69-20,855 FRANZ, Verl R. W., 1923MICHIGAN FARMERS1 PURCHASING COOPER­ ATIVES TESTING FOR AN IDEOLOGY. Michigan State U niversity, Ph.D ., 1969 Sociology, general University Microfilms, Inc., Ann Arbor, Michigan (C ) Copyright by VERL R. W. FRANZ 1969 • MICHIGAN FARMERS’ PURCHASING COOPERATIVES TESTING FOR AN IDEOLOGY by Verl R. W. Franz A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Sociology 1967 ABSTRACT MICHIGAN FARMERS' PURCHASING COOPERATIVES Testing for an Ideology by Verl R. W. Franz The major goal was to test assumptions of various sociologists concerning ideo­ logical belief systems as they pertain to modern Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Co­ operatives. In order to study the dynamics of Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Coopera­ tives, consideration was given as to whether or not these cooperatives fit the model of a social movement, are committed to a cooperative ideology and/or a business ideology, and whether differential commitment to these ideologies is associated with individual and organizational characteristics. A review of the literature on the history of cooperatives, on the implications pertinent to the theory of social movements, on ideology, on theory of ideology, on the sociology of knowledge, on belief systems, and on value orientations was made. Hypotheses resulting from these theoretical positions were formulated. Through personal interviews, data were gathered on a random sample of thirty managers, thirty board members, and thirty farmer members of thirty Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Co­ operatives. Questions included pertained to personal information (age, education, training, experience), size of cooperative (based on gross annual sales), and attitudes toward cooperatives in general and toward the respondent's specific cooperative. A sixty-two item questionnaire was used to gather information on the cooperative mem­ bers ' attitudes toward traditional values and beliefs, the free enterprise system, individual opportunity, desire for achievement and success, relationships between and among cooperative membership, overall economic transactions, and on their feel­ ings toward community and The items to test the social interaction in the community. major hypothesis that an ideology if present would scale were statistically analyzed by the use of various item analysis techniques: the V e r l R. W. Franz h i g h - l o w dichotony, reached trace line analysis, and f actor a n a l y s i s methods. Conclusions indicate that n o discernible a n d / o r s i g n i f i c a n t cooperative ideology or b usiness i deology could b e found. M i chigan Formers' business-like P u r c h a s i n g C o operatives wer e f o u n d not in values; lo be typically n e i t h e r could e v i d e n c e be f o u n d that an unanticipated, u n d e r l y i n g cooperat i v e v a l u e structure is hel d b y m e m b e r s and leaders. Past theory has led us to believe t h a t f a r m e r s ' c o o p e r a t i v e s fall w i t h i n the f r a m e w o r k of so c i a l m o v e m e n t theory. may be The r esults of t h i s study indicate that it impossible to d e m o n s t r a t e that a w e l l - d e f i n e d a mong M i c h i g a n Farmers' F r o m this study, s ocial movement, help p r i nciples P u r c h a s i n g Cooperatives. it is concluded t h a t if farmers' they a r e now, of t r a d i t i o n a l m o d e r n b u s i n e s s beliefs. c o o p e r a t i v e ideology exists c o o peratives were ever a f r o m a v a l u e p o i n t of view, a m ixture of the self- c o o peratives a n d the c o n s u m e r service values of ACKNOWLEDGMENTS "No man is an H a n d , intire of itselfej every man is a peece of the Continent, a part of the maine; if a Clod be washed away b y the Sea, Europe 13 lease, as well as if a Promonotorie were, as well as if a Mannor of thy friends or of thine owne were; any m a n ’s death diminishes me, because I am involved in Mankinde; And there­ fore' never send to know for who m the bell tolls; it tolls for thee." JOHN DONNE (1573-1631) Devotions XVII When one is "over-age in grade" it is all too easy sometimes to wonder "for whom the bell tolls." In retrospect, when I felt I was being "washed away by the Sea," it was ray dear family, friends, teachers and fellow graduate students who guided me ba c k "to the maine," who insisted that I a m "a peece of the Continent" and who restored my perspective. If this single work ever represents the culmination of a long arduous journey through "academic land"; if this work will ever make a contribution to b e ing "in­ volved in Mankind e , " it will do so only as a result of the fellowship, support, faith and dedication