rather thanq initial involvement -decision. Mode of operations refers to initial involvement as well as expansion decision. Using FDI as an example, mode of operations ‘will include new investments, reinvestments and divestments. Secondly, conclusions from the study is limited to the actions of U.S. manufacturing firms at the aggregate rather than for select industries or individual firms. Further research direction involves investigating the same phenomena for Canadian firms, Japanese firms, etc. Inclusion of intermediate modes of operations such as joint ventures, licensing (if measurable) can add significant insights to the strategic choice process. The behavior of Third World multinationals needs to be researched before overall theory relating to this decision process can be developed. This study begins that process of theory building in this area. 23 Thirdly, a sophisticated model would have to include firm specific and country specific variables that would affect mode of operations choice decision process. This model will not follow the current popular approach in theory' development (the eclectic approach courtesy of John Dunning).11 The author does not deny that the mode of operations has to be a function of country specific and firm specific variables - especially firm size. However, available data suggest that 80% of exports and definitely a greater percentage for FDI is carried out by large firms - U.S. multinationals. Therefore adjustments using mode of operations may be a phenomena of large firms. Finally, the conclusions are only as good as the secondary data used. Errors in collection and reporting data could bias the conclusions (See appendix A). ORGANIZATION OF THE STUDY In Chapter I, the first task is to fully develop the conceptual framework by bringing together the dependent and independent variables. Therefore the language of the research will be clarified by discussing the key concepts. Chapter II reviews the relevant empirical research from the perspective of different schools of thought. Its 24 objective is to show how the major variables of the research are derived. Chapter III discusses the research design, hypothesis, operationalization. of the ‘variables and. data analysis procedure. Chapter IV reports the results of all lag models tested. Chapter V is a discussion of the results and conclusions. Finally in Chapter VI, the implications of the findings for theory and policy are discussed. Future research direction is also outlined. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 'Incremental School The theoretical framework can be built around two streams of research. The first school of thought focuses on initial involvement in foreign markets. Conceptualization of the internationalization process can be traced back to economic theory. Bertil Ohlin (1933) in his works for instance postulated that fbreign trade was only a special case of domestic trade. Exporting has been identified as the first mode of operations and its adoption is said to be passive and gradual. This school is adequately represented by the 25 research works of Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul, Finn, Olson and Welch (1978); and Bilkey and Tesar (1978). Johanson & Wiedersheim-Paul (1975), who traced the complete internationalization process for Atlas-Copco, Facit Volvo, and Sandik (all Swedish firms), had observed that each stage in the process represented successively larger commitment of resources. They concluded that the pattern was a gradual internationalization, rather than large spectacular investments. Wiedersheim-Paul, Finn, Oslon & Welch (1979) later studied small firms in Australia and found that they tended to expand interstate before their first export sale. Bilkey and Tesar (1977) proposed a stage model for examining export behavior. The International Product Life Cycle (IPLC) which was developed by Wells (1966) and R. Vernon (1966) focused on innovation/adoption process in explaining export movement to foreign markets. The theory acknowledges that at the maturity stage, foreign production starts, however production in foreign markets is by indigenous investors rather than by foreign investors. Root (1982) has argued that a company will gradually change its entry mode decision in a fairly predictable fashion. Increasingly, it will choose entry modes that provide control over foreign marketing operations. But to gain greater control, the company 26 will have to commit more resources to foreign markets and thereby assume greater market and political risks. Two conclusions can be derived from these studies: 1) Export marketing is usually considered to be a first step in the process of internationalization. (Cavusgil & Nevin, 1980). Root (1982) attributes this to the desire to gain experience; "the general belief is that prior involvement in foreign markets in the form of exporting increases experience and consequently reduces uncertainty."(p.90) But this may prove to be fallacious since political risks can, and does result in substantial losses even in the face of accumulated experience. Exporting experience may not cut down on certain types of risks such as expropriation. A firm such as Shell (Nig) Ltd. with large accumulated experience is still vulnerable to political risks unless that firm assumes such a position of size and importance to its host economy and consequently becomes untouchable. Maclayton, Smith & Hair (1980) also did not substantiate the experience explanation. 2) The initial involvement decision in international marketing is conceived as a gradual and sequential process. The gradual process is thought to be the consequence of greater uncertainty, higher cost of gathering information, and the lack of experiential knowledge in international marketing activities. 27 Further, two implications can be drawn from these conclusions: 1) The concern for risk of exporting exhibited by the firms studied can be extended to other modes of operation. At the very least, the same level of perceived risk in foreign market operations will be shown for the other modes of operation. If firms are concerned about riSk in exporting, greater concern will exist for other modes that involve more resource commitment. The significance of risk in foreign markets involvement is thus emphasized. 2) The "gradual and sequential" process can be extended to other modes of operation. In other words, licensing, joint ventures and FDI will similarly follow in a gradual and sequential manner. If that is the case the modes of entry substitute rather than complement each other. This leads us to the question of substitutability or complementarity of exports for FDI and the views of the second school of thought. Strategic School The second school of thought sees entry or expansion into foreign markets as a strategy or dynamic alternative. Studies under this school of thought have looked at two dimensions. The first sees the choice of modes of operations as a function of firm specific 28 decision variables (see Grosse, 1985) while the others see the decision choice depending on country specific variables. (see Goodnow and Hansz, 1972) U.S. manufacturing firms in trying to access foreign markets have a choice among adaptation strategies. One mode or a combination of modes can be chosen. The choice depends on several factors. Neilson (1980) says that the decision is based on a firm's differential advantages or resource mix. Goodnow and Hansz (1972) say that the mode of operation decision depends on environmental factors. Environmental factors such as market opportunity, economic development and performance, political stability, cultural unity, legal barriers, physiographic barriers and geocultural distance determined the environmental attractiveness of a fereign market and invariably the mode of entry strategy that is used. Grosse (1985) tried to develop an imperfect competition theory of the MNE. He concluded that MNE decision makers can consider four alternatives for serving national markets which lead to optimal decisions on production level, internal and external pricing, and horizontal and vertical integration under 'various conditions. No study to date has investigated the relationship between political risk and the mode of 29 operation despite overwhelming evidence that political risk. is a major consideration in mode of operations choice decisions in foreign markets. Root (1968) in discussing a firms' adaptation policies to political risk notes joint venture as a means of adaptation to political risk. Root, suggesting joint venture as a mode of adaptation implies that a less risky mode is used in situations of high political risk. This implies that firms strategically adjust in politically unstable environments using mode of operations. Horst (1974) investigated the issue of complementarity or substitutability of exports for FDI. This topic had. been previously analyzed by empirical researchers but emphasis was related to the policy question of the impact of multinational firms on the balance of payments. Horst applied regression analysis to twenty-three manufacturing industries and eight countries and the relationship in Figure 3 was observed. As long as foreign subsidiary net sales as a percentage of domestic shipments were small, an increase in sales was accompanied by a rise in U.S. exports. Also Lipsey & weiss (1976) study which investigated the same issue produced mixed results. They examined the relationship between the exports and FDI of the U.S. and thirteen other major exporting countries. Using regression analysis, they found that for U.S. 30 TM(%) .7 Ran e o ‘ g f Range of substitutability complementarity .----------- _A v v r 1 T I 1 U I 1 l I I I ' 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11121314 15 PM(%) Figure 3.--Re1ationship Between U.S. Manufacturing Exports and FDI SOURCE: T. Horst, "American Exports and Foreign Direct Investment," Harvard Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper 362. NOTE: TM = Estimated relationship between US exports as a percentage of domestic shipment PM = Subsidiary net sales as a %age of domestic net sales. 31 manufacturing affiliates their level of activity was positively related to U.S. exports. Also, U.S. manufacturing affiliate activity was negatively related to exports by the thirteen other countries. Although results seem to be mixed, Horst (1974) concludes that the choice between exporting and overseas production depends on whether savings from exporting are greater or less than the costs of control and coordination of foreign production. However correlation of U.S. exports and FDI to a particular foreign market using macro data may not be enough to suggest that a firm's exports and FDI to a market are complementary. David Aaker (1984) has suggested that exporting would be a logical choice when "heavy commitment is inadvisable because of political risks or because the market is either not sufficiently attractive or its prospects uncertain."(p.285) The question is, does political risk however measured constitute a significant influence on corporate mode of operations strategy or is it a consideration among many as suggested by the Goodnow and Hansz (1972) study and by Maclayton, Smith and Hair (1980) studies. If political risk affects foreign direct investment, then it should also have some effect on other modes if they are alternatives. One might argue that foreign governments are dictating the mode of operation of firms and therefore, 32 that, it really isn't a decision variable of the firm. Examples of Brazil, Mexico and Nigeria with local content laws come to mind. It is important to note that these countries are trying to build an economic base by attracting investment. The success of such policies is ix: doubt. or' can. be ‘jeopardized. if political risk is prevalent in that market. This study tests the effect of political risk on exporting and investment. The findings will help determine why some of the host government policies of encouraging/discouraging investments or exports maybe offset by political instability. COST BASED MODELS Buckley and Casson (1981) were concerned with timing of entry and developed a cost based model. The authors state that fixed production costs for exporting is negligible while variable costs are almost certain to be high. The converse is true for FDI (low variable costs and high fixed costs). Their rationale is that exporting, licensing, and FDI are in ascending order of fixed costs and decreasing order of variable costs. The relationship is diagramed as in Figure 4. The illustration shows that as a nmrket grows, it may be efficient to switch directly from exporting to FDI and forego the use of licensing. If the potential size of the market is small then the firm will export 33 Cost Exporting Licensing I I I I I I I I I I I +— Exporting -—.fl— FDI —."" - ' ‘r Quantity Switch Figure 4.--Mode of Operation as a Function of Fixed and Variable Costs of Operation. SOURCE: Adapted from,P. Buckley and M. Casson, The Future of the Multinational Entegprise (London: MacMillan, 1976). 34 indefinitely. If the potential market is only of moderate size, the firm may switch from exporting to licensing, but not from licensing to FDI. Alternatively, if the market is large to begin with, the firm may omit the exporting stage and begin with licensing: if the market is very large it may even commence servicing with FDI. Hazard (1977) was concerned with location decisions of firms. According to his model a firm will locate in a foreign market if the costs of production abroad are less than the costs of production at home plus the transportation costs to the foreign market. He utilized the automobile industry to illustrate how foreign nations have restricted United States exports to their markets making FDI necessary to preserve market access and tending to lower foreign production costs to the point that they were able to export to the U.S. market. In another cost related explanation, Horst (1974b) explained that the choice between exporting and overseas production depends on whether savings from overseas production is greater or less than the costs of control and coordination. Figure 5 shows the relationship. The shaded portion represents the savings from overseas production. 35 PRICE MARGINAL REVENUE FROM FOREIGN SALES FOREIGN DEMAND CURVE /// Marginal COSt gggéa7’ cthmgnming Mamfinalcnst ofcwenflms ‘\\\\\\\\\ Exbdmnion Quantity Figure 5.--Exporting and Overseas Production as a Function of Foreign Demand. SOURCE: T. Horst, “The Theory of the Firm" Chapter 2 in J. H. Dunning, ed., Economic Analysis and the Multinational Enterprise (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1974b):31-46. 36 BUSINESS REACTION TO POLITICAL RISK There have been conceptual and empirical articles detailing business reaction to political risk. Unfortunately there isn't universal agreement on business reaction to political risk. This section discusses those responses. Table 3 provides a comparison of the studies. Root (1968) surveyed (by mail) and interviewed (in person) top executives of companies listed in the Fortune Directory of the 500 largest industrial corporations. Three major responses to political risk were identified: 1) Avoidance. The response pattern denotes staying out of foreign market without respect to the modes of operation. Under such circumstances the decision not to invest implies that perceived opportunities are more than offset by perceived political risk costs. In determining how management weighs opportunities and risk factors the author attributed it to the aggressiveness or passiveness of the management. An aggressive management will be reluctant to refrain from investing in high political risk markets while a passive management will not. A defensive management might opt to exploit the new opportunity by relying on direct exports or licensing. 2) Adaptation. This policy consists of a range of dynamic alternative policies encompassing one or :more aspects of the company's operation abroad. Adaptation could be passive (minimal) or active. Active adaptation 13'7 .ooocououoa uo soda com. .ouo- uuagm .. use usauflom .n ocasnnou "unquaaom .« ucuauuo>:« Hufiwcut .d cauuouncot .n uuuoaonoxouu Macon weano~v>on .v oduuu uwuocon \uuoo 0:» ocamcosu .n noduouaawnoa uauoaa snou-uuonm .m unsuno>uo Quandam .n codunuoaooo .« coup-acoaucou .n Sauna haunt £5533: oval >uucu .n 856392 . H ucuacouaoco as» acquaauoooz .n 005.32; . a oucucwo>£ .n unasnnoa aoca«au- ocean no acol850I I undouaomli >uouuuu. anaconousn «Icons: Que-Io can unocducw uo coauQOOH any ocaaflouucoouu muououu- Rhonuoc .ooun ~.ucnou huubauuo uofiuauvuu Ins- osu ocuuouu¢lu nouuouauu- have. can acaIAUII oooueauoau unoluooacu «0 coal: 00 oOHuaGOI .n oo o: .n 00 .H nounsoua load .n :o«uaunaa« .A 006.040»‘ .n snug» ououon coma Ouaouoxo mama oudnosm who" Hounuo¢ .uha~_ xoonou coma cu scum «coauuuoa o» ecuuoaloz gonad-9a so couvaum Mann: «0 eouuudnl90ll.n Hausa 38 seeks. to ensure ‘the long-run survival of ‘the foreign enterprise by making it an essential element of the national economy in the eyes of the host government officials and other political persons. Specific policies to minimize political risk include staffing foreign operations with local managers and workers, using local suppliers and participating in joint ventures. 3) Risk Transfer. Companies seek to transfer risks to third parties. True risk transfer does not alter risk exposure: it merely shifts the incidence of loss. Favorite third parties that assume these risks are private insurance companies and government agencies/programs such as AID. Robock's (1971) conceptualization had three choices - go, modified go, and no go. According to Robock "the international enterprise is not helpless in the face of political risk."(p.18) Robock's risk minimization strategy or 'modified 90' strategy are as outlined below: 1) the use of investment guarantees 2) timing and entry strategy 3) altering the subsidiary's activity 4) international production network strategy 5) controlling the location of intangible assets 6) local purchasing strategy 7) sourcing and movement of funds 8) direct lobbying 39 Antoine W. Van Agtmael (1976), a bank executive, relied on past experience and probably contacts with businessmen. to decry their lack. of sophistication in political risk analysis. He suggested a framework to systematically analyze political stability.12 Van Agtmael's strategies of confrontation or cooperation is for firms faced. with. political risk: in. their' foreign markets. The determination of the policy to pursue will depend on "candid evaluation of one's bargaining position."(p.27) Shapiro (1981) did not use any empirical data to support his framework. He was concerned about findings that suggested that managers are not involved in any systematic analysis of political risk. So his approach was to discuss policy options available to international decision makers after determining that a target market represents considerable political risk, Shapiro thus suggests "four separate, though not necessarily mutually exclusive"(p.64) policies. .A policy of avoidance simply implies staying away from the market in question. But Shapiro argues thus: "The real issue is the degree of political risk a company is willing to tolerate and the return required to bear it. A policy of staying away from countries considered to be politically unstable ignores the potentially high returns available and the extent to which a firm can control these risks."(p.65) 40 .A policy of Insurance involves insuring assets in politically risky areas. Coverage provided by U.S. government through the Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC) is typical. Shapiro states that this approach is inadequate since the economic value of its future cash flows is not covered, only the investment in assets is covered by insurance. Negotiating the environment involves 'concession agreements' prior to undertaking the investment. This policy’ however is not reliable since neW’ governments could repudiate such agreements. Finally, a policy of structuring the investment involves adjusting; 1) corporate operating policies in the areas of production, logistics, export, and technology transfer, and 2) its financial policies. After the multinational has invested in a project its ability to influence its susceptibility to political risk is greatly diminished but not ended. Policies available to the firm under such circumstances - planned divestiture, short-term profit maximization, changing the benefit/cost ratio of expropriation, developing local stakeholders, and adaptation. Planned. divestiture implies phasing' out their ownership of foreign investments over a fixed time period by selling all or a majority of their equity interest to local investors. 41 Short-term profit maximization is manifest in such practices as "defining maintenance expenditures, cutting investment to the minimum necessary to sustain the desired level of production, curtailing' marketing expenditures, producing lower quality merchandise, setting higher prices, and eliminating training programs, cash generation maximized for the short-term."(p.66) Changing the benefit/cost ratio is manifest by such practices as establishing local research and development facilities, developing export markets for the affiliates output, training local workers and managers, expanding production facilities, and manufacturing a wider range of products locally as substitutes for imports. Developing local stakeholders involves incorporating individuals and groups who have a stake in the affiliates continued existence as a unit of the parent multinational. Adaptation policies involves "trying to earn profits on the firm's resources by entering into licensing and management agreements."(p.68) This section shows that firms have a wide range of reactions to political risk before and after they enter the foreign market. In a sense one can say that data for investments and exports applies to firms that have already entered the foreign markets. Data for firms that have avoided high risk foreign markets is not recorded. 42 How effective are these strategies? Beeman (1979) surveyed 132 firm-nation pairs in order to test six hypothesis and developed a paradigm to explain differences in effectiveness of risk reduction strategies. Executives believe that adaptation strategies have the greatest risk reduction effect. Dependency strategies have little or no effect. Hedging strategies increase risk. MODEL FOR MODE OF OPERATION ANALYSIS A firm's mode of entry could be by FDI (when political risk is low), but reduces FDI (i.e. reinvestments) as political risk increases. In ‘what appears to be a contradiction of his earlier position, Root (1982) suggests 'that. international. executives (are apt to consider political risk in a target country, such as general political instability or the threat of expropriation, they favor’ entry modes that limit the commitment of company resources. Conversely, low political risks encourage equity investment in a target country. Three major factors are encompassed in the model shown in Figure 6. Market Size and Growth Rate This is one variable that the survey studies and cross-country studies have universal agreement as to its MODEL ONE .————. 10w FDI mOd L._( igh MODEL TWO “low 1 — FDI mod .L__.. hi MODEL THREE { high —_l FDI mod Figure 6.--Alternative Models to be Tested. arg large ed MARKET med SIZE small small arg arge MARKET med med GROWTH RATE small small high high med POLITICAL med RISK low low high mod low high low 19W high EXPORTING EXPORTING EXPORTING 44 effect. Market size is definitely a variable that influences investment decisions. Indicators of market size were used by Aharoni (1966) and Goodnow & Hansz (1972) and. was identified as significant influencers. Basi (1963) surveyed international executives in an attempt to determine the criteria they use in deciding upon a foreign investment and found that the two most important factors in foreign market investment were political instability and market potential. Aharoni showed the same results through in-depth interviews with international personnel in thirty-eight firms. Bennett and Green (1972) recognizing the significance of market size and potential controlled for both variables in determining the effect of political instability on FDI. Market size is an important variable because sales volume helps achieve economies of scale. Also, Davidson (1980) says that FDI makes economic sense when volume exceeds a level at which the average cost of serving the market through exports exceeds the average cost of production within the market.The significance of' market size is evidenced (by its inclusion in studies of political instability and foreign. direct investment. (Green and Cunningham 1975; Kobrin 1976; Thunell 1977) Grosse (1985) in developing an imperfect competition theory of the MNE concluded that the choice between alternative modes of operation is "dependent upon the costs and 45 government policy constraints involved in each alternative, the size of the market, and changes over time."(p.74) The results are therefore impressively consistent that market size and potential are major determinants of entry into foreign markets. Although market size is not the only variable of interest, any model explaining modes of operations should include market size since it is a significant explanatory variable. The Mason, Miller & Weigel (1975) model (Figure 7) summarizes the factors affecting mode of operations. Political Risk There has been attempts at theory-building in political risk. The theorists have tried to look at factors that increase the risks of a market. Most have focused on the host government as the major actor and the MNC as the prime target. Boddewyn & Cracco (1971) have attributed an increase in political risk to national interest, national sovereignty, and national identity. Kobrin (1980) however refutes the assertion that forced divestment is simply a response to economic nationalism , reflecting national pride, an anti-foreign bias, or political opportunism. It is however incomplete to explain an increase in investment risk or "forced divestment" as Kobrin refers to it, to only firm specific 46 License Joint Joint Size technical venture venture Wholly-owned fin ' aid mgt. with with subsidiary I ’ u o o - mana- EXPORT contract minority majority gerial investment investment - techni~ ,///;' cal strengtfih and / int'l expe- ,I’II' rience 2:... / / / /' J/ Market size, level of develop- ment, availability of natural resources, permissiveness of the environment Figure 7. Firm and Foreign Market Specific Factors Determining Modes of Operation. SOURCE: Mason, Miller, and Weigel, The Economics of International Business (Toronto: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., ), p. 252. 47 factors. ILf his findings also are tenable then why is there more forced divestment in certain countries? Also given the three interrelated factors, if true, one would expect a vulnerable firm to experience the same level of forced divestment across all countries. Gurr's (1969) theory of relative deprivation points to a high level of national frustration as the key determinant of expropriations. The host government uses the IMNE as a scape-goat for the country's problems. Green (1974) tried to attribute political risk to political structures. His theses ‘was that political structures can predict radical political changes. Simon (1980) has used a composite model. According to Simon, the MNEs vulnerability is a function of it environments consisting of host country environment, home country' environment, international environment and. the global environment. Authors such as Bennett & Green (1972) and Nigh (1985) implicitly believe that political risk is a function of political instability and political events respectively - a view the author shares. Political instability has been identified as one form of political risk. A vital element of the environmental analysis is political instability. There are other types of political risk, but the political instability can arguably be the most significant. Political risk consists of political instability and 48 political events which are forms of political risks. The notion of political events as a determinant of political instability has been investigated by Brewer (1984). He looked at the association between specific governmental policy changes and other forms of political instability. His analysis focused on three types of governmental instability: personnel change, factional change, and systemic change. His findings showed moderately strong relationship between policy instability and factional change. The other two governmental instability variables were positively related to the instability of foreign exchange policies, but not statistically significant at the 0.05 level. Together, the forms of governmental instability are more strongly associated with political instability among industrial nations than among developing nations. This piece of research ties the knot between a relationship researchers have been interested in for so long - namely, can firms use political events to predict policy changes? Political instability also has been proven to influence international executives in their decision to invest albeit no systematic evaluation and analysis is done before commitment to invest. (Root 1968a; Root 1968b: Rummel & Heenan 1978) A Conference Board study of international executives cites political instability as the most frequently mentioned political obstacle. This 49 could be due to the fact that a nations' level of political instability affects the rate of return that investors expect to receive on their foreign ventures. In general, the greater the instability a nation exhibits, lower profits can be realized from manufacturing FDI. (Green & Smith, 1972) While Kobrin (1978) concludes that political instability is neither a necessary nor sufficient condition for political risk, Green & Korth (1974) succinctly put the relationship as such: "a vital element of the environmental analysis is the question of political instability .....instability is the most significant form of political risk."(p.23) Robock (1971) notes that political instability depending on how it is defined is a separate although related phenomenon from that of political risk. He says that political risk exists when; 1) discontinuities or radical changes occur in the business environment, 2) which are difficult to anticipate, and 3) which result from political fluctuations and disturbances.(p.7) It is probably due to Robock's definition that studies trying to measure political instability have used political events. His conceptual framework as shown in Table 4 suggests that consequences (expropriation, confiscation, etc.) result from sources (political events). 5(3 aocuaoo ownssaou s.u:oammomo< one coduou«u«ucoou .ONuo "Aymamsou .ncowuoouusmcu .nuOAu souu Amaconuom no huuomoum ou confide ocwuoouucoonsm >u0mazm taco moxou am noon coauocdsquonao mucoSOouoo one nucouucoo :« ocona>ou Honouoawcn uo nonoooum .munmwu manmuoczo uo Hoccomuom .moooo .Amucoexmm unououca .mocoo«>«o ..u.o. Hoaococau ”Boooouu uowucouu mo mmoq .ouo .mflnmuocao oouocm SHHMUOH .noaoHHoa ucoe>onEo .aoqunauouoouoso uosooua .mouonu uoxnofi uncowuoHuumou Hoseauouomo .ououomo 00 Eoooouu uo mmoH "sewuomcomeoo nu“: newuowumoumxm acquomcomsou woo Icuw3 muommm no mmoa acofiumomaucou cowaaonou «unwound uuommsn ou no uowaucoo oosuo oucw uouco ou mafiaaat mucoscuo>oo :uaouom 0mm 0:» no £09m .mowocoqo Hmucoacuo>oo no mucoacuo>oo coaouom .ouo .moauwuocaa .uuconmom .muoxuOI .nucoosum “unsouo one showed canoo oouwcomuocoz “Suucsoo uo oodnuso no canvas Bonn ocaxuoz nucoao>oa oaawuoov 2.2qm: cowuooaHoucoaowauomcoz museum coda :«mommo auoucoaewauom moaocomo mcwumuomo mua one Meson ca ucoscuo>oo oucoocomooca dooauaaom ocuocomfia one ucooom mmsoum unocwmsn HonoH no mumuouca oounob noouomao one amends Howoom AEmansEEoo .amaaoaoom .Bmaao:0aumcv mownmomoHazm auowuwaom ocwuodsoo woodwouomo unocwmom ooumuocoo on HocoeuocuoucH co mucosa—CH ' coo xmfim Hoowugom to mouse "muumuum swam Hobgugaoa 50%;: noaouaa mmsouu t xnwm ”coaufiaoa no manusom xuo3o5duh Hooumoucou t “Roam Hufiuwaom .v mqm<fi 51 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK In a sense this study tries to determine the variance explained by location-specific factors which are deemed essential in determining the mode of operation in a foreign country-market. My conceptual framework builds from the theoretical framework and literature review in the area of political risk analysis. It is partial, not complete since it omits firm/industry specific factors. The conclusions of the survey studies about the behavior of international executives are namely: 1) country-market entry decisions are not based on systematic evaluation of political risk, 2) executives rely on sources internal to the firm, and external sources such as the general news media. Cracco (1972) has indicated that there's a difference in the perception of headquarters executives and subsidiary executives. Based on these reports the executive forms a perception about each country-market and a decision as to the mode of entry is made in consideration of other factors such as market size and market growth rate. If the export mode is chosen, the firm then organizes itself for at least minimum control of marketing activities. The opposite analysis applies for FDI. In host nation markets where political risk is low, market size is high and market growth rate is high, investors can be expected 52 to commit as much resources as possible to maximize their presence in that market. The converse is true for exports. Exporting should be attracted to markets with high risk, low market size, low nmrket growth rate. The framework in Figure 8 illustrate the sources of information used, decision variables and strategic action. It was diagramed based on the theoretical and empirical studies discussed earlier. NOTES 1. See Cavusgil, S.T. and J.R. Nevin (1980), "A conceptualization of the initial involvement in International Marketing", Theoretical Developments in Marketing, C.W. Lamb and P.M. Dunne, eds., (Chicago: American Marketing Association), 68-71, for a summary of the studies and their findings. 2. See Glossary of terms (p.226) for definitions of these terms. 3. All references will be listed in LIST OF REFERENCES on page 257. Only the authors, & date of publication and page numbers (if quotation) will be used in the text to avoid excessive repetition of common bibliographical information necessitated by extensive basic referencing of basic documents in separate chapter. Chapter footnotes, in turn, will be confined to explanatory documentation rather than bibliographic references. 4. Goodnow and Hansz (1980) use the term environmental attractiveness or hot to mean country-markets that have a high degree of political stability, ample market opportunities, high level of economic development and performance, cultural unity, limited legal barriers, low physiological barriers etc. Environmentally unattractive or cold countries have high political instability, few market opportunities, low economic development, cultural disunity, numerous legal barriers, high physiological barriers etc. 53 SOURCES or DECISION ACTION INFORMATION VARIABLES EXPORT IF' INTERNAL E: i: EggH ex Past 1 MGR IS LOW IDGERUEKE IUXETHJJSRHHFFCFACKXB 1 Perception of PoliticaI Risk EXTEENAL —->—Market Size & GrOWth 1 w Rate INVEST IF: MAGAZIEHSPZEEESRS Competition PR IS LOW Cost MS IS HIGH Other Environmental MGR IS HIGH Factors FIRM SPECIFIC FACTORS Firm size R&D Intensity Advertising Intensity Mgt. Percpetions Figure 8.--Conceptual Framework of the Effect of Political Risk on Modes of Operations. 54 5. Survev of Current Business,U.S. Department of Commerce (Washington D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office, 1980. 6. Ibid p. 20 7. Nehrt, L.C. (1980), The Political Environment for Foreign Investment,(New York: Praeger Publishers.) 8. Studies using survey methods have concluded that political risk is a major consideration in foreign market investment, while studies using cross-country sample conclude that political risk does not influence foreign investment. 9. See 'Glossary of terms', (p. 226) for explanation. 10. The study of theory in international trade usually starts with issues such as classical, neoclassical and neofactor to explain why nations trade. Theorists interested in firm behavior have subsequently concentrated on exporting first, then licensing, then joint ventures etc. in that order. 11. See Dunning,J.H. (1981), International Production and the Multinational Enterprise, (London: george Allen & Irwin) 12. This framework was originally published in "Country Risk Analysis for Medium Lending, by Antoine W. Van Agtmael. CHAPTER II LITERATURE REVIEW A difficult task facing a researcher is how to organize the conceptual and empirical studies which have made positive contributions in his area of interest. In this case however there has been paucity of research on the relationship in question. While many studies have dealt with the issue of political risk and others have focused on each of the modes of operation, few studies have tried to relate the two. In fact, only one empirical study has focused on political risk and mode of involvement. It is therefore necessary to explain the procedure to be used to organize the 'outside' literature. Initially, the studies belonging to the incremental school will be reviewed. Then, those studies that view modes of operations as strategies will be reviewed. Within each school of thought, an attempt has been made to classify studies according to the sampling frame used i.e. cross-country and cross-firm. Cross-country studies have typically used secondary sources and macro measures of the variables studied. Their sampling frame is usually countries, hence the name cross-country. Secondly, the 55 56 cross—firm studies will be reviewed. Cross-firm studies typically use survey methods (primary data) to interview a sample of firms. They can be defined as micro level studies. So the typology is divided into "SCHOOL OF THOUGHT-SAMPLING FRAME USED." The schema for the literature review is as in Figure 9. The basic objectives of this chapter are three-fold: 1) To show how research has progressed, 2) To identify basic ideas and the state of knowledge, 3) To show where concepts, variables and propositions to be measured are coming from. The author seeks to be selective rather than exhaustive. Therefore, in addition to developing a taxonomy of studies some criteria has to be used to eliminate non- essential studies. The criteria to be used are as follows: 1) Only empirical studies will be included. Empirical studies are those that rely on or are based solely on experiment and observation rather than pure theory or speculation. Also these studies must have significant findings. 2) Major studies that have considered some aspect of political risk; for example, political instability, will be referred to although some of the 57 moflosum Euflmlmmouu AOOmUm UHOflBdMBm .Bofl>om ousvmuwuflq mo HmoHOI|.m madman mowosum moaosum hupcooo Euflmnmmouu Immouo AOOEUm AdfizmzmmUZH a mmoeammqu-moneo>uom moanwflum> ooumHou uoxuma .muommcouu .ooxo Hmaomom mow mbmfl omen< a poem mama >uoocooom How .Hmwucmpom uoxnoE .ouflm uoxumz mom puma mung Haocona mucofio>ao>cfl uuomxo mama whoocooom .m.D uoflua .Hom .HMflucouom umxumE .ONfim umxumz no» mhma .cflunox mama Smoocooom Ham .Hmwucouom poxuoe .mnam uoxumz mow mumH Eosmcwccou a comma coaumuucoocoo muucm no» mumfi uoxoonuoxOASM mama Sumocooom Ham «0 >uaafioouamoum no» whoa .nuflsm a comma mama Snoocooom :ofluoeum> HmGOAqou .ucoEQOHo>oo mo Ho>oa .Hmflucouom poxumz .Ham mm» mhmH .cmouo ocm uuoccom >o>usm no» mood .uoom Hmsumoocoo oz moma .com:floom mama Sumocooow open mmeumu .ONHm uoxuoz oz momH .Hosmz w ocmauommom >m>nsm Ham mow mama .Rmmm Hmzuomocoo Ham mow momH .socmMmae >m>usm +Hom coma .acoumna >m>nsm +Hom mama .moHox >o>usm +Ham homfl .QOflz cmwmoo noumomom oouoowmcoo moafiofiumfi MOnmz Txmfim oumo ocm MOSHE i .mocaocwm Hflone ocm oonoowmcou moaomflum> Home: mcwsogm mmflosum xmfim HMOfiuflHomnHom mo mumfifismlll.o wands 61 variance explained by market size and potential and for a linear relationship between FDI and political event data. His first conclusion was that a reasonable percentage of the variance in the flow of manufacturing FDI is explained by market related variables. A second conclusion was that no significant relationship is apparent between flows of FDI and any of the indicators of political instability. The author used previous export involvement as a measure of market familiarity to explain an incremental 10% of variance for all countries and 11% for LDCs only. Kobrin's study has limitations. As the author admitted, "there are limits on.IhOW’ one can. take the results: any conclusions must be viewed as tentative"(p.37), due to the cross sectional design used to investigate what is obviously a longitudinal phenomena. Kobrin's article is suggestive that exports is a 'step' in the ultimate decision to invest in a foreign country. He therefore would argue that modes of operation are an incremental process, and ultimate success with export marketing along with market related variables, not. political risk, determines the foreign direct investment decision. His findings with respect to political risk agree with that of Bennett & Green (1972).2 62 Kobrin (1978)3 looked at a different angle of political risk. This time he was interested in the relationship between political events and the investment climate. Prior to his study, other research had equated perceived instability’ with. a poor investment climate. Kobrin used statistical analysis of forty-eight countries, all of whom had received FDI of at least one million dollars as of year end 1967. His results showed market size, and growth, previous export involvement and the regional dummies for Latin America and Europe are significant at the .05 level with signs as expected. Kobrin sought to show the relationship between political instability and political risk. ID1 his model he only focused on anti-regime violence which was fOund to be significant. In his summary he concluded that the relationship between conflict and flows of manufacturing FDI is complex and indirect. It depends on both the nature of the conflict and the socio-economic conditions under which it occurs. Kobrin could have been influenced by' Robockls statement that "political instability depending on how it is defined is a separate although related phenomena from political risk."(Robock, 1971 p.8) The author cites examples of political instability in countries that did not necessarily result in increased political risk. He also notes that political risk is not "a homogeneous phenomena: vulnerability is clearly industry, firm and even project specific." (p. 114) However the issue really is how correlated are political instability and political risk rather than the use of isolated examples to support a position. Thus Brewer (1984) tested for and showed a fairly strong relationship between political events and policy changes. This dissertation deals with political risk (as perceived by investors) and its effect on modes of operations decisions. Kobrin however admits that managers equate political instability and political risk. (Kobrin 1980, p. 74) The econometrics studies 'which. belong' to the incremental school are limited. The incremental-cross firm studies will be discussed next. Cross-firm studies As mentioned earlier, cross-firm studies have used survey method (questionnaires or personal interviews) to investigate :modes of operation. Their conclusion. or position is usually that modes of entry or operations are incremental rather than dynamic alternatives. What follows is further explanation of their contributions. 64 Export Marketing Studies. Initial export studies (prior to 1978) have tried to discover types of firms engaged in exports and why. More recent research has focused on the process of developing an exporting strategy. Specifically current research has sought to answer the following questions: 1) How did a firm arrive at the decision to export? 2) Having decided on export as a strategy, how did a firm implement its decision? 3) What factors caused a firm to move from non-exporting to the initial stages of exporting, and beyond? 4) Can a theory of exporting be developed? Two studies [Snavely, Weiner, Ulrich & Enright (1964) and Cevusgil (1976)]4 have identified some distinctive characteristics of currently exporting firms. These characteristics are: 1) Managers should have favorable expectations regarding the effect of that activity on firms growth, market development and profits, 2) Managers who have systematically planned and executed the export activity, 3) Firms have annual sales of $1,000,000 or more, 4) Firm has unique product or distinctive competitive advantage and have sole rights or patents. These studies have also identified two key characteristics that affect a firm's involvement in 65 export; managers characteristics and firm characteristics (size and unique products). Home country specific factors usually have not been included as explanatory variables. Other studies have added richness to the model by considering change agents. Change agents help stimulate export development, but do not necessarily result in the firms adoption of exporting. Change agents can be external or internal. External change stimuli to the decision whether to export include banks, industrial associations, government agencies, and other firms. (Johanson & Weidersheim 1975)5 Vesper (1979)6 has identified other external change agents. These are unsolicited overseas orders, attractive foreign markets and availability of patents. Internal change agents can be classified into four areas according to Cavusgil & Nevin (1981):? 1) differential firms advantages, 2) strength of managerial aspirations for the firm's growth, profitability and market development, 3) management decisions, 4) organizational commitment. Cavusgil and Nevin's model are diagramed in Figure 10. In trying to identify the key internal change agent Bilkey & Tesar (1979)8 have attributed this to a key decision-maker within the organization. .afiaueflfl ".HSmH sumsunmm. soummmmm.mmwuoxuoz mo Hmcusoo =.:O«ummflumm>cH HMOHHHQEN c< "H0fi>msmm mcflpoxuwz uuomxm mo mucocaEHmpoo Hmcuoch: .:H>mz .o w Hamms>mu .m "mumaom .H0fl>mnmm uuomxm mo mucmcHEuovmn HmcumucHil.oa musmwm mA¢OD mmmZHmDm ZO mA< UZHBmOmxm m0 mBUMhhm mmMZHmDm mom mZOH MEB UZHZMMUZOU Idemmd fldemwd .802 m0 mZOHBafi IBZMEBHZSOU ho AH>HQ ZMHh AflHBmemhhHQ mmqdem¢> Bzmazmmmo mmqdem<> 02Hzm>mmBZH mmqmfiHm4> QZDOfiUMUdm 67 Cavusgil & Nevin (1980)11 have a 'stage' process of export marketing involvement. The five stages are domestic marketing stage, pre-export stage, experimental involvement stage, active involvement stage, and committed involvement stage. The export studies represent a specialized area of study but provide some insights from which implications can be drawn. They highlight significant factors and behaviors. Exports is based on, a comparative product advantage as economists claim. But involvement in foreign markets is a cautious process. Secondly, managerial perceptions and motivations are important. As shown in the FDI studies, these factors also affect investment decisions. Export studies would argue that the activity could be a process not a strategy. The international product life cycle theory can be classified to this school. The diagrammatic relationship of the international product life cycle theory (IPLC) is shown in Figure 11. According to the hypothesized cycle, in phase one, U.S. exports dominate the world market while in the next three phases, producers from other developed countries become increasingly competitive, first in their own markets, then in the third country markets, and finally in the U.S. market. The initial U.S. strength derives from market size, ready acceptance of innovation, R & D resources, well developed marketing 68 < ”oaozo OMHA uooooum HmcofluocuoucH: UD aAammHmHv m:.. 004 .m.D oou Mo was» ooHOHHmumm mocoEuOmHmm unomxo m.HoonH omBonm measmou m..am>¢ ..HmmH flame. me mahumxumz mo Hmcuooo :.mcofluoOHHaEH >OHHom uooooum ocm ucofimmwmmmom .Hmsm .H soot omuamam "mBOZ« «WUmDOm .coflumz umBOaaom o mo uCHOQBOH> on» Eoum UAmHII.HH ousmflm ""L >H mm 'the significance of political instability in investment decisions. The index used seems appropriate. A criticism is the relatively small number of observations. Another shortcoming is the lack of consideration of a lag period to test the sensitivity of the analysis. The assumption was made that adjustments to country political risk factors are quick (1-12 months). Investment is a high involvement decision and requires time to plan and organize. At the very least a one year lag should exist between political instability in a country and investment in that country. Finally this study neglects the longitudinal nature of the decisions. Only 1965 data was used to test the relationship. Bennett & Green (1972) served as a springboard for Green & Smith (1972) . In the latter study, an attempt was made to derive the relationship which exists between a nation's level of political instability and the returns the multinationals expect to receive on their investments. 75 Again the Feirebend and Feirebend political risk index was used. The 1965 investment data from Survey of Current Business was used. Four aspects of U.S. foreign direct investment was used for each nation. Cross- sectional data for twenty-three nations was used. The authors hypothesized that a positive relationship exists between political instability and foreign investment profitability; The higher the political instability of a nation, the higher the rate of return on the foreign investment located in that nation. The hypothesis was accepted for investment behavior in mining and petroleum, but rejected for manufacturing data. Higher profits are derived from investments in politically stable countries or stated differently manufacturing investment was less profitable in politically unstable countries. The results for manufacturing is not surprising since the concept of political risk and its results suggests substantial losses due to instability and expropriation. The results can be explained due to faster reaction time for manufacturing investment compared to mining and petroleum investment. It may explain why U.S. manufacturing firms are less apt to invest in less developed countries. Horst (1972b)18 was concerned with the differences between investors and non-investors within the same 76 industry. He commented that "many of the determinants of the decision to invest abroad (e.g. tariff, transport cost, dependence on natural resource) are the same for any two firms in the same industry."(p.259) His conclusions were that larger firms were more likely to invest abroad than smaller firms. Once inter-industry differences are washed out, the only difference of any separate significance is firm size. He also found that industries in which the economies of size are important tend to have fewer foreign investors controlling a larger share of the foreign market. Horst made use of 187 multinational firms making up the Harvard Business School sample at that time. Graphically the relationship is illustrated as in Figure 12. Graph 1 shows partial relationships between firm (holding industry influences constant) and the probability that it would be multinational and the probability that it would have a Canadian subsidiary. The later observation lead the author to suggest that a Canadian subsidiary may be a stepping stone to investing in other countries. Graph 2 shows a plot of the relative heights of the two functions in Graph 1 showing how the conditional probability of being multinational. While holding firm size constant, Horst concludes that inter-industry differences - research and development level, resource concentration and estimate of 77 P 1.0. '9‘ Probability of being a [—- Canadian investor IT ' .8- .7. .6‘ 5. Probability of being ' a multinational .4 ‘ investor. .3‘ .2‘ .11 v U v I V GRAPH 1 50 125 250 500 1000 Firm Sales (106 Dollars) P 1.0 . .9 q - . Combined probability of .7 being a multinational . O 6 ‘ .5 ~ 0 4 1 .3 . .2 4 .1 d I I l I GRAPH 2 50 125 250 500 1,000 Figure 12.--Investment as a Function of Firm Size. SOURCE: T. Horst, "Firm and Industry Determinants of the Decision to Invest Abroad: An Empirical Study," Review of Economics and Statistics 54, 279-294. 78 minimal efficient plant size as further variables influencing investment. Horsts first conclusion agrees with Mason, Miller & Weigels (1975) conceptual development of the effect of firm size. However the later are more explicit in saying that firm size affects the firm's chosen mode of operations in foreign markets. Smaller firms will tend to export while larger firms will invest when all things are equal. Firm size is not included in this dissertation because only location specific factors are being investigated. However a composite model of modes of operation should include firm specific and location specific factors. The Goodnow & Hansz (1972)19 study is the only one that specifically looked at the relationship between modes of entry and environmental factors [political stability, market opportunity, economic development and performance, cultural unity, legal barriers, physiographic barriers, geocultural distance]. The hypothesis tested was originally developed by Litvak and Banting and read "a firm will tend to pursue an entry strategy involving greater control over and greater investment in marketing channel activities as the country's environment becomes 'hotter'."(p.33) The authors used multiple macro indicators of the environment to classify nation-states as either' hot, moderate or 79 cold. A cross-sectional survey of managers was used to find out their entry mode for their main product in their main foreign market. Goodnow et. al. found that U.S. firms used exporting strategies most often in environmentally 'cold' countries, and invested in environmentally 'hot' countries. While their study is insightful it is riddled with methodological problems. The 'entry' variable was measured by a self- administered questionnaire which was sent to directors of international divisions requesting them to identify for each country in whiCh the firm's MAJOR product is sold, the type of market entry strategy used by the firm. The data collected is erroneous partly because it eliminates data for 'minor' products. Conclusions were based on reporting percentages only. No statistical relationship was sought for the data and no significance tests were done. Finally the measure of political risk was based on estimates by the U.S. Department of Commerce country specialists. This problem while not peculiar to this study is serious. How can we correlate the actions of managers who make decisions about modes of operation with perceptions of the political risk by country specialists? A better analysis would be to have these managers evaluate these countries based on their perceptions of their riskiness. 80 This study will improves on the Goodnow and Hansz study by using macro aggregate data for exports and FDI. Also explicit criteria will be used in selecting the periods and nation-states in accordance with the hypothesis. Rock (1973)20 was interested in investment guarantees as a spurious variable affecting the relationship between political risk and FDI flows. It had been postulated that developing countries offer guarantees on FDI against political risks. Omission of those guarantees in some FDI studies have resulted in surprising conclusions. Rock considered two periods for analyzing the effect on political instability in host developing countries on U.S. FDI in manufacturing industries. In the first period when an investment guarantee did not exist, U.S. FDI was found to be negatively correlated with political instability while in the second period (when a guarantee was introduced) the correlation disappeared. Situmeang (1978)21 concluded that political instability was statistically unrelated to the flow of FDI in all sectors. (non-extractive, manufacturing, high technology and low technology industries) Baldwin (1979)22 tried to determine whether trade and direct investment can be explained by the same 81 variables - capital and labor content. His reason and conclusion was as follows: "Because of the capital intensity of natural resource imports, U.S. import trade is capital intensive relative to export trade, taking into account all industries. When only trade in manufactured goods is concerned this result does not hold. On the other hand, U.S. firms investing abroad in manufacturing apparently are attracted by the relative abundance of unskilled labor and bias their activities toward labor intensive industries. However the heavy direct investment in capital intensive - natural resource industries, such as petroleum and mining that is designed to facilitate imports of these products prevents the sign of the capital/labor coefficient in all-industry direct investment equation from also being significantly negative."(p.46) The cross-country, strategic school studies have clearly shown that certain factors would affect a firms choice of operations or entry mode. The authors seem to have focused on those factors that interest them or that are most relevant to their disciplines. There doesn't seem to be any attempt to build a body of knOwledge. The authors have looked at location specific and firm specific factors. It is not clear from the studies if one or the other influences the mode of operations entry decision. The major contribution of the school is in identifying factors relevant to the mode of operations decision. The most recent study on political risk and foreign direct investment was Nigh (1985a) and Nigh (1985b).23 82 Although Nigh examined the relationship between political events and manufacturing direct foreign investment (MDFI) decisions, he was interested in political risk. The study pooled time series (21 years) and cross sectional (24 countries) data. The Conflict and Peace Data Bank (COPDAB) was used to measure political events. This index records events that are deemed political for 148 countries obtained from seventy news and media sources. Political events are classified as either inter-nation conflictive, inter-national cooperative, intra-nation conflictive or intra-nation cooperative. Nigh felt that separation of political events as conflictive and cooperative would reveal the true effect of political risk on flows of U.S. FDI. Prior studies had not separated the two, and one reason for the surprising findings of the econometrics studies has been the nature of the political risk phenomena. Robock (1971)24 suggested that political instability does not always enhance political risk for FDI while Thunell (1977)25 has suggested that the degree of political risk emanating from political instability in a country is likely to vary for FDI of different origins and in different industries. Nigh tested the relationship for less developed countries and developed countries separately. For less developed countries (for one-year lag model), his conclusion was that "political events affects the 83 manufacturing direct foreign investment of U.S. multinational corporations when less developed countries are being concerned. Both conflictive and cooperative inter-nation. political events, as well as conflictive intra-nation political events, appear to have an affect on MDFI in less developed countries."(p.9) For developed countries regression analysis for the one-year lag models indicated that the conflictive and cooperative inter-nation (but not intra-nation) political events affect the MDFI decisions of U.S. multinational corporations when developed countries are being considered. 1&3 also found that market size affects the MDFI decisions. Nigh's findings agree with the conclusions of the survey studies and are contrary to the findings of Bennett & Green (1972), Green & Cunningham (1975) and Kobrin (1976). His methodology is superior since he uses a cross-sectional, time series design. The use of the COPDAB is innovative. Nigh (1985b) followed up his earlier study be investigating the effect of political events on German MDFI flows. He was influenced by the criticism of Thunell that the relationship varies for MDFI from different origins. His conclusion was similar to that of the U.S. MDFI flows and thus validated that study. 