of my friends, family and teachers. To all these people I express humble and grateful appreciation. I want, first, to extend my appreciation to Mr. M. D. Brownlee and Farm Bureau Services, Inc., of Lansing, Michigan, for their financial support and managerial insight to sponsor this research, as well as the Michigan State University Agricultural Experiment Station for their administrative support. To Drs. A. 0. Haller and J. Allan Beegle, who separately and jointly served as advisor and chairman of my thesis committee, a special thanks. Special thanks are due Dr. Beegle, who in addition to listening to every idea about cooperatives and helping me sift the chaff from the wheat, served as my "office landlord," p r o ­ tagonist at the "brown-bag seminars, and as ny editorial consultant, along with John Stoeckel, to the "Bruno Bronski Story." A debt of gratitude must go to Dr. Haller who made it possible for me to resume iry graduate study--for his faith in ny "delayed" potential and for his insistence that "rigor is the better part of valor " A grateful thanks to Drs. W. H. Form, D. W. Olmsted, and John U s eem for serving on m y thesis committee. These good men, along with Drs. C. P. Loomis and C. R. Hoffer, contributed greatly to this thesis and to my student career as advisors and teachers (the most noble of professions). All in all, I have been blessed with great teachers, like Drs. Harry Trice, William Sewell, Eugene Wilkening, and Douglas Marshall. The contributions of my peers certainly will linger in my memory as elements of great significance to completing this endeavor, for without the mutual aid and reinforcement from my good friends in the OSS (our social system) the structuralfunctional process would certainly have reached a point of disequilibrium many times. Therefore, to Gene Erickson and Bob Holloway, as charter members of the OSS, ny deepest and sincerest gratitude for being "involved in Mankinde." In short, if all of the leaves in the forest had tongues they could not begin to e x ­ press ny indebtedness. To my wife, Margaret, I can only say "How does one express gratitude for seventeen years of love, trust, faith and confidence"? Thanks are due Drs. R. K. Burns, W. G. Lonergan, and M e l a n y K. Baehr of the Industrial Relations Center, The University of Chicago, who not only accepted me as a colleague but also tolerated the inevitable "stress" problems during the final writing stage. Finally, a word of appreciation to all of the Organization Research Staff at the Industrial Relations Center who kept the "ship afloat" to free some time for writing: to Sally Jacobson, Sally Greisdorf, Mike Manning, and Alvin (Bo) Huffman, III, thanks. Likewise, thanks to all of the dear ladies who fought the "battle" of typewriter, commas and footnotes--Mrs. Paul, Mrs. Jamison, and Sandra Davenport. Special thanks to Frances Burns, Peggy Vecchione and Stan Powers for t h eir talented editorial help. Verl R. W. Franz 1967 Margaret family Uncle Louis Wrensch and Aunt Alma Franz Wrensch TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter Page I Introduction........................................... 1 II Literature on Cooperatives............................ 7 History of Cooperatives and the Cooperative Movement.............................. 7 III • IV V Theoretical Considerations in the Study of Cooperatives.............................. 23 Literature on Social Movements................... 23 The Place of Ideology in the Study of Farmers' Cooperatives................... 30 The Study of Ideology as a Function of the Sociology of Knowledge......................................... 42 The Relation of Belief Systems and/or Value Orientations to the Theory of Ideology........................... 51 General Hypotheses................................ 56 Methodology, Pertinent Variables, Analysis of Data, Tests of Hypotheses and Findings ........... 58 Michigan Cooperatives............................. 59 The Sample........................................ 62 Pertinent Variables and Hypotheses .............. 65 Independent Variables............................. 70 Test of Hypotheses................................ "Jk Cooperative Ideology.............................. 85 American Business Ideology....................... 87 Summary and Conclusions .............................. 102 TABLE OF CONTENTS Appendixes A A-l B Page Correlation Matrix for the o2 Selected Items........................................ Questionnaire Items Included in the Correlation Matrix ............................. .............. E F G H I J K L 117 A Trace Line Plot of the Anti-Big Business Index Composed of Items C-3> C-31> and C-3^* D 115 A Trace Line Plot of the Competitive Yardstick Index Composed of Items C-5* C-7, C-13, and C-k2. C 109 • • A Trace Line Plot of the Pro-Business Index Consisting of Items C-10 and C-53.......... H® 119 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Coopera­ tives as a Source of Political Power Consisting of Items C-l6, C-23, and C-62. . . . 120 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Coopera­ tive Idealism Consisting of Items C-20, C-26 , c-27, C-35, C-37, C-^5, C - W , c- 56, C-59, and C-60.............................. 121 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Favorability Toward Economic Goals of Cooperation Consist­ ing of Items C-13> C-3^> C-7> and C-5...... 122 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Orientation Toward Economic Democracy Consisting of Items C-26, C-27, C-56 , and C-60..................... 123 A Trace Line Plot of the Traditional Indi­ vidualism Index Consisting of Items B-l, B-6, B-lk, and B-4l................................... 12k A Trace Line Plot of the Index of the Centrality of the Free Enterprise System to the American Society Consisting of Items B-ll, B-28, B-44, and B-l+6. . . .............. .. . . 125 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Individual Opportunity, Desire for Achievement, Success and Upward Mobility Consisting of Items B-17> B-21, B-30, B- 36 , B- 38, and B-50.......... . . 126 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of the Rigors and Demands of Leadership Consisting of Items B-2k, B-kO, B-52, B-55, and B-6l............... 127 TABLE OF CONTENTS Appendixes M N 0 P Q R S T Page A Trace Line Plot of the Free Enterprise Creed A, Consisting of Items B-l, B-6, B-l4, B-1T, B-24, B-28, B-3o , and B-44......................... 128 A Trace Line Plot of the Free Enterprise Creed - B, Consisting of Items B-l, B-6, B-l4, B-17, B-24, B-44,and B-50. ............ 129 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Individualism Consisting of Items B-l, B-l4, B-17, B-24, and B-50................................................ 130 Index of Cooperative Economic and Occupational Normlessness Consisting of Items N-2, N-29, N-39, N-43, N-47, and N-54.......................... 131 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Economic Powerlessness - A, Consisting of Items P-8, P-15,P-32, P-49, P-58, and N-29.................... 132 A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Economic Powerlessness - B, Consisting of Items P-15, P-32, P-49, and P -58............................... 133 Index of Isolation from Social Interaction in the Community Consisting of Items S-4, S-9, S-22, and S-25................................. 134 The Interview Schedule Used...................... . 135 Bibliography..................... ........................... . l44 LIST OF TABLES Table Page I Percent of Population Represented by the Sample . . . . oh II Percent Members of Managers, Board Members, and Farmer by Age in the Sample........................... 66 III IV V VI Difference in Age between Board Members and Farmer Membersin the Sample............................... 66 Years of Formal Education of Managers, Board Members, and Farmer Members in the Sample by P e r c e n t .................................................. 67 Years of Managerial Experience of Managers by Size of Operation of Cooperatives in the Sample by P e r c e n t ........................................ 68 Size and Number of Local Cooperatives Based on Gross Annual Sales for i960 as Represented in Sample................................................. 69 LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS Figure Page 1. Factor I (6$ of Variance of 62 x 62 Matrix)........... 95 2. Factor II (6$ of Variance of 62 x 62 Matrix) . . . . . . 5. Factor III (6$ of Variance of 62 x 62 Matrix)......... 98 A. Variables with Communalities (h^) Greater Than . 3 0 .............................................. 99 - 97 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Sociologists, psychologists,' economists, and historians have concerned themselves with the birth, growth, and death of social movements for quite some time. Foremost among sociologists are rural sociologists who concern themselves with farmers' coopera­ tives. Their efforts, while serious and scholarly, are often directed out of historical perspective. The need to study farmers' cooperatives within their historical frame of reference is demon­ strated by the following three citations: There is no doubt that King's idea of cooperation was one of social reform. King does not regard coopera­ tion merely as a means of imposing limits on or exter­ minating the middleman, or augmenting the productive power of labor. . . He hopes by means of the coopera­ tive society to transform the structure of our economic life as a whole, and thus liberate labor from subjection to and dependence on capital. It is obvious. . . that he looks upon the interest of capital and labor as being hostile the one to the other, . . . he (King) considers cooperation the means to be adopted in the conquest of capitalism and its wage system. . .1 Although consumers' cooperation on the Rochdale principles was introduced in the United States during the nineteenth century, particularly in the Granger movement and in some labor unions during the latter ^-Cited by A. J. Kress, Ed. Introduetioh to the Cooperative Movement (New York: Harper & Brothers, 19^1), PP- 10-12. Dr! Hans Miller, Secretary of the International Cooperative Alliance, found a file of twenty-eight numbers of Dr. William King's Brighton Cooperator in the British Museum. He devoted much of the International Cooperative Alliance Yearbook for 1913 to an exposition of King's writings. Miller places King, a con­ temporary of Robert Owen and a colleague of Ricardo, as the first theorist of the modern cooperative movement. King pub­ lished the Cooperator some time around 1827. 1 2 third of the nineteenth century, the cooperative pur­ chase and distribution of goods was often confused with the cooperative producing and marketing of commodities and in any case the ventures were highly unstable, given to extreme fluctuations of momentary success and utter failure, while the movement itself remained undirected, uncoordinated, and haphazard. Impartial experts and cooperative leaders are gen­ erally agreed upon those factors in the American environment which militated against the steady and sturdy growth of consumers' cooperation. The pro­ ducer orientation of American business, labor, and agriculture is most often cited, and with large validity, as a primary force keeping citizens from recognizing their role as consumers.^ ; Always his (Miller's) vision has been that co­ operatives bring to their members that special ini­ tiative, health, and hope that one usually associates with arguments advocating capitalism. He carries the message everywhere that cooperatives are a natural and vital segment of a successful capitalistic private enterprise system.3 Which of these three representative quotations reflects the ideological belief system of modern Michigan farmers' purchasing cooperatives? Does an ideology of this or any kind still persist, and does it order and structure individual and organizational b e ­ havior? How do cooperators in Michigan resolve these paradoxical beliefs? An attempt to answer these questions will be the major goal of this thesis. Two strong ideas are characteristic of United States farmers generally, and Michigan farmers specifically. One is the long ^C. A. Chambers, "The Cooperative League of the United States of America, 19l6-196l: A Study of Social Theory and Social Action," Agricultural History, XXXVI, No. 2 (April, 1962 ), 59-8l* 3Written by Vernon R. Alden in the foreword of Raymond W. Miller, A Conservative Looks at Cooperatives (Athens, Ohio: Ohio University Press, 1964). standing adherence to freedom of individual choice. The other is the traditional belief that their localities are autonomous and sacred. Farmers' Cooperatives, both producer and consumer, are an expression of these localistic ideas in response to economic conditions. The early economic development of United States industry and agriculture was primarily local. Small businesses in small cities could not serve farmers adequately, and, even when they could, business transactions between city and farm residents left much to be desired. As mechanization took over the farm, as the size of farm operations increased, the farmer needed elevator and distri­ bution facilities which could not, or would not, be provided by city business interests. The American farmer, somewhat alienated because of a self-sufficient past, responded to economic needs by self help. The need for supply and distribution facilities when not met by the business community was solved by the development of coopera­ tives. The American farmer had been accustomed to mutual help principles. He had helped his neighbor raise his barn; the thresh­ ing season had brought all neighbors together to complete the harvest; so it was not unusual that he should join with his neighbors to collectively buy seed, corn, or to market cream, and, ultimately in the Midwest, to form elevator cooperatives. Cooperatives in Michigan were originally organized locally to meet local economic problems. These relatively small organizations k were a response to a need to protect prices for produce, as well as to gain favorable farm supply costs. It