84 The role of tariffs in the export, foreign direct investment substitution issue is not clear-cut. Two studies highlight this contradiction. Horst (1972a)26 examined the relationship between U.S. exports to the Canadian. market and. the sales of U.S. affiliates in Canada. He concluded that the most significant factor influencing the decision whether or not to invest in Canada was the height of Canadian tariffs. As the tariff increased, U.S. subsidiary production in Canada increased. In an earlier study Scaperlanda and Mauer (1969)27 arrived at diametrically opposing results. The authors used least squares regression to test three hypothesis relating to the size of market, economic growth and tariff discrimination. Data on U.S. direct investment in the European Economic Community for the 1952-1966 period was used. The authors were interested in explaining the rapid growth of U.S. investment in Europe during the 1959-1966 period. Empirical tests led to conclusions that only the market size hypothesis was supported statistically. Tariff discrimination did not explain the switch from exports to production. Cross-firm studies Cross-firm studies typically use survey methods to determine factors influencing choice of mode of entry or operations. These factors determine all modes used not 85 simply the export mode. Buckley and Pearce (1979)28 focused on sourcing policy. Their main thesis was that a firms sourcing policy is a function of firm and industry characteristics. Their hypothesis was to examine the determinants of sourcing policy and to show that a firms international imports are strongly related to its research and development intensity. Buckley' and. Pearce's findings 'were 'three-fold. First, even among the largest firms, size of the firm is a major influence on the type of sourcing policy adopted: ceteris paribus, the larger the firm, the more likely it is to service its foreign market by production in those markets. Second, there are significant variations in the sourcing policy of firms when grouped not only according to industry but also nationality. Thirdly, the size of internal flows from parent to subsidiary is very clearly connected with the degree of research intensity of the industry in which the firm is competing . The more research intensive the industry, the more likely are internal transactions to be of importance. The conclusions of this study are not surprising. The importance of firm size has been established in the literature. MaClayton, Smith and Hair (1980)29 used health care firms to test hypothesis relating to foreign market entry. The specific objectives were two-fold: 1) to 86 identify those foreign market environmental factors which companies within the health care products industry perceive as relevant in evaluating foreign markets and, 2) to investigate the relationship between these factors and the internal characteristics of the companies. They concluded that firms in the U.S. based health care products industry seemed to evaluate foreign markets on the basis of the following home country specific dimensions: market and marketing opportunity, legal barriers and their economic objectives, cultural unity and physiographic barriers, political stability, level of economic development and performance of the country. An interesting conclusion was that no statistically significant relationship existed between the companies experience in overseas business, number of employees, research and development expenditure, total sales nor total investment and home country specific dimensions. This finding is fascinating because it goes against theoretical speculations. Although the mode of operations was not specifically addressed, the authors recognize that "it makes a difference if a given market is entered through exporting from the parent country, or one of its subsidiaries abroad, through a direct investment in a manufacturing facility or through 87 licensing arrangements. Obviously direct investment represents a greater risk and requires more analysis." (P- 40) MaClayton, Smith & Hair (1980) have speculated that erroneous reporting of data for sales, investment and research and development expenditures may be the cause of findings. However one significant implication is that it destroys the myth of companies seeking to familiarize themselves with the home country market thereafter opting for exporting or licensing in preference to full scale investment. Further research on this important relationship is necessary as a strong relationship has been ‘theorizeda This finding, although inconclusive, lends credence that a firm might enter directly into a foreign market via foreign direct investment if the factors are right. Harrell & Kiefer (1981)30 used the product portfolio concept to postulate strategies U.S. firms should pursue in international markets. Using the portfolio matrix developed by George Steiner, et al., the authors suggested that harvest/divest/combine/license strategies should be used in product markets in which the firm has low competitive strength and where country attractiveness is low meaning modest in market size and growth rate. Since the underlying concept behind the competitive strength variable is the experience curve, that variable 88 can be interpreted as market share. The competitive strength variable was measured as a function of market share, product fit, contribution margin and market support. Therefore the authors suggest that the mode of operations will be a function of market attractiveness and firm size. Thus a multinational such as Ford Tractor could invest in Kenya or Pakistan where country attractiveness is high and where it [Ford] has a high competitive strength while a smaller firm such as Snell Environmental Group, Lansing, will be content with a joint ‘venture strategy in those markets. Figure 13 illustrates the thrust of the relationship between mode of operation, competitive strength and country’ market attractiveness. This article is insightful in its application of portfolio analysis to the development of international marketing strategy. Kirkpatrick & Yamin (1981)31 were concerned with the determinants of export subsidiary formation by U.S. transnationals in developing countries. It has been suggested by Kobrin et. al. that political risk may be an industry specific phenomena, hence the use of U.S. manufacturing FDI rather than mining, petroleum or finance. This empirical analysis lends support to that theory in showing that U.S. transnational's propensity to 89 High Country ”XXII'IIII° , ” .14 Attract-L . - . Li JOINT VENTURE iveness f .. . DIVEST I Z-INVEST'; v .1 + + t T ‘l ' + + 4 v T 3 ° : -§- 1 .' fiv 'I’ I T . 'f 1 w t + +-+ w 1» + at 't 1 w ~t + + -: 1 1 * ‘1 twt++**" s+++1~o4+~o + +-§+'++-01-14 744**4f+++ +4+1+1++i1 1* 4+ d-id‘id 1 + 1+ ++-+1++Ht+ 4 111++11+i1 4"! 4+11-I-I-I 4 1 41-+ 44-: ‘11 11 4 «'11 4 -4 HérveSt q 4 4 w + 1 + 4 +-t-+ 4 diveFt '** * combine 1" T * 3 ** " I license I I I 4+ +4 4‘14+-t+*.,,,+« 4 *+--t~-***'~$}.++*1* Low High LOW COMPETITIVE STRENGTH Figure l3.--Modes of Operation, Competitive Strength and Country Attractiveness Grid SOURCE: G. D. Harrell & R. Kiefer, "Multinational Strategic Market Portfolios," MSU Business Topics (Winter 1981): 7-15. 90 invest in export-oriented manufacturing subsidiaries in LDCs is a function of industry characteristics. The authors used information from the Harvard University Business Data Bank. Two subsets of data - for all LDCs and for five LDCs was used. The later performed better than the former (i.e. all independent variables had the expected sign and significance at the 10% or 5% level). The authors thus concluded that export subsidiary formation is a function of value added per production worker, research and development personnel as a percentage of total employees, advertising expenditure as a percentage of sales and expenditure on after sales service as a percentage of sales. The focus of this study was on export seeking rather than market seeking FDI. It would be interesting to determine if the same relationship holds for market seeking investment. Kravis & Lipsey (1982)32 tried to explain location decisions from the economic consideration implied by the market scanning hypothesis. They assumed that production in a host country is a result of interaction of several sets of factors. One has to do with country and commodity characteristics while the other is firm characteristics. In trying to determine who invests where, the authors were concerned with whether there is some relation between the characteristics of a country 91 and the type of firm that sets up manufacturing. Following a tabulation of the number of firms investing in. certain countries per industry' group, the authors hypothesized that location of production in a foreign country is a function of proximity to the U;S., the use of English and the size of market. These findings suggest a regular country order for each product/product line that a firm decides to market abroad, not a regular mode of entry pattern. Their results showed large differences in size between U.S. investors in Canada and U.S. investors in other country-markets. U.S. firms invest only in Canada or Canada first.(p. 205) Within each industry low wage firms tend to have investments in high wage countries, while U.S. companies invest more frequently in low wage destinations (p.223), such as developing countries. Davidson (1980)33 investigated the role of host country characteristics as determinants of FDI location patterns. The main variable was corporate experiences. Prior experience in a host country is found to increase the firms priority for projects in that country relative to other investment options. In addition, the experience level of the firm influences the relative importance of different country characteristics in determining location patterns. Inexperienced firms exhibit greater preference 92 for near, similar markets than firms with broader international operating experience. CONCLUSION The literature reviewed shows that many studies have been interested factors that affect changes in mode of operations. Few studies have considered political risk although political risk is a major determinant of the foreign market involvement decision. This dissertation addresses that missing link. NOTES 1. See, Kobrin, S. (1976), "The Environmental Determinants of Foreign Direct Manufacturing Investment: An Ex-Post Empirical Analysis", Journal of International Business Studies, (Fall/Winter), 29-42. 2. See, Bennett, P.D. and R.T. Green (1972), "Political Instability as a Determinant of Direct Foreign Investment in Marketing", Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 9 (May), 182-186. 3. See, Kobrin, S. (1978), "When Does Political Instability Result in Increased Investment Risk?", Columbia Journal of Business, (October). 4. See, Snavely, W.P., P. Weiner, K. Ulrich and E. Enright, (1964), Export Survey pf the Greater Hartford Area, Vols. 1 & 2, University of Connecticut.;. Cavusgil, S.T. (1976), Organizational Determinants of Firms Export Behavior: An Empirical Analysis, PhD. dissertation, The University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 93 See, Johanson & Weidersheim-Paul, (1975), "The Internationalization of the Firm: Four Swedish Case Studies", Journal of Management Studies, (October), 305-332. See, Vesper (1979), "Entrepreneurship in Foreign Trade", Journal of Small Business Management, (April), 5-11. See, Cavusgil & Nevin (1981), "Internal Determinants of Export Marketing Behavior: An Empirical Investigation", Journal of Marketing Research, (February), 114-119. See, Bilkey & Tesar (1978), "The Export Behavior of Smaller Sized Wisconsin Manufacturing Firms", Journal of International Business Studies, (Spring), 93-98. See, Axinn, C. (1985), "An Examination of Factors that Influence Export Involvement", Unpublished PhD. dissertation; Michigan State University. See, Cavusgil & Nevin (1980), "A Conceptualization of the Initial Involvement of International Marketing", Theoretical Developments in Marketin , C.W. Lamb and P.M. Dunne, eds., Chicago: American Marketing Association, 68-71. Cavusgil & Nevin, op. cit. See, Ayal, Igal (1981), "International Product Life Cycle: A Reassessment and Product Policy Implications", Journal of Marketing, Vol. 45, (Fall). See, Bain (1956), Barriers to New Competition, (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press). See, Mann (1966), "Seller Concentration, Barriers to Entry and Rates of Return in Thirty Industries 1950- 1960", Review, (August), 296-307. See, Comanor & Wilson (1967), "Advertising, Marketing Structure and Performance", Reyiey, (November), 423- 440. See, Orr, D. (1984), "The Determinants of Entry: A Study of the Canadian Manufacturing Industries", Review of Economics and Statistigs, LVI, (February),. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 94 See, Bennett, P.D. and R.T. Green (1972), "Political Instability as a Determinant of Direct Foreign Investment in Marketing", Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 9, (May), 182-186. See, Horst (1972b), "Firm and Industry Determinants of the Decision to Invest Abroad: An Empirical Study", Review of Economics and Statistics, 54, 258- 266. See, Goodnow, J. an J. Hansz (1972), "Environmental Determinants of Overseas Market Entry Strategies", Journal of International Business Studies, (Spring), 33-50. See, Rock, M. (1973), "Cross-Country Analysis of the Determinants of U.S. Foreign Investment in Manufacturing Less Developed Countries", unpublished PhD. dissertation, University of Pittsburgh. See, Situmeang, B. J. (1978), "The Environmental Correlates of Foreign Direct Investment with Reference to Southeast Asia", Unpublished PhD. dissertation, University of Oregon. See, Baldwin, R. (1979), "Determinants of Trade and Foreign Investment: Further Evidence", The Review of Economigs and Statistics, Vol. 6, Amsterdam, 40- 48. See, Nigh (1985), "The Effects of Political Events on U.S. Direct Foreign Investment: A Pooled Time- Series Cross Sectional Analysis", qurnal of International Business Studies, Vol. XVI, No. 1 (Spring), 1-17. See, Robock (1971), "Political Risk: Identification and Assessment", Columbia Journal of World Business, (July/August), 6-20. See, Thunell, L. (1977), Political Risks in International Business: Investmen; Behavior of Multinational Corporations, New York: Praeger Publishers. See, Horst, T. (1972a), "The Industrial Composition of U.S. Exports and Subsidiary Sales to the Canadian Market", American Economic Review, 62, 37-45. 27. 28. 29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 95 See, Scaperlanda, A. and L. Mauer (1969), "The Determinants of U.S. Direct Investment in the EEC", The American Economic Reviey, Vol. 59, Evanston, 558-568. See, Buckley & Pearce (1979), "Overseas Production and Exporting by the World's Largest Enterprises: A Study in Sourcing Policy", Journal of International Business Studies,10, (Spring/Summer),9-20. See, Maclayton, D.,M. Smith, and J. Hair (1980), "Determinants of Foreign Market Entry:A multivariate Analysis of Corporate Behavior" Management Ipternational Review,20 (3),40-52 See, Harrell & Keifer (1981), "Multinational Strategic Market Portfolios," MSU Business TOpics, (Winter),5-15 See, Kirkpatrick & Yamin (1981), "The Determinant of Export Subsidiary Formation by U.S. Transnationals in Developing Countries", World Develo ment, 9, 373- 382. The market scanning hypothesis states that MNCs use their superior knowledge to locate manufacturing activities in countries that are most advantageous from the standpoint of market and cost considerations. See, Kravis & Lipsey (1982), "The Location of Overseas Production for Export by U.S. Multinational Firms", Journal 0: Intepnatipnai Economics, 12, 201-223. See, Davidson, W.H. (1980), "The Location of Foreign Direct Investment Activity: Country Characteristics and Experience Effect", Journai of international Business Studies, 11 (Fall), 9-22. CHAPTER I I I METHODOLOGY In Chapters one and two, the variables of interest were discussed. In this chapter, the research design, the research hypothesis and their operationalization, and issues of sampling will be discussed. The research design involves the use of both secondary and primary data. The hypothesis will be examined using the secondary data which will be pooled.l The testing of the hypothesis constitutes the first stage of the research. The second stage involves validation of the findings through personal interviews with eight Michigan corporations involved in foreign markets. The secondary data consists of pooled cross- sectional (20 countries) and time-series (11 years) data. Pooling of data offers the advantages of increased reliability although the variance is reduced (Wallace, 1972). Bass & ‘Wittink (1975) say' that "the use of multiple observations gives rise to opportunities through the gain in degrees of freedom"(p.414) provided pooling is appropriate. This study is concerned with the role of political risk in influencing the mode of operations 96 97 decision. In research jargon we are interested in the amount of variance which is explained by political risk (and indeed other identified variables) in the export/investment decision. Although the independent variable of interest is political risk, market size and growth rate are included to avoid biased and inconsistent estimates of the constant and slope coefficients by violation of assumptions concerning the disturbance term. (Kelejian & Oates 1981,p. 233) Since we are interested in dependency of the variables and all variables are measured as interval or ratio data, the appropriate technique is multiple regression. Multiple Regresssion Analysis is a statistical technique which can be used to analyze the relationship between a single dependent (criterion) variable and several independent (predictor) variables. The objective is to use several independent variables whose values are known to predict the dependent value the researcher wishes to know. (Hair et. al.,p. 35) A series of multiple regressions will be run on the dependent variables of interest.2 The selection of the sample (countries and years) will be based on sampling theory.3 Studies using secondary data tend to use pg available data to test relationships. For example, Nigh (1985) pools and regresses all available data (countries) for the years 1954-1975 to test the hypothesis of his 98 study. This will tend to inhibit our ability to make inferential decisions since the sample is a convenient one not a probability sample. Therefore in this study the selection of the sample size, sampling element, time period, variables and measures will be based on decision rules or theory in order to isolate the effects (variance) of the variables under investigation. (Hage, 1975) Table 6 shows research methodologies that have been used to investigate political risk. The objective of this research is to explain a phenomena. The primary data will be used to validate the results of the secondary analysis. Data will be obtained through personal interviews with some Michigan firms involved in foreign markets. Although personal interviews would allow a very limited number of firms to be studied, it provides significant insights and maintains a real- world context for data collection. A mail survey will not capture the dynamic processes involved in this decision area. The duration of the interviews were between one and one-half and two hours and they were conducted in the months of April and May, 1986. An attempt was made to structure the interviews such that the same questions were asked of each individual respondent. Thirty-five letters of solicitation were initially sent out. Of these, twenty replies were received (after follow-up letters were sent). Of the twenty replies, eight were 99 positive while twelve were negative. Reasons cited for refusal were mostly the length of interview time requested. The respondents felt it was too long. A few replies indicated that the month of April was a particularly busy one for them and could not therefore make out time for the interview. Appendix J shows a list of the questions used for the interviews. The responses/conversations were recorded using tape recorders in order to ensure that valuable information was not omitted. The interviewees were aware that the conversation was being recorded. Later the tapes were transcribed4 and edited for inclusion in this study. Appendix I provides data about the firms used for the interviews. Appendices E, F and G show documents used to solicit these firms. Appendix H shows the interview schedule. The factors taken into consideration in selecting firms in the sample were size (sales and employees), nature of business, years .of foreign involvement and commitment to foreign markets.5 RATIONALE FOR RESEARCH DESIGN Kobrin (1980) has criticized the research in this area for using cross-sectional techniques: "all the studies entail major data and methodological problems ranging from the use of composites indices of instability to the almost universal use (with one exception) of 100 Hensoumem ..onH .mneummm nOHueEnomnH ..n> .Haenmuez =.meamoHooonuoz noneemem hufiaflneumnH HeowuHHom mo unoEmmemmn mm. .HmmmHv .eHmmom .3 .O one eHofluonn .o .m mo monfipflnz on» Scum ooumeon ”monnom HabmH .Hmoumoms noHHOHoenm one nOHueHnEHm .Q n Amhma xoeASOHH one “Home mnflumeoeHOm neflmexem .0 nowuowoenm oemen Hoooz Hemneu .U mHmS ene oemEHImmou . HommH ..He um . H u . O o anuemaonnv mnoueOHonw mnfioeeq .m AHBmmmv mneuweoeHOE finmaea .m nofiumwoonm oomen eueo une>m .n o>wuowoonm o>flu0floonm uneecono mxnw nOHuwnan .n HommH ..He um numbness Emwuonuoe one wuHOHnnum .uneEm>Oz Hewoom .Q HvsmH .Honmoxmv nOHunHO>om one HeHOOm oeoum .0 mnOH ene ax one I o O emne . .u H m e m H e 2 H O O HmsmH .nomnwnnHues mnoflueneamxo umHuHHm .Heo nowunao>em one mouHHm .m IHOO o o>m . eOH H O . e OHOO . . H n m H .u.H n H u . m m HmomH.maozv, nOHuenemem OHEOnOom .< Snouenemem Shoueneamxm mnOflunHo>emmwmunemeom .< . Hmoma Nunenom oH>eQ OHHwonm noHnenuHm HennounH O eoma nOmnnOb mnefiaenu mcoHuHcHeme ,msmH .qsmH.sHHan mnemou oomemneueo uno>m .m SpfiawneumnH HeOHUHHOm mo wnoH eOH Home ne m e .m momH Honenm .u .m. HO o H o0: mnOHanHmoo HeOHHHQEm .n o>Humwnomeo o>HumHHOmeo moaonum emeo Henow>fionH .n m>Huumnno m>Huownno noneomem noueemem m>HueuHucena o>HumuHHmno peacoHooonuez noenemem SuflawneumnH HeowuHHomII.m manna 101 cross-sectional techniques to investigate what is obviously a longitudinal phenomena."(p.74) The implication is that a design that captures the dynamic nature of the relationship would be more appropriate. Kimberly (1976) defines a longitudinal organizational research as one that "consists of those techniques, methodologies and activities which permit the observation, description and/or classification of organizational phenomena in such a way that processes can be identified and empirically documented."(p.329) Some of the advantages of using longitudinal data to study organizations as suggested by Kimberly (1976) are: 1) Longitudinal research facilitates attempts to establish causality (i.e. temporal precedence can be established). 2) Longitudinal research can help minimize the problems encountered when process is inferred from cross- sectional data. 3) Longitudinal research facilitates the development of better models of organizational growth and change. 4) Longitudinal research permits one to take contextual constraints into consideration in the research design. 5) Longitudinal research ultimately enhances the effectiveness. of 'various. strategies for’ organizational intervention. 102 THEORETICAL DECISION RULES Certain decision rules have to be made with respect to the data which is available. Hage (1975) puts it this way, "since nation-states are complex, they require special methodological rules for sampling."(p.133) The suggested implication is that societies should be selected on the basis of their score on some independent variable and studied over long periods of time so as to maximize information gain and minimize cost. (Hage 1975,p.131) The fact that most of the macro variables do not. have normal distributions can raise a number of statistical problems regarding inference. It is thus necessary to follow rules of purposive sampling in order to approximate an experiment that will build on present theoretical knowledge. The decisions necessary to develop an appropriate design are: 1) What should the number of countries in the sample be? 2) What countries should be chosen (sampling element)? 3) What time periods should be chosen? 4) How many variables should be measured? 5) How many indicators for each variable need to be measured? 103 Determination of Sample Size and Element The upper limit is the number of countries available in the political risk index. Since BERI Index6 will be used. that upper limit is forty-eight (the number of countries monitored by the service). It is not necessary to use all forty-eight countries. Decision Rule 1”. Choose countries that have high and low scores on the independent ‘variable and. where possible, find instances where the same country has high and low scores. (Hage 1975, p. 138) With respect to this study this means to study countries that have high and IOW' scores on. the independent ‘variable: of interest - political risk. The reason is to maximize variation, and thus information gained and allow for an approximation to an experimental design. pecision Rule 2. Choose high and low scores on the independent variable of alternative explanations and, where possible, find instances where the same society has both high and low scores. (Hage 1975, p. 140) This is essential to test a theory when we can safely eliminate alternative explanations. Therefore countries with high and low scores on all our independent variables need to be chosen. 104 Decision Rule 3. Select societies and time periods that allow for the control of particular variables, which do :not necessarily’ represent alternative «explanations, but which do confound or contaminate the results. (Hage 1975, p. 141) This is a particularly useful rule when we are not sure what the alternative explanations are. Examples of these variables are population size and level of development because they are related to a large number of other variables in a number of ways that are not necessarily understood. Hage (1975) suggests that if there is any conflict between this decision rule and the first, the third should take precedence because we always need experimental manipulation or variation in over independent variables before we try to eliminate or control for confounding factors. We therefore need to take countries that have low and high scores on the independent variables from the geographic area (e.g. African nations). Choosing nation-states that are much alike in terms of economic development or political structure is counter productive. Thus this third decision rule implies the use of control variables in conjunction with the selection of societies that are high and low on independent variables. 105 Decision Rule 4. When searching for the cause of societal events, select instances of absence and presence or relatively high and low scores. (Hage 1975, p. 144) If the researcher also chooses time periods within the same societies when events such as revolutions did not occur; then they have a powerful kind of research design because we can partially control for various biographical factors. Determination of Specific Time Periggs The selection of specific time periods presents a problem: however, Moore (1963) has suggested that it may not. be a problem because "most variables are always changing either to higher or lower scores."(p.23) Decision Rule 5. Choose a time period that is one- half the amount of time needed to represent a meaningful change in the independent variable. (Hage 1975 ,p.145) Since variables have their typical change rates, naturally we would want to measure variables at least as often as their change rates . The determination of a 'meaningful change' depends on the information being collected. Such information as cultural trends, distribution of wealth, and urbanization are the slowest to change. (Hage 1975,p.146) 106 Decision Rule 6. Choose a duration that is longer than the causal process we are interested in studying.(Hage l975,p. 148) Therefore an eleven year time-span provides an adequate time period for the phenomena under investigation. Determination of the Variables The implication of the first two decision rules is that we want to include not only the independent variables from our own theoretical model, but also, the independent variables that have been isolated by others. Two variables that have been consistently isolated in research studies are market growth and market size. Hage (1975) suggest inclusion of variables from other disciplines for statistical reasons. Decision Rule 7. Systematically include the key variables of several disciplines if relevant to the problem. (Hage 1975, p. 153) Determination of Measures Where possible alternative measures for the same variables should be included. This is because using only one indicator tends to favor certain countries and not others. In this regard the care that Cutright (1963) took in combining two indicators to measure variation 107 between societies on the dimensions that concerned him were exemplary. CONCLUSIONS Based on these decision rules relating to the sample; time period variables and measures, the following countries have been selected. Twenty countries (ten LDC and ten DC) were selected (Appendix D). The time period selected for the analysis is the period from 1973 through 1983.Yearly measurements within this time period is deemed appropriate to observe and measure variables and their affects. HYPOTHESIS AND THEIR RATIONALE H1: A positive relationship exists between U.S. manufacturing firm's exports to a host country in year t and international decision makers perception of political risk in that host country in year t-k : ceteris paribus. This hypothesis investigates the relationship between exporting behavior to a host country as political risk is perceived to increase and decrease over time. The incremental school postulates that firms usually export first in the internationalization. process to increase learning (Root, 1982), reduce risks.