was natural that farmers should solve these problems jointly as they had solved others in the past. Kercher wrote in 19^1: It has been in the intimate, neighborly social setting of the hamlet, village, or small town that the cooperatives as a whole have had their firmest roots. Here occupational and other class differences are minor factors, and consequently economic wants are sufficiently commonplace and uniform to be served by a relatively simple institutional structure. Further­ more, the face-to-face contacts of every day life pro­ vide the ideal social experience for the development of common understanding and the formation of attitudes of group solidarity so essential to voluntary coopera­ tive effort.^ Present day changes in the economic structure of agriculture tend to .challenge Kercher's "commonplace and uniform economic-wants to be served.by a relatively simple institutional structure." modern farmer must be rational to survive. The High cost mechanization, high cost production and distribution, and large, expensive farm operations have demanded that farmers become highly skilled managers with a knowledge of all aspects of the agricultural economic structure. This demand for modern management has placed the Michigan farmer in a conflicting position which is expressed in his attitude toward his cooperative. On the one hand his traditional way of life demands that he be independent in decision but tied strongly to his intimate, face-to-face experiences in his ^L. C. Kercher, V . S . Kebker, and W. C. Leland, Jr., Consumers' Cooperatives in the North Central States, Part I. (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 19^1)• own locality with life-long friends and acquaintances who band to­ gether cooperatively to meet common and uniform problems. On the other hand he has been caught up by increasing industrialization and mechanization on the farm. He finds he must compete in large markets; he must purchase from nationwide manufacturers and must learn to operate in a business community which is large and com­ plex and adheres to rules unlike any in his local community. He finds his local cooperative inadequate to meet the challenges of modern agriculture, and he finds that he must think about the place of his cooperative in these changing times. likely to do? What is he most Will the Michigan farmer, the cooperative board members, and the cooperative manager accept the fact that they must affiliate in some way with large complex production and distribution systems, or will they hold more tenaciously to their traditional sentiments of localism and individualism? This thesis is an effort to study the dynamics of Michigan Purchasing Cooperatives in terms of: 1. Whether or not they fit the model of a social move­ ment, especially in respect to the existence of ideological prerequisites. 2. Whether or not members are committed to a co­ operative ideology. 3- Whether or not managers are committed to a busi­ ness ideology. 4. Whether or not differential commitment to ideologies is associated with individual and organizational, characteristics. Chapter II w i 1 include a review of literature on the history of cooperatives. Chapter III will include implications germane to the theory of social movements, ideology, the theory of ideology and the sociology of knowledge, belief systems and value orientations. Con­ clusions and hypotheses resulting from these theoretical positions will be presented. Chapter IV will include the methodology used, significant variables, analysis of data, tests of hypotheses, and research findings. Chapter V will include the conclusions and their theoretical and empirical implications. CHAPTER II LITERATURE ON COOPERATIVES For the most part the published works about cooperatives in general and Farmers' Cooperatives in particular cover a wide range of approaches. Various authors have written from the sentimental and evangelistic point of view, others have been somewhat neutral and objective, while still others have been picayune and empiri­ cally sterile. In an effort to recap the literature from an analytical point of view it became necessary to develop a classi­ fication system within which to analyze the various approaches and concepts used for the study of cooperatives generally and farmers' purchasing cooperatives specifically. History of Cooperatives and the Cooperative Movement The first awareness of works on cooperatives, and possibly the most obvious, were those of a broad historical, partisan nature. These works include historical compilations by non-historians. The authors are loyal partisans who in many cases approached the task as a "labor of love" and were dedicated to being the chroniclers of the "holy histoiy." Probably foremost among the "emotional" doc­ trinal authors is Voorhis. In his most recent book, American Cooperatives, Voorhis serves up a wide range of fare in cafeteria fashion. He reiterates the glorious past of why and how coopera­ tives developed; he explores the human motives and "naturalness" of cooperation versus conflict; he explores cooperative health plans, 8 and reiterates the ancient wrongs of monopoly and big business. In short, his publication is a folksy, popular version of pseudo­ cooperative ideology characteristic of the Cooperative League of which he was executive director at the time. Of the historical treatment of cooperatives, three authors stand out as having produced accurate, well thought out, scholarly works. They are Daniels, published in 1938; Kress in 19^1, and Casselman in 1952. Daniels deals with the history of cooperatives in America, while Casselman, a Canadian labor economist, is concerned mainly with consumer cooperatives, the major schools of cooperation, and cooperatives' relations with other institutions such as the state and labor. He does not agree with the commonwealth ideal because it is too utopian but does present a case for the competitive yardstick goal as the only practical approach. Casselman uses the terms co- operatism and cooperativism instead of cooperation or the coopera­ tive movement because these terms better describe the phenomenon as a system of economy, whereas cooperation gives a better indication of the movement as a method or technique. Daniels presents some significant insight into the historical relationship between consumer and farmer cooperatives. He tries desperately to include farmers' purchasing cooperatives within the framework of consumer cooperatives but in so doing stretches a point which cannot be corroborated by experience, analysis, or reality. His history and certainly his predictions are in error when he says: 9 As the farmers' purchasing cooperatives keep on moving consumerward, in the process.of orientation through which they are now passing, it looks as though they will soon emerge from the twilight zone into the sunlight of con­ sumers' cooperation, there to join forces with urbane cooperatives in the common cause of bringing to all elements of the American people still better standards of living and more of the joy of life.l His observations regarding the Farm Bureau are, however,, more accurate and to the point. He states: The principle objective of this organization (the American Farm Bureau Federation) is evidently to shape national policies affecting agriculture, and much of its effort is brought to bear upon influencing Congressional legislation and federal action. As compared with the Grange and the Farmers Unions, the Farm Bureau Federation has more of a business character and viewpoint, and is more pragmatic and less idealistic. As regards coopera­ tion, the national organization is on record as strongly favoring cooperative marketing, and cooperative purchasing of farm supplies in production. But it has not yet taken a definite stand on cooperative distribution of consumers' goods.^ Andrew J. Kress edited a book, Introduction to the Cooperative Movement, which is the most comprehensive, well organized, and best documented analysis available. Kress traces the development of the social philosophy which underlies the cooperative idea from its very beginning in 1798 in England, through its .various ideological and organizational phases to 19^-1> the date of his publication. His excellent analysis of the various movements, cooperative move­ ments that had worldwide implications, deals with all aspects of cooperation expertly and completely: political, economic, medicine Ijohn Daniels, Cooperation: An American Way. Friede, 1938> P- 193* 2Ibid., p. 26 l. New York: Covici- (health), consumers, producers, marketing, financial, philosophical, international, and statistical. His is the only source which ac­ curately places American farmers' cooperatives in a reasonable ideological and historical perspective. His grouping of the total historical development of cooperatives, his analysis of the ideological underpinning and the relation of consumer cooperatives to farmer co­ operatives in the United States far eclipses that of any sociological publication brought to the attention of this author. Kress's work is indeed a classic in the history of cooperatives and as such will be relied upon heavily throughout this thesis. Three other important works contribute to the historical treat­ ment of American farmer cooperatives. This treatment is not a specific goal of the publications but is a welcome by-product of their efforts. The earliest, Justus Solon Buck's study of the Granger Movement, has sections in which he describes the Grange Agencies, business coopera­ tion (cooperative buying and selling, cooperative stores, manufacturing, banking, and insurance) activities of the Patrons of Husbandry. Hicks, in The Populist Revolt published in 1913* devotes considerable time and effort to farmers' grievances between 1870-1897* which figured significantly in the early rise of farmers' cooperatives and farmers' organizations, which in turn led to the Populist Revolt. A more modern historical treatment has been done by Saloutos in his analysis of Farmer Movements in the South. 