(Cavusgil and Nevin, 1980) This implies that exporting is an effective strategy in high risk markets. Therefore as risk 108 increases firms would resort to exporting and therefore a positive relationship is expected. The hypothesis tests the theory of the incremental school of thought. Basi (1968) surveyed international firms and concluded that political risk was a significant determinant of mode of operation. The contention is that even when firms are. accessing foreign markets through investing (when political risk is low), they would refrain from further investing as the level of political risk increases. To continue to seek profits and maintain a presence in that market, the firm would then switch and opt for less risky modes of operation. Exporting then becomes the logical choice (least risky mode), if the firm chooses to adapt. Hence, a positive relationship can be expected between exporting and political risk. Observation of U.S. manufacturing exports and FDI to high risk country markets lends support to this hypothesis. Peru, for instance, received $75 million dollars worth of foreign direct investment in 1973 and $415.2 million in exports. But as political risk increased, the proportions shifted dramatically. By 1982, U.S. manufacturing firms FDI had declined to $2 million and exports increased to $1,116.9 million. While these figures8 do not adjust for inflation, they do not negate the conclusions since any deflation will be used for both FDI and exports and therefore cross-out. This phenomena holds for most 109 developed countries. Other factors such as tariff and non-tariff barriers can influence exports, hence there is a need to assume all other factors equal (ceteris paribus). It should also be noted that the relevant decision isn't IF to enter the host market or not, but WHAT mode of operation to use given the level of perceived political risk. One would therefore expect a significant positive relationship between exports and political risk. H2: A negative relationship exists between the flow of U.S. manufacturing firms foreign direct investment to a host country in year t and international executive's perception of political risk in that country in year t-k, ceteris paribus. This hypothesis tries to investigate the opposite (i.e. negative) effect of political risk using FDI as the dependent variable. Root (1982) has conceptualized that firms stop investment if political risk is high. Kassicieh, Suleiman & Nassar Jamar (1984) investigated the effect on MNCs sales due to the war in the Persian Gulf and found that the level of sales, contracts, and investments by MNCs reflect the perceived risk of losses from political instability brought about by the Iran-Iraq war. Sales by MNCs from FDI from June 1977 to December 1981 decreased from $5.256 million in 1977-78 to $1.888 million in 1980-81 (Nassar Jamar, 1984). That political 110 risk reduces FDI cannot be denied. Foreign direct investment by definition involves tremendous commitment of resources. Markets with higher political risk increase the probability of intervention (see definition of political risk) and therefore firms would want to guard against losses by minimizing FDI commitments. That is, decrease the increase in the flow of FDI funds. A positive relationship is therefore expected between FDI and stability. Hypothesis 1 and 2 jointly test the theory of the strategic school with respect to substitutability of exporting for FDI in high risk markets. H3a: In developed host countries, market size in year t-k explains greater variance than political risk and market growth rate in year t-k for the exporting decisions of U.S. manufacturing firms in year t, ceteris paribus. H3b: In developed host countries, market size in year t-k explains greater variance than political risk and market growth rate in year t-k for foreign direct investment decisions of U.S. manufacturing firms in year t, ceteris paribus. The objective of this hypothesis is to indirectly determine the effect of political risk on the export- invest decision by using the data for developed countries. An assumption is that the perceived political risk in developed countries is low or stability is high. The international decision maker interested in developed country markets realizes that they do not have to worry as much about expropriation, nationalization or 111 intervention. Consequently the amount of variance explained by political risk will be minimal. As Bennett & Green (1972) put it, "it is possible that the allocation of investment within the developed nations is not made on the basis of their level of stability."(p.186) Market size then becomes a very important variable explaining a greater share of variance. In a step-wise forward regression market size will enter the equation. Market size will be significant for exports decisions as well as investment decisions. However a firm would like to maximize its presence in large markets and therefore would seek to invest in those markets. The amount of variance explained for foreign direct investment by market size would be greater than that explained for exports. H4a: International executive's perception of political risk in less developed countries in year t-k does significantly explain greater variance than market size in the exporting decision of U.S. manufacturing firms in year t, ceteris paribus. H4b: International executives's perception of political risk in less developed countries in year t-k does significantly explain greater variance than market size in the fioreign direct investment decisions of U.S. manufacturing firms in year t, ceteris paribus. Again this hypothesis indirectly tests for the effect of political risk. As a group of countries, LDC show a high degree of political risk. Investors would be 112 determining the political risk level of the markets they operates in. Political risk will therefore explain a significant amount of variance in the decision to export or invest. The amount of variance explained by political risk for FDI will be greater than that for exports. Also there is theoretical support for considering the relationship different for less developed nations and developed nations. Fer instance Ievi (1979) has argued that including developed nations in his sample would hide the actual relationship between political instability and FDI in less developed countries. (p. 60) Bennett & Green (1972) and Nigh (1985a) have shown that level of development is negatively related to political instability. Lewis (1979) empirically tested the relationship between political instability and the flow of foreign direct investment in developing countries (LDCs). His conclusions suggested that political instability is an important albeit not the prime determinant of foreign direct investment decision. run. Burton (1984) examined expropriation of foreign assets for the period 1960-1977 by reference to a matrix of the nationality of expropriated firms, industrial sector, time period, and the regional and income levels of host countries. The data, consisting of 1,857 cases, forced sales in whole or in part and contract renegociation. He found that low income countries accounted for a high 113 proportion of confiscation. The southern African region accounted for 44.5% while Latin America were responsible for 36.2% of the expropriated firms. (p.132) H5: In LDCs the amount of variance explained by political risk in year t-k for FDI in year t is greater or equal to the variance for exports in year t, ceteris paribus. This hypothesis tries to compare the contribution or explanatory power of political risk for the dependent variables - foreign direct investment and exporting. This hypothesis is designed to determine if political risk is more closely associated with exporting or investing. Goodnow & Hansz (1972) has concluded that environmental factors determine the mode of entry used by U.S. firms to access foreign markets. This study tries to isolate elements of what Goodnow & Hansz (1972) calls environmental factors - political risk versus market size. The choice of market size is due to the conclusion of many survey and econometrics studies about the effect of market size. The author hypothesizes that in nations of high political risk, i.e. LDCs, it is a major consideration in the choice of modes. Firms would prefer to access risky markets via exports or joint ventures or licensing (depending on local regulation) rather than commit resources in the fOrm of FDI; hence, the greater amount of variance accounted for by political risk. So firms that decides to adjust for political risk and 114 maintain a presence in the market would opt for exporting. This mode of adaptation is fully supported by the studies of Root (1968), Shapiro (1981), and Robock (1971). Root's (1968) early work is particularly useful in supporting this hypothesis. "Once a company invests in a foreign country it has no choice but to adapt in some fashion to the political, social, and economic condition it finds there." (p. 76) He further stated that joint venture is an effective way to reduce political risks of foreign operations, especially in developing countries. Maclayton, Smith & Hair (1980) did not separate the determinants of foreign markets for developed and less developed countries, but concluded that market opportunity and political risk were two major determinants. Verification/refutation of this hypothesis will be based on comparison of the partial correlations (two- order partials) and testing for their significance. H6: In DCs, the amount of variance explained by market size in year t-k for FDI in year t is greater or equal to the variance explained for exports in year t, ceteris paribus. This hypothesis tests to see if the authors rationale is supported. Market size explains greater variance in the FDI-Export decision than other 115 independent variables in DCs. Political stability is usually taken for granted and therefore isn't a major determinant. of the :mode of' operations. IMost of the studies that have surveyed U.S. international executives overwhelmingly conclude that it is a major consideration. My contention is that significance is applicable only for DCs and not for LDCs. A ‘U.S. firm ‘will export to developed countries with low relative market size. Verification/refutation of this hypothesis will be based on comparison of the partial correlations (two- order partials) and testing for their significance. THE VARIABLES AND THEIR MEASURES Independent Variables Political Risk (Risk) Political risk is operationalized as the yearly perceptions of international executives on three dimensions: a) political risk index (PRI) b) operations risk index (ORI) c) R-factor (R-FACTO) Political scientists cannot agree on a definition for political risk and their focus of interest is not likely to produce the answers needed for international businesses. Political risk indices is measured on a 100-point scale indicating the degree of risk. While some studies 116 have used political events to ‘measure political risk (e.g. Nigh 1985), the use of international executive's perceptions provides a more sensitive measure since it is the same perceptions which the executives used before deciding on the mode of operation to choose. Studies by Bauer de Sola Pool & Dexter, Van Agtmael (1976) and Zink (1973) have arrived at the same conclusions with respect to how managers evaluate political risk. Kobrin (1976) aptly summarizes: First it is clear that managers consider political instability or political risk, typically quite loosely defined, to be an important factor in the foreign investment decisions. Second it is just as clear that rigorous and systematic assessment and evaluation of the political environment is exceptional. Most political analysis is superficial and subjective, not integrated formally into the decision making process and assumes that instability and risk are one and the same. The response frequency is avoidance: firms simply do not get involved in countries or even regions that they perceive to be risky. Last, managers appear to rely for environmental information primarily on sources internal to the firm. When they look for outside data, they are most likely to go to their banks or the general and business media. (p.75) The data for political risk; is obtained from Business Environment Risk Index (BERI). This index is preferred over others available primarily for two reasons. First the index is based on ratings by executives from companies, banks, governments and institutions with 117 extensive international experience. One criticism of other indexes such as Conflict and Peace Data Bank (COPDAB) is that weights are assigned to political indicators In! political scientists. Unfortunately international executives do not consult. political scientists before deciding on where to invest or the mode to use. Even though political scientists are in a better position. to assess country-markets and. political risk level, international executives do not rely on them in forming their perception of political risk. Bennett & Green (1972) have stated the need to use an index validated by international executives. "It is possible, however, that future research could be directed toward developing: an index: of’ political instability: designed for, and ‘validated. with, investment. decision ‘makers." (p.186) Secondly the BERI index is very current - providing data as recent as 1985. Given the rapidly changing nature of the international environment, the more current the more reliable. Also part of the methodology calls for personal interviews with international executives in 1986. Lastly the BERI index measures a broad range of variables [PRI, ORI, R factor] and the sensitivity of these measures to each other and other independent and dependent variables. 118 What follows is a definition of the sub-indices of risk: 1) Political Risk Index (PRI) measures socio- political changes based on eight causes [regional factors: global factors; political fractionalization: religious/ethnic/language fractionalization; coercive measures to retain power; etc.] and two symptoms [societal conflict; assassinations, guerrilla warfare, coup d'etats]. The BERI panel consists of more than sixty political scientists from around the world. Scale: 0 I ----------------- I ---------------- I 100 Most stable 50 Most risky 2) Operations Risk Index (ORI) is the degree to which complex operating conditions affect profits earned in the local currency by a foreign firm. One-hundred plus business executives from around the world use fifteen factors - labor conditions; bureaucracy; attitude toward foreign businesses: nationalization potential; infrastructure: credit availability; economic factors: contract. enforcability: local partners and. management: and other factors to rank each country on a scale. Scale: 0 I ------------------ I ------------------ I 100 Very Attractive 50 Least attractive 3) R-Factor is the risk associated with remittance of profits and repatriation of capital in a convertible 119 currency. Commonly referred to as remittance and repatriation risk is measured by computer analysis of data based on four sub-indices: a) legal framework - laws as written and actual practices b) foreign exchange generation current and capital accounts c) accumulated international reserves analysis d) foreign debt assessment Scale: 0 I ---------------- I --------------- I 100 Very Favorable 50 Least Favorable Market Size (GDP) This study relies on indirect measures of market size mostly economic measures . Reliance on this type of measures is due to the paucity of multi-country data on product sales and the historical bias thereof. Market size is operationalized as the gross domestic product10 of each nation and is measured in U.S. dollars. Although the collection and reliability of data is suspect, it is still the best available measure of market size. One might question the use of a single indicator rather than multiple indicators, however in many cross-sectional studies multicollinearity has been found between multiple indicators of market size for instance per capita GDP, GNP, GNP per capita, energy consumption, roads, 120 advertising expenditures, etc. However: data for two indicators GDP and. GDP per capita will initially be entered into the equation. GDP is to be denominated in U.S. dollars. This is the GDP of each market measured at factor cost rather than market price (this helps deal with the inflation problem). The original GDP figure is first obtained in the countries currency then converted to U.S. dollars by using the appropriate exchange rate. GDP is to be obtained from two separate sources; a) Statistical Abstract of the ‘United States published by the U.S. Department of Commerce and, b) The Yearbook of National Accounts Statistics published by the Statistical Office of the United Nations. This data will be interval in measure . Market Growth Rate (MAGROl The variable market growth is operationalized as the rate of yearly change of gross domestic product. Since GDP is obtained as a yearly statistic, market growth rate will also be yearly. The data for the previous year becomes the standard. used to measure an increase or decrease in the rate of market growth. MAGROt = GDPt - GDPt_1 / GDPt ; where t = year This data will be collected as ratio data. 121 Dependent Variables Exporting (EXPORTl Exports of domestic and foreign merchandise include commodities which are grown, produced, or manufactured in the ‘United States, and commodities of foreign origin which have been changed in the United States from the form in which they were imported, or which have been enhanced in value by further manufacture in United States (for further explanation of source and coverage of exports see Appendix A). The dollar value of cumulative yearly balance of exports to each foreign market is used. That value is denominated in current U.S. dollars. Data on exports is obtained from the Department of Commerce's export schedule E. Foreign Direct Investment (FODIVl The value of direct investments abroad rather than direct investment earnings or direct investment capital flows is used. Within this category only manufacturing FDI is used. Since U.S. DOC data measures outstanding book value, the flows of FDI will be the change in value of FDI. That value is reported in U.S. dollars and represents investments, reinvestments and divestments. According to Mrs. Patricia Walker of the Department of Commerce an increase or decrease in the book value of FDI results from the interaction of these three measures: 122 1) Equity and Intercompany Account Outflows 2) Reinvested Earnings of Incorporated Affiliates 3) Net Outstanding Loans to Foreign Affiliates The only source used in this case is the Survey of Current Business published. by the Department of 11 Commerce . The data to be obtained will be interval. DATA ANALYSIS PROCEDURE The testing of the hypothesis will be done using the secondary data exclusively. The primary data collected will be used for the sole purpose of ‘validating the results. Since the methodology involves pooling of time series (eleven years) and cross-sectional data (twenty nations), the first step is to ensure appropriateness of pooling of the observations. Bass & Wittink (1975) have demonstrated that pooling of the observations has to be appropriate if reliability resulting from the increased degrees of freedom. Also since cross-sectional variation is ordinarily substantially greater than time-series variation, the pooled estimates would have the desirable property of being derived from a wider space of variation than estimates based solely on time-series data. However 123 pooled, the estimates should not be accepted uncritically therefore a homogeneity test has to be performed. A homogeneity test involves a comparison of the error of sum of squares from the separate regressions (i.e. each country and each year) with the error sum of squares from the pooled ordinary least squares estimates. Two issues related to pooling are; a) whether or not pooling is appropriate, and b) how should the data be pooled? 1) Should Pooling Be Done? As mentioned earlier the test of appropriateness involves comparison of the error sum of squares from the separate regressions with the sum of squares from the pooled ordinary least squares estimates. If there are wide departures from homogeneity then pooling will distort the conclusions about the nature of the relationship. If, however, differences exist and are thought to be significant, but small, Wallace (1972) suggests accepting some bias in order to reduce variances. 2) How is Data Pooled? Table 7 shows the models that can be used to pool cross-sectional time series data. The model used depends on the assumptions about the slopes and intercepts. Three common statistical tests for homogeneity are: (Johnston,1984) 124 TABLE 7.--Taxonomy of Time Series, Crosssectional Models Model Intercept Vector of Slope Disturbance Term a Coefficients U. 1t 8 . . 2 1(a) common for all 1,t common for all 1,t E(uu;) = O uIn I(b) common for all i,t common for all i,t E(uu') = v IIa varying over i common for all i,t fixed effects model IIb varying over 1 common for all i,t random effects model IIIa varying over i,t common for all i,t fixed effects model IIIb varying over i,t common for all i,t random effects model 2 IV varying over i varying over i E(pu) = O uIcrE(uu') = V Source: J. Johnston, EconometriCMethod, 3rd ed. New York: McGraw- Hill Book Company, 1984. 125 a) tests for overall homogeneity (slopes and intercepts) b) tests for partial homogeneity (slopes) c) tests for partial homogeneity (intercepts) If we assume regression coefficients are fixed parameters, the pooling procedure is represented by the equation: IYI le El Y2 = X2 P + F2 = XB + E ...... 1 Y x E b Nd L Nd L NJ Y1 = X181 + E1 1 = 1,2, ... N cross-sections ... 2 where Y1 = Ti X 1 X1 = Ti X k fixed k x 1 vector III II E- = Ti x 1 random vector Under the assumption of fixed and common slope coefficients and intercepts which are not fixed, but random, variance components is the appropriate method. If, however, the assumption is that the intercepts are fixed then ordinary least squares with dummy variable intercepts (OLSDV) is the appropriate method for estimation. In this case the test of the hypothesis of equality of slope coefficients (Bi = BJ) is accomplished 126 on the basis of an F-Test with degrees of freedom K(n -1) and N(T - K) where: N number of cross-sections T number of time-series observations K = number of estimation parameters Bass & Wittink (1975) say that "it is wise when analyzing cross-sectional and time series data to: 1) test the homogeneity hypothesis before pooling the data, and 2) estimate pooled data with a variety of methods in order to determine the sensitivity of the estimates to the underlying assumptions."(p.415) The model to be tested is stated as below: EXPORT f(RISK, GDP, MAGRO) FODIV f(RISK, GDP, MAGRO) TESTING FOR MULTICOLLINEARITY Initially six independent variables will be entered and a correlation. matrix used to determine if multicollinearity exists between the following sets of variables: PRI, ORI, RFACTO [Political Risk Variables] GDP, GDP/capita [Market Size Variables] To the extent that multicollinearity exists, the variables will either be combined or dropped from the model. 127 The final independent variables will then be entered into the equation via backward elimination. Three Lag Models can be used; zero, one year and and two year lag models. Green & Smith (1972) have suggested that manufacturing investment reacts/responds more quickly to changes such as political instability than investment in mining and petroleum. So One and Two year lag models seem appropriate for manufacturing data. Equations for the lag models are: EXPORTit = BO+B1RISKi(t_k)-B3GDPi(t_k)-B3MAGROi(t_k)+.... EI(t-k) FODIVit = B9_B1RISKi(t_k)+B2GDPi(t_k)+B3MAGROi(t_k)+.... EI(t-k) where: i = country t = time of year lag period TESTING FOR RELIABILITY OF THE MODELS The reliability of the model will be tested through inspection of the residuals to ensure that what we have is a linear relationship. Durbin-Watson statistics will also be used to test for autocorrelation. Interpretation of the results will then be based on the multiple regression coefficients and significance levels. 128 The statistical package to be used for the analysis is SPSS' version 9 which is the current package available. The advantage of the regression procedure available in SPSS is the plotting of various residual variables. Thus verification of the appropriateness of the model through observation and analysis of the residuals is possible. It is reasonable to expect cross- section effects between the equations within the same country and serial correlation within an equation. Using pooled time-series and cross-section data model is then adequate and used for this study since it can properly handle statistical problems. Testing for serial correlation will involve the use of the Durbin-Watson (1951) test which is computed from the vector of OLS residuals e = y -xB and defined as: Ema. cl “ Z LCétt " ale-IL)- A 2 6“ th ‘ L The hypothesis of no autocorrelation is tested. using Durbin-Watson tables. CORRECTING FOR SERIAL CORRELATION The generalized differences method as detailed by Cochrane-Orcutt is used to correct for serial correlation. The procedure is as below: STEP 1: Regress Yi t-k) on Xi(t-k) to obtain residuals 1(t-k) 129 STEP 2: Estimate the relationship among the disturbance terms. We assume this relationship is of the form: eit = V8 Mat-I) + M* whereaue satisfies all the assumptions of OLS error terms. STEP 3: We then use the expression below to estimate P(rho): % ‘ a c . , I) H 1::2 "t “it” __ ~32 614*") STEP 4: Estimate the parameters (taking care of the time-series correlations) from the transformed model: \1: = 71-: ‘ hydra) L‘I’.‘ A XL: = Xtt "‘ PeXiLe—U STEP 5: This procedure continues via a series of Cochrane-Orcutt estimations until successive values of rho converge (for instance,p = .6791, .6795, .6795 . . ) NOTES Cross-sectional and time series data will be pooled. A minimum of sixty regression is run for each dependent variable in each lag model. See "Decision Rules" on page 103. Recordings are available from the author. This is determined by the percentage of sales resulting from foreign operations. 10. 11. 130 BERI stands for "Business Environmental Risk Index". Description of the index is provided in Appendix K. t=year : k=lag period Exports and FDI data are from Department of Commerce documents. See Appendices A and B. See Appendix K for description of BERI methodology. Appendix C provides definitions and explanations of National Accounts Statistics. Survey of Current Business (1974-83) CHAPTER IV THE SUBSTANTIVE FINDINGS In this chapter the results of the data analyzed will be presented. The author aims to present empirical findings rather than discuss the findings - the latter is left for the next chapter. As mentioned in Chapter 3 the results for all three Lag Models (Zero, One and Two Year Lags) will be presented. An attempt has been made to maintain consistency in the format used for presenting each lag model in order to ensure comparability. Data on the following variables was collected and analyzed: 1) Political Risk Index (PRI) 2) Operations Risk Index (ORI) 3) Remissions & Repatriation Index (R-FACTO) 4) Absolute Market Size (GDP) 5) Per Capita Market Size (GPCAP) 6) Market Growth Rate (MAGRO) It is necessary first to determine if all or a few of the six variables should be used in the regression model. When independent variables are correlated among themselves, intercorrelation or multicollinearity is said to exist. If a high degree of multicollinearity exists between independent variables they will be 131 132 combined or one of the co-linear variables eliminated. When multicollinearity among the independent variables is minimal (or removed by factor analysis), then we can identify: the extent. to ‘which. each. of ‘the independent variables is related to the dependent variable. (Hair et. al. 1979, p.36) The process of eliminating/combining intercorrelated independent variables ultimately results in a reduction to three independent variables [Political Risk (RISK), Market Size (GDP), Market Growth Rate (MAGRO)] from the original six identified on the previous page. The computer results are shown in Tables 8 and 9. Table 8 shows the initial correlation coefficients of all variables. Correlation is a statistical technique that measures the degree of association or intercorrelation between variables. The numbers in Tables 8 and 9 represent coefficients of correlation or the degree of association between each pair of variables. The starred coefficients represent points where multicollinearity is suspected. As a rule of thumb, multicollinearity exists if the coefficient of correlation between the two independent variables is greater than the sum of the coefficients resulting from the dependent variable and each independent variable. Observations of the coefficients reveals the following: 133 TABLE 8.--Correlation Coefficients Export PRI ORI RFACTO GDP GPCAP Dependent Variable = Export Exports PRI .17585 ORI .29684 *.77766 RFACTO .19754 *.52764 *.75538 GOP .60574 .23013 .29008 .32925 GPCAP .16359 *.81452 *.78708 *.64427 .32623 MAGRO -.00576 .00410 —.02997 -.00509 -.12330 -.10255 FODIV PRI ORI RFACTO GDP GPCAP Dependent Variable = FDI Foreign Direct Investment PRI .17715 ORI .16193 *.77766 RFACTO .12676 *.52764 *.75538 GOP .22241 .23013 .29008 .32925 GPCAP .00332 *.81452 *.78708 *.64427 .32623 MAGRO .26058 .00410 -.02997 -.00509 -.12330 -.10255 Key *: Implies variables with high correlation coefficients. PRI: Political Risk Index ORI: Operations Risk Index RFACTO: Repatriation Index GDP: Market Size GPCAP: Per Capita Market Size FODIV: Foreign Direct Investment MAGRO: Market Growth Rate 134 TABLE 9.--Correlation Coefficients Export Risk RFACTO GDP Dependent Variable = Export Exports RISK .17455 RFACTO .18715 *.71213 GDP .65918 .21541 .31738 MAGRO -.07397 .06311 .03464 -.15202 FODIV Risk ’ I RFACTO Dependent Variable-mFDI Foreign Direct Investment RISK .24461 RFACTO .18098 *.71152 GDP .28927 .21724 .31726 MAGRO .19461 .05296 .02802 -.15330 Key * : Implies variables with high correlation coefficients PRI : Political Risk Index ORI : Operations R1sk Index RFACTO : Repatriation Index GDP : Market Size GPCAP : Per Capita Market Size FODIV : Foreign Direct Investment MAGRO Market Growth Rate 135 a) PRI and ORI and RFACTOR are highly correlated to each other, and b) PRI and ORI and RFACTOR are highly correlated with GDP per capita. As a result of these observations, GDCAP will be eliminated while PRI and ORI will be combined and new correlation coefficients calculated. Table 9 shows the results of the new analysis. PRI and ORI have been combined to form the new variable RISK while GDCAP has been eliminated. The correlation coefficients seem to be satisfactory except for variable risk an RFACTOR. Therefore, RISK and RFACTOR will be combined. Beyond this point analysis proceeds using three independent variables: Political Risk (RISK), Market Size (GDP), Market Growth. Rate (MAGRO), and two dependent variables - Foreign Direct Investment (FODIV) and Exporting (EXPORT). The subsequent reporting of results for each lag model starts with the test for homogeneity 'to ascertain the appropriate method to pool the data and ends with confirmation/rejection of the alternate hypothesis. The four steps are outlined below: 1) Test For Homogeneity a) Complete homogeneity (slopes and intercepts) b) Partial homogeneity (slopes) c) Partial homogeneity (intercepts) 2) Results for EXPORT obtained through the appropriate pooling method 3) Results for FDI obtained through the appropriate pooling method 136 4) Confirmation or Rejection of Alternate Hypothesis LAG ZERO MODEL1 The Tables 10 through 18 provide a summary of the regressions run on the data allowing for no lag time. The implication is that investors react to the independent variables: political risk, market size, and market growth within months (1-12 months). As indicated in the 'Data Analysis Procedure' section of Chapter 3, the first step in analyzing the results is to determine if it is appropriate to pool all data for the purposes of estimation of one parameter. Since there are two dependent variables (Foreign direct investment and Exports) the homogeneity tests will treat each separately. In examining the appropriateness of pooling subsets the study uses three formal statistical tests - tests of overall homogeneity, partial homogeneity (slopes) and partial homogeneity (intercepts). The results for the first dependent variable - EXPORTS will be discussed. Exports Table 10 shows ordinary least squares time-series estimates by countries reflecting the relation between 137 Honéh ouoon n. u.“ unenduunuHm 36A 3....» n .3 3323630 n no. v a. o-~.nn ha.oa oNS.H- ea.nH- nn.H m~.on nano.n vooo. Hoo.Hu mm.mamHu «HucH omn6.HH vm.~m ham. . mmo.n- Hmm.- an.ma- mo.m oHsHo. oHo. ~m.omev oHuocoecn umv.~o «H.5m Hoo.H vsuo.q nw~.- Hso.«- ann.6H avqo. no”. omH.sm nocHnHHHHna ono.nH an.mo mom. mas.~ HHn.H men.no vo~.Hu Hsowo. vw~.Hu sm.ooa~u ouHuu: auaom uHoH.o cm.mp moo.H- vvm.v- om>.H- os.~v . n~n.v «ano. mHm.H co.mnn~ aHuuon cana.HH co.na n-. mama. nsvm.~- mm.va I nva.m aHsmo. ene.“ vo.o~om anon ammo.a~ ma.~a Hoo.H oo.mm nao.n- Ho.mno- nvwo.m aamao. oeo.n o.m~nen oono: unv.oH em.ao oo~.H amH.6H HHE. GHH.HH nanm.m cosmo. mmo.H- EH.mo~Hs .HnsoHoo Hem." ".mm amo.H va.mm oHv.H- mH.Hv- n~m6.~ mmoHo. HH.H o~.ma- HHuuua oan.h so.Ho Ame. Hoo.~ HHv.H- em.o~- n~o6.n aHHHo. am~.H om.o~s ucHucoou< uam.nv nH.ma on. v-.~H Hoe. . e~.mn- n~vn.m mmnwo. man. oo.vnHH aoeucHu uuuHca coo.an ao.va «mm.H- eHm.HH- QHN. mno.h naHs.o mmHHo. mam.- mm.omm- ocean» mo.m~ ~H.~o amom.n- -s.m~- «Ho.n- an.wo- anm.m HHHHo. maa.n H».~mne cHuam ons.HH H..Ho Hem. - smH.HH- mmH.- man.ea nHao.m oHoHo. moo. voH.o~vH sHauH omv.nn ov.no ana.~- som.H~- mam. has.mH nNHm.m Hummo. ammn.~- sm.~soH- acaHuuuqum o~n.a~ Ho.~m n~e~.v- mno.m- nHao.~ Hm~a.~ naom.o «ooHo. HHS. . ooo.o~H- xuaacoo omo~.H~ RHH.om avn.- ovsa. n mm. . oHo.m . nooa.a oHeHo. can. amo.eo~ cooozm uHm.~o mHv.oa noH~.m- moH.vo- was. von.o~ nsHh.o anvo. va.H «Hs.nm~H munaHuonuoz umoH.~n n~.na mav.- ~He.H- env.H- Hom.m - naqv.o emoHo. away." coo.mon snauoz ova. «HamH. Hoa. HH.¢H vmv.- n-.mo- vo~.H Hoeoo. com. moo.aoon scasnoo ouMom acoHUHunooo oumom ucoHuHuuoou oumom ucoHuHuuooo oumom ucoHoHuuooo 632 n ...m >358 86:. .32 a8 2328 ' I Hoop: uncouounn oouwh 39396 new noueawunm defiance—.3. 30:14: 393. 138 exports and political risk, market size and market growth rate for a fixed intercept model.2 The initial test is the test for complete homogeneity (equality of intercepts and slopes) for all cross-sections and is accomplished on the basis of a F- Test with degrees of freedom of 76 and 140.3 The critical value of F .01,4 76, 140 is approximately 1.00. The computed value of F under the fixed intercept assumption is 43.81. Thus the assumption of overall homogeneity is conclusively rejected. The test of the hypothesis of equality of the slope coefficients alone is based on a thest with degrees of freedom of 57 and 140. The critical value of F .01, 57, 1405 is approximately 1.00. The computed value of F in testing for equality of slope coefficients is 21.0. Therefore the hypothesis of equality of slope coefficients is also rejected. In determining the appropriate method to pool, evidence indicates that the intercepts for the different cross-sections are not equal. The question is whether to treat the intercepts as fixed or random. If we assume the intercepts are fixed, then ordinary least squares dummy variable (OLSDV) regression is the procedure to use. However, if the intercepts are random testing of the hypothesis, slope coefficients should proceed on the basis of that 139 assumption. This assumption implies that a zero intercept model should be employed in estimation. (Bass & Wittink, 1975) Table 11 shows the OLS estimates for each country on the eleven time-series observations for a random intercept model.6 The test of the hypothesis of the equality of slope coefficients is accomplished on the basis of an F-Test with degrees of freedom 57 and 140. The critical value of F .01, 57, 140 is approximately 1.00. The computed F for the EXPORT equation is 8.7. Thus the homogeneity hypothesis for slope coefficients is clearly rejected if an assumption of random intercepts is employed. The evidence indicates that if a fixed intercept assumption is made, pooling is appropriate and OLSDV is the correct method of estimation. If the intercepts are assumed to be random and slopes fixed, pooling is questionable and should not be done at all unless, using Wallace's argument, one is willing to accept a great deal of bias in exchange for reduced variance. Also there is some indication of systematic variation. Systematic variation in the intercepts would suggest that the assumption of random coefficient is inappropriate and thus on balance, pooled estimates are probably most appropriately developed with OLSDV. Table 12 shows OLS cross-sectional estimates. An inspection 1.4!) mm." A Gave... h .3. uneoaqnmimo H24. A Boo. ... 3 £333.53 n no. v on umm.m- ~mm.mm nho~.nu ~o~.oHu HHo.H mHm.h nomn.m momoo. uu uu «HecH uam.no ~m.em mow. honos.H owe. van.~ anne.m meHo. uu uu «Hmocoucn omm.mvn hm.mm nH~.H ovH.v ho~.u aonom. u nv6~.~H vmvvo. uu uu nocHaHHHHza u~m.mo ~n.oa mno.Hu mvH.oHu omN. pva.~ neem.m ammHo. uu uu auHuun zusom o~mo.ev mm.va «Ha. cosmo. mHo.u Noan. u n~Ho.n «ano. uu uu «Huoon uom.am om.ma mom.H nsov.~ «em. mHom.~ mam. «memo. uu uu anon uevo.ho eo~.ea nvmo.~ who.oHH oHv.u heHv.vHu ammo.v mama. uu uu ouonx unso.mp we.em mam. mvv.e vnm.u vHHao.v u nmm~.~ mmovo. uu uu aHnaoHoo ueo.m~H so.>m ammo.~ mmH.os vom.u moHv.mHu nooH.v HnnHo. uu uu HHuonn oaHH.on nan.nm o~o. HmH.n m~n.u mn~H.v u nvoH.m vomHo. uu uu ocHucooun oo.omn v~.om HHm. oon.~H oma.u Homo.eHu neoH.mH n~v~o. uu uu aoeocHu voana coa.omn H~.am om~.~u www.mnu Hmo.u omaen.H u nHma.a onHHo. uu uu vacuum uoos.oo mo.am mom.Hu HHm.-u GVH.H mee.~H nnmm.v ~mnHo. uu uu :Hoam uoo.moH Ho.mm Nae. u oo~.n u Naa.H nnan.o~ nno.e «HoHo. uu uu sHoun uoo.ooH oo.hm oem.Hu nee.mHu noa.Hu ovo.H~u neon.oH mno. uu uu ecoHuouuHam coo.mnv mn.oo Hmm.vu mHeo.e u nnHv.n mom.m nHao.m «mace. uu uu xueaeoo cam.va~ no.am «mm. u «Ham. u omo.u mnam.~ u nmvH.oH HSVHo. uu uu covoam one.aHo sm.am nHHo.mu an.~eu nHvo.~ Hnn.mv nEOH.VH moevo. uu uu neccHnonuoz umv.Hm~ mo.mm Geo. amHmH. com. oomsm.H anH.m mmmHo. uu uu scxuoz comm.o~ mo.mm «on. ooo.o~ HoH.u awnv.m u noon.n mmoHo. uu uu sausage onoum unoHuHunooo onoom ucoHoHuuoou ouoom ucoHoHuoooo ouoom ucoHoHuuooo oHuou n _ «a a a e a shunsoo Once: qum moo uneunnou Hoop: uooouounn aoonen .Hoh uOu noueeHu-u «OHuonoaHa mAOIu.HH mnm<9 141 26A ofiaunu 3 ufiozéfimu omo.~ A.ouoo. a u“ unuoauwcuam n no. v m a 6H.N mm.mn awn. vao.hn NHN... mom.0fil fiwNn.N meOO. mmwu mfifloanwH nmmn Oman," mumN HMO. nv~.~n Has. mmnw.0 nomN.N vnmoo. Hmv. vn.QQMH NQOH 00N0.w mo.nm ¢a2n vv.nnu ¢on.Hl wn.v.nHl Qfimh.n FNOHO. hho.n mvudv~nw Hmmu omho.n wu.nm Jpn.~ nom.~m Hmo.an so.mmu nflov.n vm~ao. coo.“ mn.vvmn omma Dvw.v mm.0v JNBN.NI ¢VO.MI nmm.l nominml nwo>.N vnmoo. NON...“ mn.Omov whmu owno.n n~.mm 5mm.~ nna.mo~ an. som.m~ nomm.n naooo. a~m. n o~.pnoun ahma owns.» n~.oo aan.flu on~.mvn «me. u ono.na u nmmm.n mmmoo. mwv.n hm.oo- shag omo.w ma.hm mum. n moo.onn Hm~. n meme.» u n~ov.n Hmofio. swo.n woo.nHmH who“ oven.o ~>~.vm mmm. noo.m~ nmow.n onmn.~ nNow.n vomoo. «mm. mm.vo~ mnmfl .Hno.m mn.~m mwo. u onnom. u nw. u mm-~.m n nuv~v.n vo-o. «mm. «on.s-a vnma ovmn.n oo.mm «ac. namm. mfim. u nwa.oH n nsH.v m¢oo. mNH.H aon.mao~ aha” «a 8mg. 230238 ouMum 232880 ouMom 5.3338... SMum 23032.8 canoauu>\udov ouwox xnwa moo ucouucou I gone: unannoucH voxau .nuuoaxm new aouqaauum macaquoomnuuouo m40ln.- manta 142 indicates that the magnitude of the coefficients appear to change more systematically with time. Pooling all the data will not provide any insight into trends and long- term forecasts. The above statistical tests provide evidence that the relationship between exports and political risk, market size and market growth rate are different for less developed countries versus developed countries. Table 13 shows results of the OLSDV corrected for serial correlation or the autoregressive least squares (ALS) model for both developed and less developed countries. It should be pointed out that the results of the two models (OLSDV and ALS) are very consistent in terms of which coefficients are significant. The sensitivity of the parameters estimates to the underlying assumptions of the model is low. Table 13 shows that market size explains significantly the variance in export behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms. For LDCs an increase in market size of one-billion dollars results in a flow of exports worth $2.361 billion. The amount of variance explained by market size is 35.733%. For DCs an increase in market size of one-billion dollars results in an increase in exports of $1.059 billion dollars for a variance explained of 53.59%. Table 14 shows the analysis of 143 TABLE 13.--Export Regression Results with LAG = 0 Constant RISKQ MKTSIZE MKTGROWTH R2 812.115 -18.49 .02361* 24.406 35.733* LDC (1976.39)+ (35.355) (.00316) (14.004) 2576.84* -32.969 .01059* —9.252 53.59* DC (774.074) (19.1474) (.009967) (11.944) *Significant at the .05 level (1 tail) +Figures in parenthesis are standard errors. 144 TABLE 14 .--ANOVA Table for Exports (LAG = 0) DF Sum of Squares Mean Square LDC Regression 3 285572265.93435 95190755.31145 Residual 103 513600944.99986 9986416.94175 F = 19.09001 Signif F = .0000 Multiple R .59777 R Square .35733 ADJ. R SQ .33862 Std. Error 2233.02865 DC Regression 3 522673342.66464 174224447.55488 Residual 106 452488317.17899 4268757.70924 F = 40.81385 Multiple R R Square Adj. R. Square Std. Error Signif F = .0000 .73211 .53211 .52285 2066.09722 145 variance table. What follows is an analysis of the results for U.S. foreign direct investment equation before determining if the hypotheses are confirmed or rejected. Foreign Direct Investment Table 15 shows ordinary least squares time-series estimates by countries of the relationship between foreign direct investment and political risk, market size and market growth rate for a fixed intercept model. The test of complete homogeneity (slopes and intercepts) is rejected based on an F-Test with degrees of freedom of 76 and 140. The critical F for the fixed intercept model is approximately 1.00. The computed value of F with the fixed intercept model is 43.81. The test of equality of slope coefficients alone also fails to confirm the hypothesis of equality of slope coefficients. In determining what assumption to make about the intercepts we test for equality of slope coefficients for the random intercept model. Table 16 shows the OLS estimates for the random intercept model. The F-Test with 57 and 140 degrees of freedom [F .01, 57, 140 = 1.00] is far below the computed value of 12.79 for the FDI equation. The evidence thus indicates that if a fixed intercept assumption is made, pooling is 146 35A 0.3.: u 3 0533.530 ~24. A 88. a 3 9533.58 n no. v no awn". flnmno. can. moomv. mam. c~s.~ «n. u nhoooo.n v-.n om.onv queen 066.6 «.mp ~no. Hoosw. hau.uu ~on.v u ~oo.au «Hooo.u ~««.~ ha.Hsn aduocoocn o-p.n mo.mo ma.” oo.~ vom.au uno.o u “o. noNoooo. mam." coo.as~ nocaauaaasa mmm.fl m~.vv mNm. nnHH.~ now. u onv.v u use.” amfloo. who. mpo.omfl ousuu¢ zusom mos." -.~v now.” meow“. nmo. homo. mod.” mouooo. con.u mmp.¢u cauooaz comm. o~.H« mac.~n ammoo.~u n.Hu cm.o~n uva.fi nonoo. m~n.u o-.o~o suom usuoo.m nm.«n awn.“ ~H¢~.o~ smS. u onn.~ou ”on. oeuoo. moo. nnu.~os~ coax»: nvv.H -.on now.” omm.~ cm.” ~ov.a oov.fi negoo. nnm.~u n«.onan «anecdoo name.” ano.~n sou. om~.n vmv.uu no.6Hu wag. u mn~ooo.n omo.u am.mn- adsoun usov.n mu.po pom." mama.“ ~n~.~u wom.m u mum.” «coco. moo. av.w~« «cauco6u4 ~m«.~ am.om spam.” cov.bm men. n ooo.o~u can. u ”Naoo.u ~vn. oo.-a conned: venue: om~o.o om.nh abnv.n h~.m~ nwmq.~u «no.6mn on”. n o-ooo.u .mq~.~ ouv.~ovfl oocnum sea.” oo.ov new. mNm. mso.~u man.mfln nme.au mflfioo.u ova." vo.oonn canon acme. mov.mn ova. oo.n nmo.u voo.vflu vac. n vooooo.u nfio. «65.nma saaua “aov. v5.6“ awn. vnhmm. vnm. mm~.n ham. u «HHoo.u nh~. vooo.~h vcuauonuuam ~noau. no.v «aw. u oomo.u an". mane”. hon. ovaooo. «on. mmH.a xuaacoo om~o.~ mm.~m new." Hoop. «on. n nvpo.d u n¢am.~u amaoo.u amv.u 'NH.~H« coc¢3m co.“ o~.~v «fl.~ ns~.m moo. u oao.p u ago.” vaoo. vov. mnv.mm~ aucuauocuoz umo.v mam.hw .Jnmm.~u mmq.mu mac. mom.” sham.nn oomoo.u moo.” nn~.~on >a3uoz hovofl. oswho.. «no. mop.HH om“. u men.» n and. u nouooo.n «av. hs.~v~ scqsuoo oumom acoaofiuuooo oumom ucodoauuoou canon ucoaoauuoou oumum ucoaoauuooo o«u~¢ a «a auucsoo anon: moo unduncoo - . dove: uoouuoucu vox«u .Hom uOu nouns—«vow acauouoauu. 30:64 392. o 147 36A 038 u u“ 05021530 8~.~A 2.8. ... 3 £333.63 n no. v QC ooum.m «n.0r oHv.. nvnvu. ova. nvoan. hNo. n avoooo°.n nn nn navcn anam.0n ooo.~m Amao.n «corn. «ammo. ”name. «00. I naaooo.n nl nn unaccoucu mmo.u -.nm mno.u m~nv~.~ 0mm. n «mann.n no. I Huoo.n nn nn nocaouuaaza um>.o o.mh mn.n mv~m0.u no. I thoo.mn mva.n cmaoo. nn nn sauna: nunom uvH.o ~n.m> Hh.m «bong. ooH.Hn houuu.n 0n.~ ovmaooo. nn nn dunno“: oooo. on.¢a non. n vnna. n nan. wuahu. awn. «noooo. nn nn anon omen.o Np.uh namo.n hum.m« «no. «Nana. o-.an mnnoo.n nn nn acqxot uwvm.o vo.nh an~.« ~o~.n nmn. mhhnn. hon. abnooo. nn nn cabanaoo unmo.~n na.uo wom.n m~o-.o~ now. n have.“ n Ono. «Naoo. nn nn awuaum ovoa.m 0H.Nh mvh.« hhvoa.u owo.~n 15m.“ n nhvo.n vanoo. nn nn anuucoou< nonv.v sv.no Amos.n mov.sm and. n ammo.“ n one. I mvwooo.n nn nn accusqu vouwco o~>~.v «o.no Annn.n vav.nn nvo.an vno.oHn mam. omvooo. nn nn vacuum mn~5.~ «n.0n vv. mans.” «mm. vonn.n «mm. n unmooo.n nn nn canon hnuo.u ov.ov owe." acua.o hum. onwa.n «go. voooooo. nn nn huoun ono.n no.0n non. canon. ~vv.« «vmv.v mo. n nvwooo.n nn nn unannouuaam 005.0 ow.oh no“. n homo. n Hum. noaan. wwh. honooo. nn nn xudacoa orb.” oo.ov nflo.u ovvo. 0mm.“ mvn.~ hmh.~n moHoo.n nn nn cooozm ownw.a nn.mh 00nn.n nnmv.o vmm. n wen.v n mou.~ hcwoo. In nn uvcdnuonuoz mmo.« am.ov o~m~.~n mowo.on 0000.0 wvm~.n noon.nn Vnoo.n nn nn s03u02 nvo.n m~.mn mam. Nom.n.n awn. wvan.h 0mm. mnvooo. I... nl r3030 0000 oaoom Swan 003043000 ouMOm 0:33:08 9 m ucoaouuuoou u. 00303000 0‘00: u «a suucsoo 0000: god“ 000 ucuuacoo 2.00: 008035 9005.. .3» 08 .333.» 63088.2. 303.3 305. 148 appropriate. Table 17 shows OLS cross-sectional estimate. The magnitude of the coefficients appears to change 'more systematically over time ending at approximately one-half the 1973 level for Bo. Again the relationship is better estimated by pooling data for LDCs separate from that for DCs. Table 18 shows the results obtained for foreign direct investment for the LAG=0 model. Table 18 shows that for LDCs, market size, market growth rate and political risk significantly explain the variance in foreign direct investment. An increase of political risk by one percentage point in LDCs decreases foreign direct investment decision by $7.818 million dollars. An increase of one-billion dollars in market size results in an increase of $1.01 billion dollars of FDI activityu For DCs, only' market size and. market growth rate are significant. An increase of one-billion dollars in market size results in an increase of $633 billion dollars in foreign direct investment to DCs. The amount of variance explained market size for FDI in DCs is 13.27%. Table 19 provides the analysis of variance table for LDC and DC. 2..” A 033 ... 3 0533.630 08.... A 88. a 3 0:83:56 14459 n no. v 0a was.“ as.on mem.u awn.mu neh.u mo.nn nmo.~u nmooo.n fine.” ma.ovu mama NAN.” «n.m~ ova. nom.n oom.u nano.vn novm.~n cocoo.u 0mm. ~o~.ao~ ~omH «Non. no.0 ova. o~mo.m amo.u vamm.vu «mo.u ooooo.u mom. omud.~flm Hood 0 am.o -.no omm.~ o~o.v~ onm.u amo.mn nono.e onnoo. 53¢.n aoo.no~n coma eon.” v0.0a «om. nomoq.~ mmo. va~.m mom.“ smooo. oov.u mn0.vo~n oboe .uofi.n~ H~.Hp on”. aommn.~ vn0.u mom.eu .0vn~.m ooaoo. man. ~00.ov~ arms um.H 00.nu . mon.u ham.~u oHo.u humo.u mm.“ cocoa. mw. noo.oo sha— ..n.o ~v.~o ”we.” moo.v Hav.u v~.«u nmflm.q unwoo. o~.n onn.mqu chad afimo.n mv.Hm s~v. oo-.d n-. Hoa~v. nHoo.n n~floo. 0H~.u vnm.o~u mam" ovno.m wo.om 00m.u homo. u mm".u hmovv. naen.n ”afloo. one. mnm.mofi who" umm~.o~ on.m~ vss.n 0mm.~u mmn.u mqumv.fiu naom.o avnoo. memo. oom.ova npufi oumom accouauucoo oumom acoauauuooo oumom unusuquuoou oumom ucoauduuooo Danna u «a canduuc>xuqo» 008:: xuam moo 0:000:00 H000: uaouuoucn voxuu .HOh now nouaaduna accowuoouanouo muonn.h~ mqm.oHu nmvo.~u «an.o-- nmv~.v fimvflo. nono.~ ouv.nomn aquocovcu no.“ oo.nn are. apnea. hwo.~ ov.q~ nu no msc.u no.~0n~n accumaaaanm ov«.ofl No.mm omn.u voa.mu nnH.vu ov.nuH- nmvn.o namno. non.n ~o.mamv auuuu< nuaom sflm.n ”mm.mn nv~. n mpg.” n wms.ao ao.nn . nmmm.n mango. mnp.~ ama.mman cannon: n~.~ «.mv nom~.~ -~.m~ aov. hm.m~ oh. I mo~oo.- om~.s «o.naon anon uo-.m mo.~h ma.“ hn.mva ma. u oh~.av a omm.H “none. mam. ~o.vm¢n ooaxu: awn. om.m~ «no. ao.H ~mm.~u oovnn.ov u «No. . mmaoo.n can.” sn.vvsn ouncodoo nv~.~ oh.on cam." v-.mn on~. can.o HNm.n cameo. oov. «oh.n~m aauuun amen. an.mfl an". . hflvwo. . vmo.~u noo.on u one. u manooo. mam.” mm.w~m~ «caucoou< okom.s o~.mh nmn~.n «mo.oH~ no.nu HHa.anu sown.~ ooHo. amnfl.n mm.cmmmH sococqu vouqca ommn.~n s~.nm mm. «v0.9 «mm. . mmv.o u anom.o anuo. mHH. u o~a.mn~u oceans nvfiwv. unm.w~ v. a ono.ou amo. . oo.~mn «mm. - venoo.u mwm.~ mn.«~mn edema unn>.ofi v~.~o nvm. mn.nH obs. wvo.n an~.m nooao. how. m~.mom sauna o~oe.~n mo.no ammo.“ noo.n~ How. - noHn.mu amo~.~ «ova. mno.~u mav.asflan ocuduouudzm «Hm. o~.m~ ovm. . mhv.v - won. I mom.ou mac. mvoooo. mn».~ ~h~.~mm xuoacoo «fiv.u s.hn ”on.“ ~n.v «mo. «no.m~ 5mm.” Hosea. moo. n hmm.nh u couozm usvn.mm mH.oo mmm.~- nom.~m- onn.~ hvm.mn n-o.- buamo. we. u ooo.vovu aucufiuoguoz vow.~ ~m.~v h~.H- moo.H~- aoo. “moon. anv~.~- osoooo.u o~o«.~ mmm.mvm sosuoz ummm.w Ho.Hm mac. ~osau. m-.Hn vow.ov u Ammo.v nonao. vs~.~ 5H.~o~a scuauoo OHOUW OHOUm ououm Guam osuum m mm a ucoauauuoou p ucoaoquuoou a unoauuuuoou a acoaoquuooo >uucsou anon: xnuz moo ucsuucoo . .fi I 0‘4. umouuoucu ponds .uuuoaxu uOu nounaaunu noauouoawe mAOIn.~n mqmcdfiuoo . uoo ouoom cauam m m oumom unmanauuoou ouMum occaoquuoou o a m ucoauwuuoou a ucoaoduuoou w . auucsoo ouoax xaum moo acuuncou AA 044v H000: unwououCH Banana .uuuoaxu uOu uouuflwuwu noduowflfiah maOlinnN Hand? 160 eleven time-series observations for a random intercept model. The test of the hypothesis of the equality of slope coefficients is accomplished on the basis of an F- Test with degrees of freedom 57 and 140. The critical value of F.01, 57, 140 is approximately 1.00. The computed F for the EXPORT equation is 108.26. Thus the homogeneity hypothesis for slope coefficients is clearly rejected if an assumption of random intercepts is employed. The evidence indicates that if a fixed intercept assumption is made, pooling is appropriate and OLSDV is the correct method of estimation. If the intercepts are assumed to be random and slopes fixed, pooling is questionable unless we are willing to accept a great deal of bias in exchange for reduced variance. Such variation suggests also that the assumption of random intercepts is inappropriate and therefore pooling under such assumptions will not provide any insights. Therefore data for LDCs has to be pooled separately from 'that of DCs. 'Table 24 shows that. market size explains significantly the export behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms. For LDCs an increase in market size of one billion dollars results in a flow of exports of $5.74 billion. The amount of variance explained by the two significant independent variables -:market size and market growth rate is 7.74%. However the majority of 161 TABLE 24.--Export Regression Results with LAG = 1 Constant RISKl MKTSIZEl MKTGROWTHl R2 21894.06 -61.1947 .00574 4.095* .” 7.74* LDC (2102.14)+ (39.46) (.00962) 1.811 2857.08* -39.56* .00962* 21.548 43.02* DC (803.22) 18.141 (.0011) (13.22) *Significant at the .05 level (1 tail) +Figures in parenthesis are standard errors. 162 that is accounted for by market size as the high T-score implies. Market growth rate adds an incremental variance of only 2.2%. For DCs an increase in market size of one- billion dollars results in an increase of $9.62 billion in export flows for an explained variance of 43.02%. Table 25 shows the analysis of variance results. The results for the foreign direct investment equation for the Lag 1 model will be discussed next. Foreign Direct Investment Table 26 shows ordinary least squares time-series estimates by countries of the foreign direct investment and political risk , market size, market growth rate for a fixed intercept mode. The test of complete homogeneity (slopes and intercepts) is rejected based on an F-Test with the degrees of freedom of 76 and 140. The critical F.01, 76, 140 from the tables is 1.00. The computed value of F with the fixed intercept model is 3.667. The test of equality of slope coefficients also fails to confirm the hypothesis of equality of slope coefficients. we therefore test for a random intercept model. Table 27 shows OLS estimates for the random intercept model. The F-Test with 57 and 140 degrees of freedom [F.Ol, 57, 163 TABLE 25.—-ANOVA Table for Exports (Lag = 1) Analysis of Variance DF SUM OF SQUARES MEAN SQUARE LDC Regression 3 621854ll.11293 20728470.37098 Regidual 106 275870101.46l99 2602509.83455 P 7.96485 Signif E = .0354 Multiple R .27824 R Square .07741 Adj. R. Square .05130 Standard Error 2644.12534 DC Regression 3 419588079.35353 139862693.11784 Residual 106 555573580.49009 5241260.19330 F = 26.68494 Signif F = .0000 Multiple R .65595 R Square .43028 Adj. R. Square -.4l415 Std. Error 2289.37987 1.654 an." A 3...: 3 £83583". 8a.... A 88. a 3 ufiodgcoqma no. v an 88¢. o.m Hhumun n.~n -.Hn om.un oHH.~ oaoo. 86¢." Hmo.a- nave" aoao. nu.nn «a.n mvunn.n mum. n mow.an mov.nn cacao.) mum. hmv.o~« aauocoucH 000.. oo.om ha." vmomo. n~a.~n wn.hn In It namm.~ omn.~nn nocamaaaanm coo." n.Ho Han.~ nov~.n wov.un pmon.mn vo.fl vvaoo. mm~.« 5mm.o«~ noduu< zunom “mo.“ o.~v vao.~n some". n .nmo.~n «cavn.n coo. oooooooo. can.“ ocm.om aauvmaz uoao.mo mn.nm nomn.na can.“ amnm.n vo~.m nvo.ou unnooo. n~p~.on ~m.onnn anon ammo.” no.vv onv.a mam.m~ gov. wo~.o~ nao.an ooo.n nan. n mn.oonn ocuxnx vnv. ow.m~ «no. ooo.~ onw. omen. wnn.u moaooo. «no. n ~n~.m n nansoaoo coo. m.mn ouv. nfluv.n on». n ov~.o n ova. n mmooo.n can.“ no.~nm Masque oovwn. na.vu on". nwvno. mac. n vo~.v n ono. n uofiooo.n and.” woo.nun acaucoou< naov. nom.o~ may. ”mo.na «an. n omv.nan cam. n m-oo.n vac. «v.moma eooocqx conga: oa.v o~.vo sown.“ s~.v~ “mo.~n nvo.nan “Ho.~n NmHoo.n omm.~ ~n.nm- oucuuu an." mo.nv on.” ufim.n ano. n 5H-.mn can. n voooo.n ono.a 8mm.omv :«adm vso.~ doo.nv noon.“ ~o~.un vvv. omm.n mac. n manooo.n awn. n o¢.~mn Sana“ umum.o~ o~.~o n~o~.mn ooo.sn mov.H abo~.n «mm. n ncooo.n as». omn.~m ccaauouuaam n-v. m~.n~ was. moanm. «mm. n noflp. n mmv. mosoooo. flea.” mona.ac xuuacoo was.” mm.nv nnm.an anvnm. n «ma. von~.n nvo.~n vapooo.n Ame. n Nom.vdn covosm H~w.a boo.” coo.“ moo.« new.Hn Ho~.mn ooH.m «00. ”Ha. n «mo.nn nvcuauozuoz nmvo. com.” o~. omvn.H nnfl.n anuom. n nvm. nooooo. moo. n ooH~6.Hn suzuoz mvsov. ~m.o~ vmm. mvwas. «an. as.“ no. n ~muoooo.n Hem. n ~oq.von scoauoo 035. u a Snow 233398 8M6 332380 oumom 233380 Snow £883.38 N >uucaoo cumo: xnau moo unauncoo . An Q¢A. deco: uncououcn noxwh .Hoh nan ooaaduum nowuonOBAH muonn.o~ fiance 165 mm.n h Oaucu m u« £393.30me SN." 5863 a 3 £333.53“. no. v A. 0N.w vm.ow nah. hnvwv. mom. wqua. mvn. voooo. II II uavcw ammo.n No.5m owv.I ovvou.I nva.n vu~m. nov.aI mnnooo.I II II nwuocovcn who'd. amu.n wam. oneao. mom. aummn. II II II II nocandanazm umv.NH vh.mh awow.n ouh.n mmv. I. voH.HI nnm.« «moo. II II auauud £090» omnm.v an.av «on. I Hmo. I van. «mane. haw. muaoooo. II II awuouaz ow.nn mn.~m Avm~.h muo.~ nmvm.vI moovv. I nub.w nanooo.I II II auom has.“ onén vow.” nonén m2..." marina Jn~n.~l «mmoo; II II 00:0: Unnn.o o~.mm Vnh. wmmm. new. mwvu. wm~.u waooo. II II canEOHOU ommo.nn mo.nm NN.H 500.0 an.H nNn.m nmu. I HmHooo.I II II ddfldun umvm.v« vwh.oo who. hfiaao. mam.u hnmmm.n wvv. I cmmoooo.l II II unaucuout mmn.u ~v.nn nvh. owv.ou mam. nvo.ma coo. I unHoo.I II II Eovocdx ooudca omnv.n Hm.om 85mm.“ nav.wN «mm. vom.vI hh~.HI ammooo.I II II conduh Unna.n o.am Qmm.n nmn. annmv.n NN.o owo.I v0noooo.l II II edema umH~.m nh.mw Doha.” unm.mn mvm. ~mH.N omn.I abnooo. II II hauuu oo~.o~ vo.mo nhmn.mn mmm.on nwb.n ovo.v ovw. moaooo. II II vcaduuauASm Dona.o o.wo ovo. FAAN. Nam. omnn. no." mmaooo. II II xudacvo mum.“ vn.vv hwo.un memo. I nomo.N aha.“ flaw.~I mflmooo.I II II cousim osm~.oH an.wh ANH.N ham.o omm. maa.n mas. muwooo. II II nucdduunuoz «woo. an.n mom. anmn.u “ov.I «moa. I Hon. mwmoooo. II II >csuoz ~wv.~ N.cv on.H mmm.v~ vvn.I hoh.hI mam. onhoo. II In >cnluoo cauam h «a ouMow uco«u«uuoou ouMom unoAUauuoou ouMom uco«u«uuooo ouMUm uncaowuuoou E58 anus: xoum moo ucuuocou . : 3 I 05. Hove: unwoucucu Bovcdu .Hah uOu ouqaauau nowuow aide mAOII.sN ounce 166 140] is below the computed value of 11.383 for the FDI equation. The evidence thus indicates that a fixed intercept model is an appropriate assumption for pooling. Also, the magnitude of the coefficients appear to change systematically over time. Thus the relationship is best estimated. using ordinary least squares dummy' variable (OLSDV) regression. Table 28 shows the results obtained from foreign direct investment data. This table shows that for LDCs only political risk significantly explains the variance in foreign direct investment. An increase in political risk by one percentage point results in a reduction of $6.539 billion in FDI flows. The coefficients for DCs does not significantly vary from zero as the non- significance of the T-ratios implies. Table 29 displays the analysis of variance tables for LDCs and DOS. CONFIRMATIONZREJECTION OF HYPOTHESIS H1: Hypothesis one tries to test for a significant positive relationship between exports and political risk for LDCs and DCs. Table 24 shows that the postulated relationship does not hold for DOS or LDCs. LDCs does show a negative relationship although not significant. 167 TABLE 28.--FDI Regression Results with LAG = 1 Constant Risk 1 MKTSIZEl MKTGROWTHI R2 434.935* -6.539* .000103 -.09545 , 3.867* LDC (180.45)+ (3.39) (.000369) (.18156) 237.24 -5.0759 .00369* 4.373 5.838 DC (156.10) (3.9144) (.000214) (2.569) *Significant at the .05 level (1 tail). +Figures in parenthesis are standard errors. 168 TABLE 29.--ANOVA Table for FDI (Lag = 1) Analysis of Variance DF SUM OF SQUARES LDC Regression 3 213678.98297 71226.32766 Residual 104 309366.89521 8484.964 F = 8.39442 Signif F = .0038 Multiple R .19664 R Square .03867 Adj. R Square .01094 STD. Error 226.00816 DC Regression 3 1299607.15459 433202.38486 Residual 106 20984780.80904 197969.63027 F = 2.18823 Signif F = .0937 Multiple R .24149 R Square .05832 Adj. R Square .03167 Std. Error 444.93778 169 It is important to note that the directionality is not consistent for the relationship between exports and political risk. Hz: This hypothesis tries to test for a negative Significant relationship between pol itical risk and FDI in both LDCs and DOS. Table 28 shows political risk is significant and negatively related to foreign direct investment for LDCs, but not for DOS. A negative relationship (not significant) holds for DCs. The amount of variance explained is rather small - 2.394% but is Significant. H3: Hypothesis three tries to compare the contributions of the independent variables for each equation. It is postulated that for developed countries market size explains greater variance for both EXPORTS and FDI than other independent variables. Table 24 shows market size with a T-Score of 8.745 compared to 1.964 for political risk; therefore, it certainly contributes more and the hypothesis is accepted for the EXPORT equation. Table 28 shows that market size has a higher T-Score (1.724) than political risk although significant at the .05 level (one-tail test). 170 H4: Does political risk explain more variance than other variables for the each dependent variable (EXPORT and FDI) in LDCs. Table 24 shows market size claims the greatest contribution. Therefore the alternate hypothesis is rejected for the EXPORT equation. Table 28 however, shows that risk explains greater variance than market size. Therefore H4 is accepted for FDI but rejected for EXPORTS. H5: Table 30 provides the results to determine the variance explained for EXPORTS as compared to FDI by political risk. Based on the results we can accept the null hypothesis and reject the alternate. For LDCs risk doesn't explain greater variance for FDI than exports. The results are not significant. H6: Does market size explain more variance for the EXPORT equation or the FDI equation in DCS? This hypothesis is designed to test this question. Table 31 shows semi-partial coefficients. We accept the null hypothesis and reject the alternate. U.S. manufacturing firms tend to export to DC countries with a large market size rather than invest. 171 TABLE 30.--Partial Correlation Coefficient Controlling for Market Size and Market Growth Rate (LDC) Controlling for GDPl Controlling for MAGROl Export FODIV EXport 1.0000 FODIV 1.0000 (0) (O) p = xxxx p = xxxx Riskl -.1254 RiSkl -.l314 (106) (106) p = .196 p = .045 (Coefficient/D.F./Significance) 172 TABLE 31.--Partial Correlation Coefficients Controlling for Political Risk and Market Growth Rate (DC) Controlling for RISKl Controlling for MAGROl Export Export 1.0000 FODIV (0) p = xxxx GDPl .6461 GDPl (106) p < .001 (Coefficient/D.F.)/Significance) FODIV 1.0000 (0) p = xxxx .1650 (106) p = .058 173 LAG YEAR TWO The three formal statistical tests: overall homogeneity, partial homogeneity (slopes) and partial homogeneity (intercepts) suggested that a random coefficients assumption is inappropriate7. The tests indicate that the relationship is different for LDCs and DCs. Exports Table 32 shows results of the export equation. In this case, market size explains significantly the variance in exports for DOS. The LDC model was not significant.0ne percentage point increase in political risk results in a negative flow of only $44.19 billion in DCs. Also in DOS an increase in. market size. by one billion dollars results in a positive flow of $7.8 billion worth of exports. Table 33 shows the analysis of variance table . The FDI equation results will be discussed next. Foreign Direct Investment These results are suspicious and no meaningful interpretation can be deduced. The coefficients are in the anticipated direction but the T-Scores and R2 are not significant. Tables 34 and 35 show the results and analysis of variance respectively. 174 TABLE 32.--Export Equation Regression Results [LAG = 2] Constant RISK 2 GDP 2 MAGRO 2 R2 6145.55* -80.128* .00151 -1.134 1.678 LDC (2.904)+ (-2.023) (.672) (-.543) 3165.01* -44.19* .0078* 27.28 14.817* DC (3.754) (-2.064) (6.321) (1.857) *Significant at the .05 level (1 tail) +Figures in parenthesis are T scores. 175 TABLE 33.--ANOVA Table for Exports (Lag = 2) Analysis of Variance DF SUM OF SQUARES MEAN SQUARE LDC Regression 3 36431971.46009 12143990.48670 Residual 66 477470112.2367 7234355.81240 F = 1-67865 Signif F = .1760 Multiple R .21297 R Square .04535 Adj. R Square .01834 Std. Error 2689.67578 DC Regression 3 28811696.71718 96039232.23906 Residual 66 427781010.0012 6481546.82195 F = 14.81733 Signif F = .0000 Multiple R .54356 R Square .29546 Adj. R. Square .27552 Std. Error 2545.88822 176 TABLE 34.--FDI Regression Results [LAG = 2] Constant RISK 2 GDP 2 MAGRO 2 R2 272.19 -3.405 -.000062 -.01319 1.14 LDC (1.502) (“1.003) (-.325) (“.074) 248.37 -3.44 .000193 1.84 1 65 DC (1.65) (-.899) (.874) (.701) TABLE 35. ANOVA Table for FDI 177 Analysis of Variance DF SUM OF SQUARES MEAN SQUARE LDC Regression 3 63048.46624 21016.155461 Residual 66 3466852.01000 52528.06060 F = .40009 Signif F = .7532 Multiple R .10682 R Square .01141 Adj. R. Square .01711 Std. Error 229.190 DC Regression 3 368683.88757 122894.62919 Residual 66 13645627.1010 206751.92525 F .59441 Signif F = .6200 Multiple R .12864 R Square .01654 Adj. R. Square -.01129 Std. Error 454.69982 178 CONFIRMATION/REJECTION OF HYPOTHESIS H1: This alternate hypothesis tests to see if a positive relationship exists between exports and political risk for LDCS and DCs. Table 32 shows we can reject this alternative and accept the null hypothesis. Exports is not positively related to political risk in LDCS and DCS. H2: This hypothesis tries to determine if a significant. negative relationship exists for' political risk and FDI in LDCS and DCS. Table 34 Shows a negative relationship between FDI and political risk for both LDCS and DCS although not Significant. Therefore we accept the null and reject the alternate. According to this model, FDI is not significantly negatively related to political risk. H3: Hypothesis three tests to see if market size accounts for the greatest amount of variance in exports and FDI in DCS compared to political risk and market growth rate. Tables 32 and 34 show that we accept the alternative for the export equation only. H4: Hypothesis four tests the amount of variance 179 significantly explained by' political risk. compared to market size and market growth rate in LDCs for the EXPORT and FDI equations. Tables 32 and 34 show that we accept the alternate for exports and accept the null hypothesis for the FDI equation. H5: The fifth hypothesis which compares the variance explained by risk for the EXPORT equation and FDI equation controlling for market size and market growth rate cannot be substantiated because of the results below in Table 3 6 . Table 3 6 shows the coefficients could not be calculated. H6: The sixth hypothesis compares the variance explained by market size for the EXPORT equation and FDI equation controlling for market size and market growth rate. This claim cannot be substantiated based on available results - Table 37. CONCLUSIONS In this chapter the results of the three Lag Models have been presented. In the next chapter a rationale is developed for the appropriate model chosen. A discussion of the results along with the validation of results via personal interviews conducted with international business executives will be presented. 180 TABLE 36.--Partial Coefficients Controlling for Market Size and Market Growth Rate Controlling for Controlling for Export Export (0) p = xxxx Risk 99.0000 (66) p = xxxx 1.0000 GDP MAGRO FODIV Risk FODIV 1.000 (0) p = xxxx 99.0000 (66) p = xxxx (Coefficient/D.F. ISignificance) 99.00 implies a coefficient cannot be calculated. 181 TABLE 37. Partial Correlation Coefficients Controlling for Political Risk and Market Growth Rate Controlling for Political Risk Controlling for MAGRO Export FODIV Export 1.0000 FODIV 1.0000 (0) (0) p = xxxx p = xxxx GDP 99.00 GDP 99.00 (66) (66) p = xxxx p = xxxx (Coefficient/D.F./Significance) 99.00 implies a coefficient cannot be calculated 182 NOTES 1. Residuals for each lag model was examined to determine the appropriateness of the predictive model in terms of: (a) (b) (C) (d) Based on detected Cochrane- page 128 A fixed the linearity of the phenomena measured the constant variance of the error terms the independence of the error terms the normality of the error term's distribution. the examination, serial correlation which was in some instances was corrected using Orcutt method. The procedure is explained on intercept model allows for computation of an intercept for each cross-section (or country). Each cross-section is computed based on eleven data points (11 years). Based on degrees of freedom of K(N—l) and N(T-K) This significance level is conservative and ensures that we are 99% confident of our findings. Based on degrees of freedom of (K-1)(N-1) and N(T-K). A random intercept model does not allow for an intercept for each cross-section (or country). The regression line is thus forced through the origin. The actual results of each cross-section and time- series for the fixed and random models are not included here. ’ CHAPTER V DISCUSSION OF RESULTS The purpose of this chapter is to provide rationale, explanation and validation of the findings. To this point, the place to start is with a summary of the hypothesis results derived in the earlier chapters as listed in Table 38. This chapter is organized into three sections. Initially a justification will be provided for choosing one of the lag models. Secondly, a written summary of the findings will be presented, and finally each finding will be examined. The results of personal interviews conducted with international business executives will be integrated in the explanation. Collectively they provide some validation for the findings. WHICH LAG MODEL IS APPROPRIATE? A lag model is appropriate because there is reason to believe that all the variables do not relate to the same time period. Thus FDI in year t could be due to perception of political risk formed in time t-l . In 183 184 N v v omummooa dance manomxm spas can» Ham spflz meMHUOmmm whoa copooflmm oouomhmm omuomflmm ma mnem umxume moon :H "mm musedxm Baas can» Ham nuw3 UUUMHUOMMM owuooflmm Umuomnmm cmpowmmm UHOE ma xmflu .muoa CH "mm mmuoq cw Ham Mow cmuomflmm monomxm Mom omuomnom muuomxm How cwuomflmm Ham cam manomxm mo ucm muuomxm How owumooofi Ham How woummoofi Ham How pmumwoofl Infleumuwp Momma xmwu mH new no m\OQ :a How cam Ham Mom omuomflwm Ham ROM pmummooa Ham new omummoo¢ muuomxm mo ucmcHEHmumc munomxm HON Umummoofl monomxm How pmummood muuomxm How pwummood HoflmE wuwm uoxumfi mH "mm moo “0w pmuomnwm moo How pmuomflmm on How Umpomflmm mMmam new Ham moon How owuownmm mung you cwumooofi Dog How cwummoofl comzuwm coflumaom m>aummwz "mm moo new pmuowmmm mood HOm cmuownmm 00 Mom Umuommom wxwfim cam manomxm moon you pmuowflmm moo How pouowmwm Dog Mom cwuoommm :mm3umm cowumHmm m>fluamom "Hm whom» 039 mo moo Hmww mco mo mmq mumww 0 mo can mammzuomhm mambo: and mouse Ham How mufismwm mammnuommm m>aumcumuacll.mm mqmca 185 deciding to use three lag periods to investigate the postulated relationship, the author was cognizant of the fact that reason existed about why one lag period should be preferred over any other. The basic question here is "how long does it take an international executive to plan, organize and execute entry decisions or shift mode of operations in a foreign market either by exporting, joint ventures, or foreign direct investment?" Certain factors such as: 1) difficulty of obtaining information about the foreign market, 2) nature of the business, 3) company's operational policies, and 4) problem of obtaining the necessary permits from the host country as well as the home country, will definitely result in some delay in entering the target foreign market or shifting mode of operation. Exporting logically as a lower involved decision would require less time than FDI. As is shown in Table 38, the results for model lagged zero and one year are similar. For purposes of interpretation; therefore, it should really make much difference whether the Lag Zero or Lag One model is used. The personal interviews reveal that twenty-four months or less is usually time enough to prepare for and enter a foreign market. One executive commented that the trend was to "build smaller and more efficient" plants that do not require much time to 186 operationalize.1 Another executive of a transportation equipment firm said it was necessary to react or respond quickly due to competitive response. "We have to act quickly in entering foreign markets . . . take China for instance, whom ever gets there first can establish a strong foothold."2 The conclusion therefore is that manufacturing firms usually can respond to information within a year. The lag’ period used. is therefore the One Year Lag. In studies where lag periods have been considered, a one year lag was deemed appropriate. Nigh (1985a) for instance tested three lag period (0, 1, and 2) and concluded that the one year model performed best according to his model prediction. (p. 9) In a later study Nigh (1985b) also used the one year lag as the appropriate model to investigate the relationship between flow of German FDI and political risk. The lack of a difference in results between the zero and one period models suggests that past studies that have not lagged the independent variables may be making correct interpretations. In Nigh (1985a), Lag One and Lag Two models supported the same hypothesis. But one year lag models are more adviseable for future studies utilizing more precise corporate data. What follows is a summary of this study's findings. 187 It should be noted that this study does not infer firm behavior from aggregate data. All interpretations are at the aggregate level. Therefore its conclusions are only tenable for all or collective U.S. manufacturing firms behavior at the aggregate rather than individual firms. SYNOPSIS OF FINDINGS 1) Exporting behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms is not positively related to political risk. No relationship or a slightly negative relationship tends to exist between the exporting and political risk. The relationship is the same for less developed as well as developed countries. 2) In less developed foreign markets a significant negative relationship holds between U.S. manufacturing firms investment activities (FDI) and their perception of political risk. For developed nations however, a significant negative relationship) does not exist, but there is, never- the-less, a negative relationship which is not significant. 3) In developed countries market size is the most significant explanatory variable for exporting and 188 foreign direct investment behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms when compared to political risk and market growth rate. 40 In. less. developed. countries international executive's perception of political risk explains more variance for foreign direct investment behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms . Political Risk does not explain as much variance exporting decisions. 5) In less developed countries political risk is not. 'more closely associated with fOreign direct investment than exporting decisions of U.S. manufacturing firms. 6) In developed countries market size has more of an influence on exporting than on fOreign direct investment by U.S. manufacturing firms. DISCUSSION OF FINDING Finding One This study had expected to find a positive relationship between U.S. manufacturers exports to country-markets with a high level of political risk as a substitute for the more risky FDI. However the 189 conclusion based on the hypothesis test is that no relationship existed or a slightly negative relationship for LDC markets with exports dropping slightly as political risk increased. Intuitively one would expect that as the perception of political risk in a foreign market rises, manufacturing investors would shift to modes less vulnerable to risk. This conclusion does imply that investors do not prefer exporting activity as political risk increases. Indication is that firms cut down on both FDI and Exporting as political risk increases. There is some indication 'that. joint ‘venture and licensing arrangements are common responses to political risk. The international executives interviewed overwhelmingly agreed that they would operate in high risk markets via joint ventures or licensing. The reviewed adaptation framework. (Root 1982, Agtamel, Robock 1974) also suggests that joint venture will be a common mode of operation. If that is the case, then exporting as a less risky mode of operation (as theory' will suggest) will increase as political risk increases. It. could. therefore :mean. that ‘while theoretically exporting' is considered the least risky mode of operation, (ie. less to lose) there may be other factors blocking it as an adaptation strategy-for 190 instance changes in exchange rates,etc. The term joint venture also is vague. What really constitutes a joint venture? If a U.S. investor and a foreign investor agree to enter a joint venture arrangement whereby the U.S. partner is responsible for only 5% of operations costs while the foreign partner covers the remaining 95%, that theoretically is a joint venture. But the scenario just described is definitely involves less risk, than exporting to a foreign market.Exporting typically involves loss of the cost of items shipped (exported) if funds are not repatriated. Companies that maintain elaborate foreign-based marketing departments are more vulnerable than. those that rely exclusively on export middlemen to market their products in the foreign counrty. In such a case joint venture rather than exporting becomes the least risky alternative. It thus may be that U.S. manufacturers prefer and indeed solicit this kind of joint venture arrangement as a means to avoid political risk. The U.S. Department of Commerce3 definition of foreign direct investment also lends credence to the suggestion that joint venture may now be a term meaning minimal commitment in the host market. The Commerce Department3 defines direct investment as "ownership interest by a single U.S. 191 investor of 10% and above." This percentage strikes this author as quite low given the definition of FDI as "full- scale commitment of resources." Also joint venture attempts to insulate operations from typical political risks (ie. takeover) by involving local capital and attaining local identity. A framework thus may exist whereby as political risk increases, U.S. manufacturing firms who export and those that invest opt for joint ventures and licensing agreements. As will be discussed next, exports is not a risk free activity. Exporting generally involves producing products at home (modified or unmodified) and transporting it to the foreign market. As goods move from home country to host country, payment, rewards, compensation flows in the reverse order. Recently the monetary flow has not been reliable nor predictable due to foreign exchange shortages and host government economic policies in the case of DCs. Repatriation of earnings may not be a major obstacle for FDI since the earnings, if restricted, can be reinvested. The economic objective of increasing the 'value of the firm' is still achieved when funds are reinvested rather than repatriated as earnings. Another consequence of high political risk on 192 exporting activity of U.S. manufacturers is the incurrence of unusually high costs of operations. These costs, as earlier mentioned, include costs of obtaining information, transfer costs, costs of product re-design due to change in product standards, costs of unsalable inventory, etc. Some may be costs imposed by restrictive govrnment policies such as tariffs and barriers that crop up frequently in a plitical crises or periods of foreign exchange shortage. These costs could rise dramatically in high political risk countries to make exporting a high cost activity - more so than joint ventures. The exports statistics used to measure exporting activity could distort the results in some cases. Those statistic4 includes government and non-government exports of domestic and foreign merchandise whether it involved a commercial transaction or not. Thus U.S. government food aid to a country such as Bangladesh is counted as commercial exports. Unfortunately the commerce department does not tell us what percentage of exports can be considered as government originated. Kobrin (1978) regressed an index of previous export involvement on LOG manufacturing FDI and concluded that previous export involvement was a prerequisite for investment in a foreign market. FDI, in fact, may be a reaction to "maintain existing markets after barriers to 193 continued import are raised? (p.117) If, according to Kobrin, previous export involvement is really a determinant of foreign direct investment, then a positive relationship should exist between exports and political risk, since exporting will be chosen mode of operation to reduce political risk. One aspect of the conclusions of the export studies is confirmed by finding number one. Involvement in exporting activity is not a hasty affair. It is preceded by cautious planning and execution. It is "gradual acquisition, integration and use of knowledge about foreign markets and operations, and on its successively increasing' commitment to foreign. markets." (Johnson & Vahle, 1977, p.23) This study does not however, confirm Cavusgil & Nevin's statement that "export marketing is usually considered to be the first step in the process of internationalization." (p.68) There is ample evidence from personal interviews that licensing and joint venture are at least equally used as modes of initial market involvement and as fallback position as political risk increases. 194 Findinq Two This study expected to find a negative relationship between foreign direct investment and political risk. A significant negative relationship was found for LDC while no relationship was found for DC markets. The homogeneity test showed that conclusions are most reliabLe if LDC and DC data are pooled and investigated separately. Also Levi (1979) excluded data for developed countries so as not to bias the relationship between political instability and FDI in less developed markets. That LDC markets are riskier cannot be doubted. The majority of nationalizations and takeovers have been 5 Recent studies that have reported in these markets. investigated political risk and Manufacturing FDI have observed some relationship. Nigh (1985a & 1985b) showed that conflictive political events was negatively related to FDI in both LDCS and DCS. This study does not make any distinction (as Nigh did) between conflictive and cooperative political events. However it serves to note that earlier studies did not find any relationship between the two. Finding number two does confirm Nigh's finding with respect to LDC markets. It is also not surprising that no relationship was found between political risk and U.S. manufacturing FDI flows in DCS. Interviews with executives in Michigan reveal that a different set of criteria might be used in 195 accessing investment decisions in DCS and LDCs. Political riSk was rarely mentioned when the executives were asked, "what factors will affect your mode of operations in your DC markets?"6 However, when the same question was posed for LDC markets, the response was different. For LDC markets, political risk was usually mentioned first, while maintaining a competitive presence, market size, and 'fOllowing the J0meses' were the most highly ranked influencing factors in DC markets. The conclusion from the empirical analysis and the personal interviews is that political stability is taken for granted in DCS while political risk is a major factor in LDC markets. Political instability (if it is perceived to exist in a host market) affects profitability. Green & Smith's (1972) conclusions were that while Mining and Petroleum FDI profitability' was. positively related. to political risk, Manufacturing FDI's profitability wasn't related. This conclusion supports the negative relationship between U.S. manufacturers FDI flows and political risk. U.S. manufacturing firms operating or investing in Western Europe know that the probability of expropriation and domestication occurring is very low. A shift in concern therefore occurs away from. political risk. to 196 business risk. The U.S. MNCS therefore is concerned with risks of producing and marketing a competitive product in an unfamiliar market. Market size then is a significant factor for DCs as the T—Scores suggest. All studies have attested to the importance of market potential. (Goodnow & Hansz 1972, Bennett & Green 1972, Kobrin 1978, Nigh 1985) Therefore finding number two is not surprising. This study, however, does take issue with those studies that have concluded that no relationship exists between political risk and U.S. manufacturing FDI. Difference between this study and those in the areas of research design, sampling selection and political risk index used, could partially explain the contradictory conclusions. By pooling cross-sectional and time-series data reliability is increased. (Bass & Wittink 1975, p. 414) Bennett & Green, 1972 and Kobrin, 1976 used cross- sectional data, a design which he noted thus, "problems are exacerbated by the need to evaluate a historical phenomena cross-sectionally."(p.37) Bennett & Green also acknowledged this weakness in their research design. Whether the perception of political risk by U.S. investors in less developed country markets is a true measure of actual political risk in those markets does 197 not really bias the conclusions. What is important is that these perceptions which are sometimes based on 'soft' data rather' than 'hard! data. do influence 'the actions or the decision makers. Ample evidence on in-house assessment of political risk was found during the personal interviews. In response to the question, "Is your firm involved in any systematic analysis of political risk before entry and after entry?", most responses were positive. When the next question, "How is the political risk factor in your country-market determined?", was asked the majority of the responses were that it was in-house. Much reliance was placed on information by executives of subsidiary firms already in the host market. Those firms not already in the target market sought outside source such as publications, other firms executives, etc.7 Executives do base their decisions on their findings which. bothers on 'gut feelings' rather used rigorous political risk analysis. It is therefore unlikely that the conclusions was due to the political risk index used. The conceptual development is fully supported by the findings. Most authors (e.g. Root, 1982) admit that some relationship can be expected between political risk and FDI flows. Cateora (1983) uses a broad definition for 198 political risk and admits that it will affect investment. Finding number two is also supported by the survey studies. Basi (1963) and Aharoni (1966) survey's reveal that political risk along with market potential are the two most important considerations for investments in foreign markets. The NICB 1969 study listed political risk as a major obstacle to private foreign investment. The conclusion is that political risk is a major factor only for LDCs. Findinq Three The survey studies (Basi 1963 , Aharoni 1966) have concluded that two major factors affecting the investment behavior of U.S. firms are market size and political risk. Some studies (Bennett & Green, 1972) have concluded that market size is the overwhelming determinant of investment behavior. There has also been suggestions that the influencing factors may vary for LDCS and DCS. In fact, finding two supports that contention. Finding number three tests to see if market size plays a more important role than political risk in the exporting and foreign direct investment behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms. Market size definitely contributes more than political risk in explaining exporting behavior 199 of U.S. manufacturing firms. It is not surprising that exporting is attracted to large markets of developing countries. To understand this finding, one has to understand the motivations for exporting. The personal interviews reveal that reasons for engaging in exporting are profitability potential and to dispose of excess inventory. It is possible the U.S. exporters associate a large market size with profitability potential. Green & Smith (1972) failed to establish any relationship between U.S. manufacturing profitability and political instability. It is possible, however, that a positive relationship exists between profitability and stability and market size. After reviewing the export literature Glover & Cady (1983) have commented on the motivation to export as thus: "Many firms began exporting with no definite corporate objective for the exporting program. Rather, exporting is a response to external stimuli such as an unsolicited order. However, among those firms which did plan an export development strategy, short-term profit was NOT a key motive for exporting. Rather, market diversification and long-term 200 growth - expected contribution to long-term profitability - were the principal factors motivating experimental exporting."(p. 8) Other studies have indicated that motivations for exporting are; adverse domestic market conditions, example, loss of domestic market share, or market saturation. The studies certainly support the position that market size and exporting should be strongly associated. We have already discussed why political risk is not a significant factor in entering developed country markets. For foreign direct investment behavior, again, market size explains more variance than political risk. This is indicative of the minimal role of political risk in developed country' market investment. decisions. Political risk can thus be a function of level of development. Its importance depends on investors perceptions about the level of development of the market. Political risk may not therefore be a discrete country by country phenomena. That is, LDC markets are perceived to be high risk while DC markets are stable. Piper's (1971) conclusions that political variables are of minimal concern to investors could be applicable only to DCS. Further the cross-country studies that have included all nations in their sample may be biasing the 201 insignificance of political risk in developed markets. Situmeang's (1975) conclusions could be interpreted in that light. Bandera & White (1968) found a statistically significant correlation between the U.S. FDI in EEC countries and national incomes measured by GNP. EEC countries constitute the developed country block used in this study. Behrman (1962) attributed this to a desire to penetrate the growing market which is defined in terms of level and growth of GNP in host countries. Scaperlanda & Mauer (1969) using U.S. data on FDI in the EEC for the period 1952-1966 collaborated the market size hypothesis. They showed that tariff rates was not a statistically significant explanatory variable for exports. Goldberg (1972) contradicted the findings somewhat by attributing investment propensity not to the size of the EEC market but to its growth rate. Unlike the contradiction which exists in the role of political risk, the studies on the relationship between market size and FDI are unanimous as to its role. Another explanation is that developed countries offer guarantees on FDI against political risks which are availed by their investors in many cases (Agarwal, Jamuna). This may mask the true relationship. 202 Finding Four So far the conclusions from findings suggest a negative relationship between U.S. FDI flows and political risk only in less developed countries and a positive relationship between U.S. FDI flows and market size in DCs. Finding four tries to compare the relative importance of the contributions of political risk and market size in the exporting and foreign direct investment behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms. It shows that political risk explains more variance than market size for foreign direct investment decisions of U.S. manufacturing firms in LDCS. However for exporting behavior of U.S. manufacturers in LDCs no significant explanatory power existed for political risk and market size but one did for market growth rate. This may indicate some LDCS in take-off stage are becoming "developing" countries. That less developed countries exhibit a high level of political risk is not suSrprising. More expropriations have been recorded for the LDCS than DCS. (Weekly, 1977) A causal observation of the political risk indexes show that LDC nations score systematically 203 higher than DCS. For instance the average in 1985 for LDCs using BERI index is 67 while DCs is 38 on a 100- point scale. Schwartz (1976) found that both EEC and LAFTA investments were significantly related to sales of U.S. owned foreign subsidiaries. However, with regard to market size hypothesis there were some differences between the two regions. Whereas the absolute size of the market of the host countries emerged as the primary external determinant of FDI, in the case of the EEC, it was the growth of the market in the LAFTA which took the position of the most important determinant of U.S. investments. Most Latin American Free Trade Association members can be classified as LDCS. Bennett & Green (1972) however controlled for level ,of development, but did not establish any relationship between political risk and FDI flows . A negative and non-negative relationship was tested for between FDI and political risk in LDCS and DCs respectively. Their hypothesis was rejected for both. They commented thus: "There is no significant relationship between the variables for either the developed or less developed nations in either condition. While this was 204 expected for the developed nations, the lack of a relationship for LDCS necessitates the rejection of the hypothesis." (p.185) There is conceptual evidence about the effect of political risk in LDCS. Since FDI can be riskier than licensing and joint ventures, it isn't surprising then that political risk explains the greatest amount of variance in FDI activity. In fact, the incidence of foreign exchange and repatriation of earnings difficulties is more pronounced for LDCS than DCS. Brazil, for instance, has a long list of items that cannot be imported. The need to conserve foreign exchange resources has prompted many developing nations in recent years to tighten controls over profit and capital repatriation by foreign owned enterprises. The constant shift in policy is a possible cause for the finding. Gerald M. Feldman of the Industry and Trade Administration's Investment Policy' division. has commented, "the shift in the climate for investment in most of the developing world was more extreme than that of the developed world, and the liberalization in many LDCS have been even more dramatic." (p.115) Such changes could have adverse or favorable consequences for investment. However it occurs too dramatically to be 205 believable. Peru, for instance, has made substantial modifications in it laws governing repatriation of profits, labor relations, petroleum exploration, etc. Zaire has reversed its earlier policy of widespread nationalization of foreign-owned enterprises, and has returned most of the holdings to their previous owners. (Feldman, 1978) Such dramatic changes do not convince U.S. investors of the non-vulnerability of their operations. Another issue is that. of market size. 'The 'market size for individual LDC countries (except for Brazil, Argentina, Mexico, India and. Nigeria) are relatively small thus discouraging' major commitments either' by exporting or foreign direct investment. Finding four also shows that political risk and market size did not provide significant explanations of exporting behavior in LDC markets. Market growth rate in this case was the major factor. Yet market growth rate has not played any significant role in explaining the behaviors in question. Some studies have not mentioned that market growth rate or market potential affects foreign direct investment decisions, but none have conclusively shown it affects exporting. Although the conclusions about the motivations for exporting (i.e. market diversification, market 206 development, profits) could rightly be argued to be highly correlated to market growth rate in LDCS. Absolute market size in those markets are relatively low, hence the emphasis shifts to the next best measure - market potential. The export studies have concluded that a significant factor determining the level of commitment, and interpretation of the outcome of experimental exporting was management's expectation of the value of exporting. Firm growth is a key determinant of export behavior for those that systematically plan for exporting. For those that started exporting based on an 'unsolicited order', continuation of the exporting activity could be based on the rate of market growth. A case in point is Nigeria that exhibited tremendous growth in the 19705 due to rise in oil prices (which accounts for the majority of foreign exchange revenue). During this period exports grew tremendously even to the extent of congesting the ports. During the same period FDI flows did not grow nearly as much. Although not all of Nigeria's exports and FDI were from U.S. sources it does show that market growth and foreign exchange availability could be sufficient to increase exports received by a host country. However when it comes to FDI, market growth does not play a major 207 role; but rather, perception of political risk does. The personal interviews did not isolate the differential impact of market growth rate and political risk on exporting and investment respectively. The smaller firms involved in exporting indicated that they were concerned about political risk factors even in the markets they exported to. Earlier on a case had been built for why exporting is not and should not be a risk- free activity. The conclusions here are that the findings can only be tentative. Perhaps using a second order partial correlation that removes the effects of political risk and market size from market growth would provide more insightful and conclusive evidence of the factor determining exporting behavior of U.S. manufacturing firms in LDCS. Finding Five In trying to determine the true variance explained by political risk for exporting versus FDI behavior it is necessary first to control or eliminate the effects of market size and market growth rate. A casual examination of the data indicates that country markets that have a high level of political risk also have relatively small market size while those with low political risk have high 208 market size. For instance in 1983, the combined market size of the LDC nations in the data set was $1,221,050,000r0008 (and this included nations such as Nigeria, India , Brazil, Mexico) while that for DCs is $2,786,800,000,000 or about 69.54% of the total.9 The average GNP/capita for 1983 for LDCS was $1,914 while that for DCS averaged $11,079.10 During the same year the ratio of political risk in the ten LDC nations averaged 61.4% and DCs 38.7%.11 Further evidence that a correlation could exist can be obtained from the studies that have controlled for market related variables in determining the relationship between FDI and some notion of political risk. Kobrin (1978) controlled for market related factors in comparing flows of FDI and focused anti-regime violence (one dimension of interstate conflict). Bennett & Green (1972) also controlled for market size (measured as per capita GNP). Although finding four shows that political risk significantly explains FDI behavior in LDCS, market size and market growth rate could be distorting the findings. The hypothesis about the substitutability of exports for FDI in high political risk markets is rejected if either or' both relationships are found to be insignificant. Although the null hypothesis was accepted the fact that a 209 significant negative relationship was found between FDI and political risk strengthens the conclusions of finding four. This study had expected political risk to cause U.S. manufacturers to substitute exports for FDI. The results show that exports do not substitute for FDI even in LDC markets (where it had earlier been shown to be a significant explanatory variable for investment). Thus exports and FDI as modes of operation do not substitute for each other in LDCS. The findings from the personal interviews are particularly relevant here. The international executives interviewed indicated a preference for joint ventures and licensing if political risk was determined to be high. The joint venture arrangement usually was with a local investor who was deemed to have political clout. The selection criteria for local partners sometimes includes intangible factors such as tribal origin or accessability to rulers. This finding cast doubts on the incremental method of involvement developed by Cavusgil and Nevin (1980). That framework identifies exporting as the first activity in foreign. market involvement. Increasingly executives favor joint ventures or licensing as modes of 210 initial involvement and adjustment to political risk. Although Goodnow & Hansz (1972) used a multi- indicator model, the findings of this study casts doubt on their conclusions. According to Goodnow & Hansz (1972), "As firms move from 'Hot' to 'Cold' country clusters, they move away from the use of licenses and joint ventures partners while they make significant greater ‘use of strategies involving' decreased control over sales such as overseas agents and distributors as well as U.S. based intermediaries." (p.45) A cold country in the Goodnow & Hansz study is one that is low on market opportunitylz, low on political stability'13 low on cultural unity, high on legal barriers and high on geocultural distance. Root (1982) relied on Goodnow & Hansz's study in stating that "a company ordinarily initiates international business with a low-risk entry mode, which is almost always some form of export . . . , alternative modes are considered only if exporting is not possible." (p.179) Root describes this approach as the "pragmatic rule". This study suggests that the pragmatic rule doesn't always seem to apply to U.S. manufacturing firm's strategies in LDC markets for exports and FDI. It is not clear what Root means by low risk, but he makes references to political risk (p.65) and states that 211 exporting is a learning experience. Learning experience is supposed to reduce vulnerability to political risk. The relationship between perceived risk and experience is shown in Figure 14. Learning could conceivably reduce business risks, but not political risk. The contractual entry modes accordingly should be used "when exports were no longer possible to a target market with the sudden imposition of tariffs or quotas or when exports were no longer profitable with the appearance of more intense competition." (p.97) This finding suggests that licensing and other intermediate modes may be used more often as entry and operation modes than the literature suggests. Since licensing and joint ventures may involve lower political risk than foreign investment or exporting. Also licensing and joint venture has been used as low risk vehicle to serve U.S. firms in foreign markets during periods of instability. The executives interviewed indicated that the primary disadvantage of licensing (i.e. loss of patent rights) after a number of years is not a major consideration. To license, a company has to have a technology, trademark, or a company name that is attractive to potential foreign users. (Root 1982, p.68) The executives said that usually they enter into licensing agreements for periods that are considered to 212 time—I Perceived rietas camxued tomm .mH wusmfim nus-Iona!— vacuum 9530.. 3.01600 «0 5331.393— conuluesq «33.33250 Inauoauu-ou tog a!“ can Eng-anus: unsung 00.150- 313 :31 :8 33:029-2— 8.3.4538 sedanguuusu i509 noun-Juan cogs-in. . 30938 onus- uxl 03009:» nus-Infidnvou acoucoo 303 J .2638» condo £2.95 a on: ax: 3: 3.338 ..- uuagoo 39598 a .3033». ex: undone 00934 395.50 «aqua 0503.— E #0.» no ouch :53: conga.“ wanna A fiasco-um.” 9:95.25.“ H335" noun-nu Aaouufiom . m 62323de 263‘s and. I can; . F?.....Bu..I 22.52: 'W) :3 . - - — um:— * r as. as: 5...... (.1 _...I§§ .... 42...... If i) 9.68:: .292. 6a.. 1 3483*. _I|I|I_§. )_n w ..fl aim M, ..-: T... u. 1 T P UZHHROAXH Egg __ ad mzozéuno nngmux m: 23.3.30.— — firms 8 a8: — L Ego .. 6252328 “Gaussian .3 g .8 ago: '1 GLOSSARY OF TERMS FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT Refers to acquisition by domestic companies of foreign-based operating facilities, such as factories, hotels, banks. The investor buys specific tangible assets that possess the capacity to produce either goods or services outside the investors home country. It represents a commitment that is not only long term but that also implies managerial control over assets or enterprise (Kolde, ). The Department of Commerce defines FDI as equity investment over ten-percent. MANUFACTURING FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT FDI that relates to manufacturing only. It includes the following industries: food products, chemicals and allied products, primary and fabricated metals, machinery, transportation equipment. MODE OF ENTRY Any institutional arrangement that makes possible the entry of a company's products, technology, human skills management, or other resources into a foreign country. (Root, 1982 p. 5) 226 227 MODE OF OPERATIONS Subsequent modes used to maintain presence in a foreign market after initial entry. MODE OF INVOLVEMENT Same as mode of entry. EXPORTING A behavior or process by which a firms products is moved across national boundaries. EXPORTS The product(s) a firm moves across boundaries. It is a result of exporting, and typically measured in dollars. LESS DEVELOPED AND DEVELOPED COUNTRIES A general term used to classify nations based on such measures as income per capita, literacy rate, productivity levels, cultural unity, etc. The United Nations 'Group of 77' is often referred to as less developed while the Western nations are referred to as developed. 228 POLITICAL RISK The subjective probability that certain political decisions will be taken (or certain political events will occur) which will perceptibly change the business environment. (Cracco, 1972) POLITICAL INSTABILITY Destabilizing events or actions in a foreign country. POLITICAL EVENTS An occurrence or action usually government initiated that affects firms operation in a foreign market. INCREMENTAL SCHOOL An academic school of thought that views modes of entry as involving gradual and incremental commitment of resources. They postulate that a firm will enter a foreign market via exporting and ultimately invest. STRATEGIC SCHOOL An academic school of thought that views modes of entry as a function of certain factors. According to the strategic school, a firm will enter a foreign market via either mode. 229 CROSS-COUNTRY Studies that have used countries rather than firms as their sample. Usually aggregate data is collected and analyzed. CROSS-FIRM Studies that use firms, rather than countries as their sample. Usually data is collected through personal interviews and/or questionnaires. BUSINESS RISK Risks associated with the consumers and operations. COUNTRY-MARKET A term used when a country is treated as a separate market for analytical purposes. APPENDICES 230 APPENDIX A EXPORT DATA Coverage The export statistics reflect, in general, both government and non-government exports of domestic and foreign merchandise including non-monetary gold and silver from the U.S. Customs territory (includes the fifty states, the District of Columbia, and Puerto Rico) and the U.S. Virgin Islands to foreign countries, 'whether' the export involved a commercial transaction or not. Excluded from the statistic are: 1) shipments to U.S. Armed Forces and diplomatic missions abroad for their own use; 2) shipments between the United States and Puerto Rico and. the U.S. and its possessions (including’ the ‘Virgin Islands), and between these outlying areas: 3) exports from U.S. possessions; 4) intransit shipments through the United States when documented as such with customs, and 5) transactions not considered to be of statistical importance such as personal and household effects, temporary exports, low-valued or non-commercial exports by mail and issued monetary coins of all component metals. 231 APPENDIX A (cont'd.) Exports of domestic merchandise refers to commodities which are grown, produced or manufactured in the United States, and commodities of foreign origin which have been changed in the United States from the form in which they were imported, or which have been enhanced in value by further manufacture in the United States. Exports of foreign merchandise consists of commodities of foreign origin which have entered the United States as imports and which, at the time of exportation, are in substantially the same condition as when imported. Source The official U.S. export statistics are compiled by the Bureau of the Census primarily from copies of shipper's export declarations. The month of exportation is generally based on the date when shipments leave the United States. (For vessel or air shipments it is the date when the carrier departs or is cleared from the port of export). However due to processing problems there is an average carryover of about 3 to 4 percent (in terms of value) of the shipments from the actual month of exportation to a subsequent month, usually the succeeding month. 232 APPENDIX A (cont'd.) Valuation The value reported is the equivalent to a f.a.s. (free alongside ship) at the U.S. port of export, based on the transactions price, including inland freight, insurance and other charges in placing the merchandise alongside the carrier at the U.S. port of exportation. Country of Destination The country of destination is defined as the country of ultimate destination or the country where the goods are to be consumed, further processed, or manufactured, as known to the shipper at the time of exportation. Errors Effective from March 1979 statistics, data for shipments value $501 - $999 (formerly $251 - $999) are estimated based on a 50% sample of such shipments. Sampling errors can generally be expected to be less than 2% fOr value totals over ten-million dollars and less than 2% for value totals between three-million and ten-million dollars. The sampling error will almost always be less than possible errors due to rounding. 233 APPENDIX A (cont'd.) Sources of Errors Sources of error include the reporting and/or processing of information as to commodity classification. However, the procedures used to compile both the import and export statistics include clinical and computer processing checks designed to protect the accuracy of the statistics to the fullest practicable extent. Citation Ft 410, U.S. Exports, Schedule E, Commodity by Country, U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (Washington D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office) years 1973-83 234 APPENDIX B U.S. INVESTMENT ABROAD According to the Bureau of Economic Analysis, DOC investment is of two kinds: direct and portfolio. Direct investment is defined strictly from the viewpoint of a primary or controlling equity owner. An interest of a U.S. person of less than 10% is not counted as part of direct investment but rather as portfolio investment. DEFINITION From 1950 to 1961 direct investment was defined as; 1) ownership by a single U.S. investor (including an associated group of investors) or at least 25% of the voting interest in a foreign business enterprise, or 2) ownership, by several U.S. investors collectively, of at least 50% of the voting interest in a publicly held foreign business enterprise in which no one U.S. investor owned as much as 25%. In a few instances, interests of slightly less than 25% are included where important management relationships were known to be associated with the interests. Beginning in 1962, all ownership 235 APPENDIX B (cont'd.) interests by a single U.S. investor of 10-25% were also included in direct investment. In 1970-71, the only two publicly held affiliates of significance were dropped from the direct investment universe because the 50 percent criteria was no longer met. Since then, that criteria has not been used in defining direct investment. COVERAGE Collection of direct investment, unlike exports, is not based on estimate; but rather, it is a census intended to cover the investment universe. Reports are obtained form U.S. parent companies and their foreign affiliates. Universe estimates were computed for each country- industry cell shown in the published tables. Universe estimates of interest, dividends, earnings of unincorporated affiliates, royalties and license fees, service changes and rentals are usually collected. The presentation format shows data on the U.S. direct investment position abroad, equity and intercompany account outflows, and reinvested earnings of incorporated foreign affiliates. Data on direct investment position is further broken down into: 1) Manufacturing, which has recently been divided into six industry groups, a. food products 2) 3) 4) 5) 6) 7) 236 APPENDIX B (cont'd.) b. chemicals and allied products c. primary and fabricated metals d. machinery e. transportation f. equipment Mining and Smelting Petroleum Transportation Communication and Public Utilities Trade Etc. The primary document utilized in this dissertation is: Survey of Current Business, U.S. Dept. of Commerce (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974-83) 237 APPENDIX C NATIONAL ACCOUNTS STATISTICS DEFINITION GDP at market prices is the market value of the product, before deduction of provisions for the consumption of fixed capital, attributable to factor services rendered to resident producers of the given country. It is identically equal to the sum of consumption expenditure and gross domestic capital formation, private and public, and the net exports of goods and services of the given country. It differs from the gross national product at market prices by the exclusion of net factor incomes received from abroad. GDP at factor cost is the value at factor cost of the product, before deduction of provisions for the consumption of fixed capital, attributable to factor services rendered to resident producers of the given country. It differs from the gross domestic product at market prices by the exclusion of the excess of indirect taxes over subsidies. The form and concepts of the statistical tables generally conform, for countries with market economies, 238 APPENDIX c (cont'd.) to the recommendations in A SYSTEM OF NATIONAL ACCOUNTS, STUDIES IN METHODS, Series F, No. 2, Rev. 3. To compile the large volume of national accounts data, the statistical office of the United Nations each year sends to countries and areas with market economies a national accounts questionnaire requesting recipients to indicate where the scope and coverage of the country estimates differ for conceptual and statistical reasons from the definitions and classifications recommended in the SNA. The basic data is obtained at current price series and is converted into U.S. dollars and per capita levels by respectively applying the corresponding exchange rates and population figures. THE UNITED NATIONS SYSTEM OF ACCOUNTS IN PRACTICE In A System of National Accounts and Supporting Tables the hypothetical system of nine standard accounts obtained by setting up three accounts for each of these sectors is for practical reasons modified in a number of ways. These modifications both simplify the presentation and concentrate attention on the formation of the more important national aggregates. As a result, the system of accounts presented in the report appears as follows: Account 1. Domestic product. This account is essentially the consolidated production account of the economy. 239 APPENDIX c (cont'd.) Account 2. National income. This account shows the national income as a redistribution of the value added in production and is largely a consolidation of the appropriation accounts of enterprises. Account 3. Domestic capital formation. This account represents the consolidated capital reconciliation account of enterprises. In addition to the capital formation of enterprises proper, it includes that undertaken on behalf of households, private non-profit institutions and general government agencies. Account 4. Households and non-profit institutions. This account is divided into two parts, a current account, and a capital reconciliation account. Capital formation undertaken on behalf of households and non—profit institutions together with that of unincorporated enterprises is recorded as capital formation taking place in the enterprise sector (Account 3) financed by a transfer from the present capital reconciliation account. Account 5. General government. As with households this account is divided into two parts, a current account corresponding to an appropriation account, and a capital reconciliation account. The treatment of capital formation, in this case on behalf of general government, is also similar. Account 6. External transactions. This is a supplementary account bringing together all transactions with non-residents. It is divided into a current account and a capital reconciliation account for recording separately external transactions appearing on the current and capital reconciliation accounts of the individual sectors. THE STANDARD ABLES The system of supporting tables outlined in the report constitutes a tabular rearrangement of the system of 240 APPENDIX C (cont'd.) accounts itself, supplemented by detailed classifications of the major flows. The tables presented for various countries in this publication follow closely this system of supporting tables. 241 APPENDIX D COUNTRIES SELECTED FOR THE STUDY COUNTRY LESS DEVELOPED DEVELOPED Argentina X Brazil X Colombia X Denmark X France x Germany X India X Indonesia X Italy X Mexico X Netherlands X Nigeria X Norway X Peru X Phillipines X South Africa X Spain X Sweden X Switzerland X United Kingdom X 242 APPENDIX E LETTER OF INVITATION SENT TO COMPANIES Department of Marketing and Transportation Admin. East Lansing, MI 48824-1121 January 22, 1986 ADDRESS Dear Mr. : I am currently researching the degree to which exports, licensing, joint ventures, and foreign direct investments are emphasized by U.S. manufacturing firms in foreign markets with high political risk. This is part of my dissertation for the doctorate degree in Marketing at Michigan State University. I am also interested in other factors that will determine the mode of operations used in your foreign markets. My research design involves conducting personal interviews with Michigan businesses active in the international marketplace and your firm has been chosen based on a set of criteria as part of the sample. I would therefore like to ascertain your willingness to participate in this survey. The personal interviews will last between 60-90 minutes and will be conducted in the months of April and May, 1986. The specific days will be Monday, Wednesday, or Friday. This research promises to contribute to theory and practice in this important strategic choice decision area. You will NOT be required to disclose any confidential company information as I am concerned mainly with your perceptions. Please find enclosed a response sheet and a self addressed stamped return envelope. Your immediate response will be appreciated. Thank you. Yours sincerely, Sam Okoroafo 243 APPENDIX F RESPONSE SHEET ENCLOSED WITH LETTER A. YES, I am interested and will be available in APRIL for a personal interview. Call me to set up an appointment. NAME OF INTERVIEWEE TELEPHONE NUMBER * Please enclose any background information if available. B. NO, I am not interested and will not be available in APRIL for a personal interview. COMMENTS 244 APPENDIX G FOLLOW-UP LETTER Department of Marketing and Transportation Admin. 315 Eppley Center Michigan State University East Lansing, MI 48824-1121 February 15, 1986 ADDRESS Dear Mr. Last month I wrote you a letter requesting a personal interview in April. Unfortunately I have not received any reply. To refresh you, I am investigating the degree to which exports, licensing, joint ventures and foreign direct investment are emphasized by U.S. manufacturing firms in high versus low risk country-markets. This is part of my dissertation for the doctorate degree in Business Administration. The interview will last between 60-90 minutes and will be conducted in the month of April on a Monday, Wednesday or Friday. I would kindly appreciate your letting me know your decision one way or the other in order for me to plan ahead. Please disregard this letter if you have already responded. Thanks very much for your time. Yours sincerely Sam Okoroafo 245 APPENDIX H.--Interview Schedule Name and Location of No. of Name and Position of Date, Time of Business Employees Interviewee Appointment 1. Asgrow Seed 1,000 Earl L. Burkybile 4/8/86 Corporation Product Manager 1 p.m. Sub. of Upjohn Int'l Division Company 2. Motor Wheel Inc. 1,200 A. N. McCotter 4/10/86 Lansing, MI. Vice President 2 p.m. Sub. of Goodyear Marketing & Sales Tire & Rubber Co. 3. Baker Perkins Inc. 750 John T. Gallagher 4/16/86 Saginaw President 10 a.m. 4. Duramettalic Corp. 563 James S. Ware 4/21/86 Kalamazoo Chairman & CEO 9 a.m. 5. Durametallic Corp. 563 4/21/86 Kalamazoo Foreign OperatiOHS 12:30 p.m. Manager 6. Fruehauf Int'l Ltd. 36,000 Joe Mack, II 4/25/86 Detroit President & CEO 9:30 a.m. 7. Ex-Cell-O Corp. 16,000 David Riechard 5/6/86 Troy Vice President 2 p.m. Export Operations 8. Newcor, Inc. 700 Clifford 0. Bath, Jr. 5/6/86 Troy President 3:30 p.m. 246 .osH .COADMOAanm mmmcflmsm pauo3eco .sowuwom sum .Hmmsd .A Hms0>sh >0 UDHAQEOU .mwfiuucsoo smflmuom ca meuwh snowH0E< m0 uouomuflo .m .ufiouumo ..UcH mcowumoflansm xowm .>uouomuwo muonsuommscmz Goodnow: .H “condom cowaafin MHOOB osfinomz MD .mocmHumsuoz .MHUCH >0HB ovH.Hm woodmcm ammuouea ooo.VH mcmeumw .mosmum .momsmu .muoo OIHHDOIxm w mfimumxm means» cofiHHHE nommscms consummucH hone mmH.mmw mfiwumwm uwusefioo oom Esflmaom .momcmo .osH .HOO3oz h ooumsmamx mHooe kumum .MD .Esfimamm .QHOU mafixomm new mammm mom muommmsfim .>smshmo .mcmsmo oaaamuumfimuso o mcfimmmooum Eoceswx copes: 3mswmmm Hmowsmno a 000m omn Monaco .UcH .sflxumm umxmm m commemme mommm UHECODmm scones m0 05m 0:0 0HD0u000> ooo.H >HmuH .xcmEHDO .mosmuh .QHOU pmmml3oumm4 v mmcwumon umHHou soeuofiuw cosmnoq «Show “maosumc0> Iflucm .muume paws «unwaumupw3m «momsmo «mucoum awouuwo.tmuoo Iwumamwu smasowsw> oom.mH “Edemamm “meamuumsfl «deflusomuc Homoznamumomm m mmflHOmmwoom Hz .OCflmcmq 0cm muumm uouoz oom.H momsmo .00 H0053 uouoz N mocmaumnuoz coflHHHn unusemucoo “SsmEumo .MAHmuumsm ameuumsa DHOHDDQ mvm.mm .mumaemuu .mxosue ooo.wm “momsmo «Heumum monommmcwm ..muou wsmnmsum H mm mm mmmsams 0 who 6 momonmEm m 0 no cqawuo wsmmeoo mo H . m m u 2 mo .oz 0 x z . m soHumooq com 0802 .02 H xHazmmm¢ 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 247 APPENDIX J PERSONAL INTERVIEW QUESTIONS What is the nature of your business-mftg,dist,etc? How long has your firm been involved in international markets? What was your motivation to seek foreign markets? What products do you market abroad? Sales level in foreign markets- estimate only? What organizational structure is used- regional, International,subsidiary, functional etc. What mode(s) was used to enter your foreign markets?* What factors determined the mode of entry used?* What mode(s) was used for continued operations?* What factors determine your mode of operations?* Did you feel a need to change modes at any time? If so, when and why?* Is your firm involved in any systematic analysis of political risk before entry into country-markets?* after entry? How is the political risk factor in your country- markets determined?* Suppose you came across some reliable information about the political risk factor in your country- market, how long would it take you to adjust your strategy if at all? In LDC markets, what factors would affect your decision to export or invest? 248 APPENDIX J (cont'd) 16. In DC markets, what factors would affect your decision to export or invest? 17. What overall strategy do you use- global, regional or country? 18. Are the majority of your exports final products? intermediate products? 19. Do you make use of foreign nationals in subsidiary management? 249 APPENDIX K BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT RISK INDEX DESCRIPTION* Introduction The Business Risk Service is specifically designed to meet the needs of banks and companies with operations in foreign countries. Executives responsible for profit performance, strategic planning, cash management, and other functions use the service on a day-to-day basis. Each of the forty-eight countries listed below is analyzed qualitatively in every issue. The factors behind the ratings are discussed and are the bases for +5 Years forecasts. The quantitative ratings included in the country forecasts are based on a perfect country achieving a rating of 100. The three measures are as follows: 1) Political Risk Index—A panel of approximately 75 permanent members submit their opinions on socio-political conditions according to a structured system which underwent trials during 1975-1978 before being published in the 1978-III Issue. 2) Operations Risk Index-A panel of approximately 105 executives submit their ratings according to a system conceived in 1965 and refined in the following years until the ratings were first published in 1972. 3) R Factor-A unique computer program has been conceived to measure a country's capacity to meet its obligations in convertible currency. Each country rating utilizes more than 14,000 cells of data. Countries Covered AMERICAS EA§I_A§IA £23223 Argentina Australia Belgium Bolivia Indonesia Denmark Brazil Japan France Canada Korea (South) Germany 250 APPENDIX K (cont'd.) Chile Malaysia Greece Colombia Phillipines Ireland Ecuador Singapore Italy Mexico Taiwan (R.O.C.) Netherlands Peru Thailand Norway United States Portugal Venezuela Spain Switzerland United Kingdom MIDDLE EAST & SUB-SAHARA NORTH AFRICA AFRICA Egypt Ivory Coast India Kenya Iran Nigeria Iraq South Africa Israel Zaire Morocco Pakistan Saudi Arabia Turkey The Business Risk Service is published 31 March, 31 July, and 30 November each year. Political Risk Index (PRI) The concept focuses wholly on socio-political conditions in a country by: 1) 2) 3) 4) Creating a multicomponent system with flexibility to weigh key factors. Utilizing a permanent panel of experts with a political science orientation rather than business. Providing data which can move independently of other BERI S.A. risk measures. Three time periods are involved: a. Present Conditions b. +5 Years Conditions c. +10 Years Conditions Eipst Step in fine Sysgem. The expert rates the present conditions for each of the eight causes shown below from seven (no problems) to zero (prohibitive problems). Then, the two symptoms are rated on the same scale in the present. 251 APPENDIX K (cont'd.) The perspective is from the viewpoint of an international corporation rather than private enterprise owned by nationals. This subtotal involves a maximum of 70 for the perfect country. 1) Six Internal Causes of Political Risk: a. Fractionalization of the political spectrum and the power of the factions. b. Fractionalization by language, ethnic and/or religious groups and the power of these factions. c. Restrictive (coercive) measures required to retain power. d. Mentality, including xenophobia, nationalism, corruption, nepotism, willingness to compromise. e. Social conditions including population density and wealth distribution. f. Organization and strength of forces for a radical left government. 2) Two External Causes of Political Risk: a. Dependence on and/or importance to a hostile major power. b. Negative influences of regional political forces. 3) Two symptoms of Political Risk: a. Societal conflict involving demonstrations, strikes, and street violence. b. Instability as perceived by non-constitutional changes, assasinations, and guerilla wars. Second Step in the System. One or more of the causes may have a very positive impact on the overall political risk. The second subtotal of the system permits discretionary use of 30 points. Experts typically allocate approximately 20 to a low-risk country, approximately 10 for moderate risk, etc., and usually opt to allocate no additional points to a prohibitively risky country. The perfect country would receive a rating of 100 as a result of steps one and two. Forecast of 2R1. Steps one and two are repeated for each of the +5 years and +10 years period. The points awarded to a country under present conditions serve as a basis for changes in the future. Interpretatipn pf the Bapings, Four categories of political risk have become apparent from usage: 1) 70-100 Low Risk. Political changes will not lead to conditions seriously adverse to business. No major socio-political 252 APPENDIX K (cont'd) disturbances are expected. 2) 55-69 Moderate Risk. Political changes seriously adverse to business have occurred, but governments in power during the forecast period have a low probability of introducing such changes. Some disturbances will take place. 3) 40-54 High Risk. Political developments seriously advers to business exist or could happen in the near future. Major socio-political disturbances are occurring periodically. 4) 0-39 Prohibitive Risk. Political conditions severely restrict business operations. Loss of assets is possible. Disturbances are part of daily life. Operations Risk IndeinORIl The objective of ORI is to gauge the business operations climate. There are two variables being measured: (1) The degree to which nationals are given preferential treatment, and (2) the general quality of the business climate, including the political environment for day-to-day business. Definition of the Index. A permanent panel of approximately 105 experts around the world rate present conditions for the 15 criteria which make up a cross-section of the country's business climate from 0 (unacceptable conditions) to 4 (superior conditions). The criteria are weighted to emphasize critical success factors, and this expands the 15 wo a weighted total of 25. A rating of 4 on each criterion gives a perfect environment of 100. a. The quality of the panel members is the foundation of the concept. Executives in companies, banks, governments, and institutions volunteer their ratings. All have extensive international experience. Geographic distribution is worldwide. b. A version of the Delphi method is used. Data are from a permanent panel. The first reply prepared by a panel member requires research and care in matching the rating with the definitions of the criteria. A panelist is supplied with his previous reply and the overall panel average per criterion as input for decisions on current ratings. 253 APPENDIX K (cont'd.) Forecast of ORI. Each panel member rates a country for a +5 years period by giving a whole number for the overall rating such as 70, 62, etc. The high and low ORI forecasts are discarded, and a panelwide average is used. Guidelines on Riskiness. The categories below have been developed to assist in interpreting the ratings. 1) 70-100 Stable environment typical of an advanced industrialized economy. Problems for foreign businesses are offset by the country's efficiency, market opportunities, financial infrastructure, etc. 2) 55-69 Moderate-risk countries with complications in day-to-day operations. Usually the political structure is sufficiently stable to permit consistent operations without serious disruption. 3) 40-54 High risk for foreign-owned businesses. Only special situations should be considered, e.g., scarce raw materials or unusual profits. 4) 0-39 Unacceptable business conditions for foreign-owned businesses. Qpitepia, Weighting Political Continuity 3 Attitude: Foreign Investors & Profits 1 1/2 Nationalization 1 1/2 Monetary Inflation 1 1/2 Balance of Payments 1 1/2 Bureaucratic Delays 1 Economic Growth 2 1/2 Currency Convertability 2 1/2 Enforeceability of Contracts 1 1/2 Labor/Cost Productivity 2 Professional Services and Contractors 1/2 Communications and Transportation 1 Local Management and Partners 1 Short Term Credit 1 Long Term Loans & Venture Capital 2 254 APPENDIX K (cont'd.) Factor R (B-FACTOR) The purpose of R (for remittances and repatriation of capital) is to estimate a country's capacity and willingness for private foreign companies to convert profits and capital in the local currency to "hard" currency and transfer the funds. The computer program manipulates over 14,000 cells of data and makes hundreds of calculations for each R rating and the four subidicies described below. Legal Framework Subindex (20% of R11 Each of the six criteria are rated from 5 (best case) to zero (worst case) and weighted by either four or three. The weighted total of 20 times 5 equals the perfect legal framework for R. 1) Laws as Written: Weighting a. Profit and Dividend Remittances 4 b. Royalties, Fees, and Renumeration for Non-Dividend Cash Flow Services 3 c. Repatriation of Capital _3 10 2) Actual Practices: Weighting a. Practices on Dividends, Royalties, and Other Periodic Compensation 4 b. Practices on Repatriation of Capital 3 c. Hedging Opportunities Against a Devaluing Currency _; 10 Foreign Exchange Genezation Subindex (30% pf B), IMF data published in International Financial Statistics (IFS) are used. Certain statistics were converted to "standard normal variates." This technique makes meaningful comparisons possible despite an immense range in the data across countries. a. Current account performance is half of the subindex, or 50 points. Breakeven receives 25 points. A rolling average is used to dampen the impact of unusual years. b. Three measures are used to award the 50 points for capital flows. First, capital account points up to a maximum of 30 are awarded by establishing breakeven as 15. Second, capital flows attracted by high interest rates adjusted for risk earn a maximum of 10 points. Third, "safe haven" currencies also attract capital, and a maximum of 10 points are awarded. 255 APPENDIX K (cont'd.) Accumulated lntepnational Reserves Subindex (39% pt 3). a. First, months of coverage for imports of merchandise and services are used as a means of relating hard currency reserves to scope of needs. The most coverage each year receives 50 points; the fewest months earns zero. b. Second, the international reserve total is added to the London valuation for gold holdings to give a complete total on reserves. A ratio is then calculated using total public foreign debt as the numerator. Foreign Debt Assessment Subindex (20% of B), The developing country data for public foreign debt published by the World Bank are the basic sources. Industrialized countries required several sources. a. A ratio using gross domestic product converted to U.S. s as the denominator is used to put the debt into perspective with the economy. Creditor nations receive all 40 points; the largest result receives zero. b. Capacity to service debt is measured by a ratio of annual public foreign loan obligations (numerator) and foreign exchange earned as the denominator. 40 points go to the creditor nations. c. The "saturation factor" is a theoretical calculation. A country reaches saturation when debt service plus imports of petroleum equal foreign exchange earned: this situation receives zero, but five points or fewer is critical. Biskipess and pne +5 gears Egzepasp, Risk categories are the same groupings as for ORI. Data used for the forecast is the result of regression analyses, research staff input based on scenarios in the FORCE reports, trends in the ratings, and senior staff judgment. Wholly quantitative forecasts proved unrealistic. * Printed with permission from: BERI SERVICE, S.A. 1355 Redondo Ave., Suite 10 Long Beach, CA 90804 256 APPENDIX L LETTER OF THANKS Dept. of Marketing and Transportation Admin. Michigan State University East Lansing, MI 48824 July 7, 1986 ADDRESS Dear Mr. : I am writing to thank you for granting me audience for my dissertation research. My interview with you was very informative and is an important part of my research design. As I promised, at the conclusion of the study, I will be sending you a synopsis of the major findings and implications (about 5 pages). Please expect the abstract in November/December- 1986. Thanks again. Yours Sincerely, Samuel C. Okoroafo. LIST OF REFERENCES LI ST OF REFERENCES Aharoni, Yair (1966), The Foreign Investment Decision Process, (Boston: Harvard University Press). Aldrich, Howard A. (1979), Organizations and Environments, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Andriole, S.J. and G.W. Hopple (1982), An Assessment of U.S. Political Instability Research Methodologies, Marshall, VA; Information Systems, inc., (September). Axinn, Catherine (1985), An Examination of Factors that influence Export Involvement, Unpublished PhD. dissertation, Michigan State University. Ayal, Igal (1981), "International Product Life Cycle: A Reassessment and Product Policy Implications," Journal of Marketing, Vol 45, (Fall), 91-96 Ayal, Igal and Ziff, Jehiel (1978), "Competitive Market Choice Strategies in Multinational Marketing", Columbia Journal of World Business, 13 (Fall), 72-81. ------ and--------(1979), "Market Expansion Strategies in Multinational Marketing", Journal of Marketing, 43 (Spring), 84-94. Azar, Edward and Swan, T. (1975), Dimensions of Interactions: A Source Book to; the Study Q: Behavior of 31 Nations from 1948 through 1973, Pittsburgh: International Studies Association. Bain, J. (1956), Barriers to New Compepition, (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press). Baldwin, Robert E. (1979), "Determinants of Trade and Foreign Investment: Further Evidence", The Review of Economics and Statist'cs, Vol. 6, Amsterdam, 40-48. Bandera, V.N. and J.T. White (1977), "U.S. Direct Investments and Domestic Markets in Europe", Egonomia Internazionale, Vol 21, Genova, 117-133. 257 258 Basi, R.S. (1968), Determinants of United States Fnivate Direct investment in Foreign Countries, (Kent, Ohio: Kent State University, Bureau of Economic and Business Research). Beeman, Don R. (1978), "Business Policies and Strategies for Reducing Political Risks in Developing Nations: A Theoretical Paradigm for Empirical Testing", Paper presented at 38th Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management, San Francisco, California. Behrman, Jack N. (1962), "Foreign Associates and Their Financing" in Raymond F. Mikesell (Ed), U.S.;Private and Government Investment Abroad, Eugene, 77-113. Bennett, Peter D. and R.T. Green (1972), "Political Instability as a Determinant of Direct Foreign Investment in Marketing", Journa o eti Research, Vol. 9 (May), 182-186. Bergsten, C.F., Horst, T. and Moran, T.H., (1978), American Multinationals and American Interests,(Washington DC: Brookings Institution) Bilkey, W.J. and G. Tesar (1978), "The Export Behavior of Smaller Sized Wisconsin Manufacturing Firms", Journa; of International Business Studien, (Spring), 93-98. Boddewyn, J. and E. Cracco (1972), "The Political Game in World Business, Columbia ourna 0 W0 s' ess, January-February Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M., (1976), he Futu f e Multinational Enterprise, (London:MacMillan) Buckley, P. J. and R. D. Pearce (1979), "Overseas Production and Exporting by the World's Largest Enterprises: A Study in Sourcing Policy", our a1 t t a Dusiness §tndies, (Spring/Summer), 9- 20 Cavusgil, S.T. (1976), Onganizational Determinants of Finns Export Behavior: An Empirical Analysis, PhD. dissertation, The University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin. Cavusgil, S.T. and J.R. Nevin (1981), "Internal Determinants of Export Marketing Behavior: An Empirical Investigation", Journal of a et'n ese , (February), 114-119. 259 --------------- &---------------(1980)," A Conceptualization of the Initial Involvement in International Marketing", Theoretical Developments in Marketing, C.W. Lamb and P.M. Dunne, eds., Chicago: American Marketing Association, 68-71. Cohen, J. and Cohen, P.(1983), Applied Multiple Regression/Correlation Analysis for the Behavioral Sciences, 2nd ed., (LondonzLawrence Erlbaum Associates, Publishers). Comanor, W.S. and T.A. Wilson (1967), "Advertising, Marketing Structure, and Performance," this REVIEW (Nov), 423-440 Cracco, E. (1972), "The Nature and Perception of Political Risk for the International Corporation: An Exploratory Analysis with Special Reference to Brazil", Unpublished PhD. dissertation, Michigan State University. Cutright, P. (1965), "Political Structure, Economic Development and National Social Programs", American Journal of Sociology, 70, (March), 537-550. Czinkota, M.R. and W.J. Johnston (1981), "Segmenting U.S. Firms for Export Development", gounnni pf Dusiness Research, 9, 353-365. Davidson, W.H. (1980), "The Location of Foreign Direct Investment Activity: Country Characteristics and Experience Effects", urna of te at'o us'n ss Studies, 11 (Fall), 9-22. --------------- and R. Harrigan (1977), "Key Decisions in International Marketing: Introducing New Products Abroad", golumbia gounnal of Wonld Dusiness, 12 (Winter), 15-23. Dunning, J.H. (1981), International Produgtion nnd the Rultinational Enterprise (London: George Allen & Irwin), 72-108. Durbin, J. and Watson, G.S.(1951), "Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares Regression", DiometFika,Vol 37, 1950,409-428, vol 38, 1951, 159-178 Feldman, G. M. (1978a), "Coping with New Challenges to Investments Abroad",§omme;ge Amerign,Vol. III,No. 14, (July 3), 2-5 Feldman, G. M. (1978b), "How U.S. Firms are Responding to New Investment Controls Abroad", Dommence Amepipa, Vol. III, No. 15, (July 17), 8-11. 260 Galtung, T. (1970), "Diachronic Correlation, Process Analysis and Causal Analysis", Quaiity and Quanpipy, 4, 55-94. Glover, K.A. and Cady, J.F. (1983), "Developing Foreign Export as a Market Entry Strategy", MBS gese Senies, Harvard Business School. Goldberg, M.A. (1972), "Determinants of U.S. Direct Investments in the EEC: Comment", The American Economic Review, 62, Evanston, 692-699. Goodnow, J. and J. Hansz (1972), "Environmental Determinants of Overseas Market Entry Strategies", Journa; 0; International Business Studies, (Spring), 33-50. Green, R. and Cunningham, W.H. (1975), "The Determinants of U.S. Foreign Investment: An Empirical Examination", Management International Review, 15, 113-120. Green, R. and Korth, C.M. (1974), "Political Instability and the Foreign Investor", Qalifornia Management Review, (Fall), 23-31. Green, R.T. and Smith, C.M. (1972), "Multinational Profitability as a Function of Political Instability", Management International Review, 23-29. Hage, J., (1975)," Theoretical Decisions Rules for Selecting Research Decision: The Study of Nation-States or Societies", Sociolo ' Me hods Resea ch, Vol 4 No. 2 (november),13l-l65 Grosse, R. (1985), "An imperfect competition theory of the MNE", urnal of er tio a s' ess t, 'es, Vol 16, No. 1, (Spring),57-80. Hair, J.F., Anderson, R.E., Tatham, R.L. and B.J. Glablowsky (1979), Multivariate Data Analysis wipn Readings, Petroleum Publishing Company, Oklahoma Harrell, 6.0. and R.O. Keifer (1981), "Multinational Strategic Market Portfolios", MSU aniness Ionics, (Winter), 5-15L Hayes, R.H. and W.J. Abernathy (1980), "Managing Our Way to Economic Decline", Manyeng Dusiness Review, (July- August), 67. Hazard, J.L. (1977), Inansponpation; Management Fconenice Roliey, (Maryland: Cornell Maritime Press, Inc. 261 Hirsh, S. (1976), "An International Trade and Investment Theory of the Firm", Oxford Economic Fapers, 28, 258- 270. Hood, N. and Young, S. (1981), The Economics e: The multinational enterprise, (London: Longman Group Ltd). Horst, T. (1972a), "The Industrial Composition of U.S. Exports and Subsidiary Sales to the Canadian Market", American Economic Review, 62, 37-45. Horst, T. (1972b), "Firm and Industry Determinants of the Decision to Invest Abroad: An Empirical Study", Review of Economic and Statistics, 54, 258-266. Horst, T. (1974a), "American Exports and Foreign Direct Investments", Harvard Institute of Economic Research, discussion paper. no. 362. Horst, T. (1974b), The Theory of the Firm", Chapter 2 in Dunning, J.H. (ed), Economic Analysis end phe Multinational Enterprise, (London: George Allen and Irwin). Hull, H. C. and Nie, N. (1981), SPSS Update 2-2, (McGraw Hill Book Company) Johanson, J. and J. Uahlne (1977), "The Internationalization Process in the Firm: A Model of Knowledge Developments and Increasing Foreign Commitments", Qounnei of International Business Studies, (Spring/Summer), 23-32. Johanson, J. and Wiedersheim-Paul (1975), "The Internationalization of the Firm: Four Swedish Case Studies", ournal of a a eme tu ' 5, October, 305- 332. Johnston,J. (1983), Fconometnic Methods, 3rd ed.,(New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company). Kelejian, H. H and Oates, W.E. (1981), Introduction to Econometrics,2n edition,(New York: Harper & Row Publishers). Kirkpatrick, C. and M. Yamin (1981), "The Determinants of Export Subsidiary Formation by U.S. Transnationals in Developing Countries: An Interindustry Analysis", World Development, 9, 373-382. Kimberly, J.R. (1976), "Issues in the Design of Longitudinal Organization Research", SocioIogicaI Metnogs eng Research, Vol. 4, No. 3, (February), 321-347. 262 Kobrin, S. (1976), "The Environmental Determinants of Foreign Direct Manufacturing Investment: An Ex-Post Empirical Analysis", ournal of ntern ' ess Stugies, (Fall/Winter), 29-42. Kobrin, S. (1978), "When Does Political Instability Result in Increased Investment Risk?", Columbia Senpnal o: Dusiness, (October). Kobrin, S. (1980), "Political Risk: A Review and Reconsideration", Sournal of InternationaI Dusiness Studies, 67-79. Kravis, 1.8. and R.E. Lipsey (1982), "The Location of Overseas Production and Production for Export by U.S. Multinational firms",Sournal o: Internapional Economies 12, 201-223. Levis, M. (1979), "Does Political Instability in Developing Countries Affect Foreign Investment Flow? An Empirical Examination.", Management International Reviey, 19, 59- 68. Lipsey, R.E. and Weiss, M.Y. (1976), "Exports and Foreign Direct Investment in Manufacturing Industries", (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper No. 131 (May). MaClayton, D. M. Smith, and J. Hair (1980), "Determinants of Foreign Market Entry: A Multivariate Analysis of Corporate Behavior", Menegement Inpepnatienei Review, 20 (3), 40-52. Mason,R.H., Miller,R., and D.R. Weigel (1975), Tne_Fepnenie_ of Internapionai Businessl John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York Mann, M., (1966) 'Seller Concentration, Barriers to Entry,and Rates of Return in tqirtygipdustries 1950- 1960", this Review. (August). 90’.0 Moore,W. (1963), Social Onange, (Englewood Cliffs, N.J:Prentice-Hall) Nehrt, L.C. (1970), The Rolitical Environment fie: Fopeign Investment. New York: Praeger Publishers. Nielson, A.M. (1980),"Global Marketing Strategy: A resource mix concept", paper presented at the Acagemy Q: Inpepnationai Susiness Annual Meeting 263 Nigh, D. (1985a), "The Effects of Political Events on U.S. Direct Foreign Investment: A Pooled Time-Series Cross- Sectional Analysis", qurnal of Internationai Dusiness Studies, Vol. XVI, No. 1 (Spring), 1-17. Ohlin, B., (1983) Interregional and International Trade (Cambridge:Harvard University Press, Harvard Economic Studies, Vol. XXXIX) Orr, Dale (1984), "The Determinants of Entry: A Study of the Canadian Manufacturing Industries", Review of Economics end Statistics, LVI, (February), 58-66. Perlmutter, H.V. (1969), "The Tortuous Evolution of the Multinational Corporation", gqumbia SounnaI e: WorIg Dusiness, (January/February), 9-18. Piper, J.R. (1971), "How U.S. Firms evaluate foreign investment opportunities", MSU Business Topics, (Summer),ll-ZO. Robinson, H.J. (1961), The Motivation and FIow o; Frivepe Foreign Investment, International Development Center, Standard Research Institute, Merlo Park, California. Robock, S.H. (1971), "Political Risk: Identification and Assessment", Columbia JounnaI pf World Dusiness, (July/August), 6-20. Rock, M.T. (1973), Cross-Country Analysis of the Determinanps o: D.S, Foreign Investment in Manufacturing in Less Developed Countries, unpublished PhD. dissertation, University of Pittsburgh. Root, F. (1968a), "U.S. Business Abroad and Political Risks", MSU Business Tepics, Winter), 73-80. 264 --------------- (1968b), "Attitudes of American Executives Towards Government Investment Opportunities", Economics end Business Dulietin, Temple University, (January), 14-23. --------------- (1982), LOW: Amaco. Rummel, R.J. and Heenan, D.A. (1978), "How Multinationals Analyze Political Risks", Harvard Business Review, (January/February), 67-78. Scaperlanda, A.E. and L.J. Mauer (1969), "The Determinants of U.S. Direct Investment in the EEC", The American Economic Review, Vol. 59, Evanston, 558-568. Schwartz, R.H. (1976), The Determinants of U.S. Direct Investment Abnoad, PhD. dissertation, Texas Technical University. Scott, B.R. (1984), "National Strategy for Stronger U.S. Competitiveness", Harvard Business Review, (March/April), 77-91. Shapiro, A. (1981), "Managing Political Risk: A Policy Approach", golumbia Joupnal of Dnsiness, (Fall), 63-70. Snavely, W.P., P. Weiner, K. Ulrich and E. Enright, (1964), Export Survey 0: the Greater Rentgepe Anees, Vols. 1 & 2, University of Connecticut. Situmeang, B.J. (1978), The Environmentei QonneIetes pf Fepeign Direct Investment wipn Reference p0 Sonpneesp Asia. Unpublished PhD. dissertation, University of Oregon. Truitt, J.F. (1970), "Summary of the Post World War II Experience of American and British Investors in the Less Developed Countries", on 81 e ' a Studies, (Fall). Thunell, Lars (1977), Rolitical RisRs in Inpennepionel Dusiness: Investment Dehavior o; MuItinapionaI Qopporepions. New York: Praeger Publishers. Vesper (1979), "Entrepreneurship in Foreign Trade," on n e: SmaIl Dusiness Menagement, (April) 5-11 Wallace,T.D. (1972), "Weaker criteria and tests for linear restrictions in regression", Feenenep;iee,40, (July),689-698. Wells, L.T. (1966), "A Product Life Cycle for International Trade?", Spurnal o: MarReting, Vol. 32, (July), 1-6. 265 Weekly, James,(1977), "Expropriation of U.S. Multinational Investments, MSU Business Topics,25 (Winter), 27-36 Weidersheim-Paul, Finn, H.C., Olson and L.S. Welch (1978), "Pre-Export Activity: The First Step in Internationalization", Journal 0 Internat o Dusiness Studies, (Spring/Summer), 47-58. Wind, Y., S.P. Douglas, H.V. Perlmutter (1973), "Guidelines for Developing International Marketing Strategies", gournal of Marketing, Vol. 37, (April), 14-23. Zaltman, G., LeMasters, K., and Heffring, M. (1982), Theory Construction in Marketing: Some Thoughts on Thinking, (New YorE: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.)