1865-1933. reprinted in i960 . While much of his work overlaps Buck's study of the Granger Movement and Hicks's Populist Revolt, Saloutos' contribution is significant 11 because it deals with causes and reasons for agrarian unrest for that period. It is especially significant in background material for this thesis because he deals with the failure of the Farm Bureau to in­ fluence the South. Another historical publication of significance to this review of the literature is the somewhat partisan history of the Farm Bureau Federation by 0. M. Kile, published in 1948. While it is rather partisan, it does give interesting and accurate insight into the issues and philosophy which guided the development of the Farm Bureau. Kile also does well to demonstrate the relationship of the Bureau to the cooperatives' development, especially in the Midwest. covers in detail the Bureau's political activities. important to this thesis for two reasons: He also This work is first, because the data have been collected from Michigan cooperatives affiliated with the Farm Bureau and, second, because it does not deal with the extreme change in approach taken by the Farm Bureau Federation since 19J+8. The utopian views of social reformer, Robert Owen, in his New View of Society: or, Essays on the Principle of the Formulation of the Human Character, published in l8l3, represents the most liberal root of the cooperative movements--a collectivism conceived and nurtured to counteract the child labor abuses, poverty, degradation, and economic slavery of the industrial worker caught in the Industrial Revolution and Factory System of l8th Century England. In 1964, in affluent America, a publication brings to full 12 circle the wide range of approaches to cooperatives. Raymond W. Miller, Harvard Business School Lecturer; President, Public Relations Research Associates, Inc. and World Trade Relations, Inc.; a member of the Board of Trustees of American University; and a member of the Bar of the Supreme Court of the United States, has written a book called A Conservative Looks at Cooperatives. His book is dedicated to two great 20th Century "bridge builders of cooperation"--Edward A. Filene (founder of the Credit Union Move­ ment) and Herbert Hoover (twenty-ninth president of the United States). To demonstrate the unusual nature of this publication it may be well to quote Vernon R. Alden, President, Ohio Univer­ sity, who wrote the foreword to Miller's book. In it Alden says of Miller: Throughout his career, he has been a constant champion for the cooperative cause. . . .Always his vision has been that cooperatives bring to their members that special initiative, health, and hope that one usually associates with arguments advocating capitalism. He carries the message everywhere that cooperatives are a natural and vital segment of a successful capitalistic private enterprise system . . . they represent a step upward toward a more enlightened capitalism.3 In the preface Miller states: . . . My belief is that a conservative is one who recognizes the need for sensible utilization of the resources available, and that a cooperative is an instrument through which a greater distribution ^Raymond W. Miller, A Conservative Looks at Cooperatives. (Athens, Ohio; Ohio University Press, 1964), pp. ^-6. 15 of ownership can be maintained. . . . Cooperatives bydefinition are the furthest reach from statism; and con­ servatives, when faced by economic and social problems, try to solve them in voluntary joint effort, going to government for help only as a last resort. . . . Co­ operatives and conservatives are ideological twins. . . . My hope is that this book will serve as a statement of my belief that cooperatives are conservative organiza­ tions dedicate'! to individual ownership and to the principles of fficient and enlightened operation. Historically, thought about the function, purposes, and reasons for cooperative organization has gone from the very far left to the very far right. On the one hand, as Kress and his colleagues point out, the cooperative movement grew out of the utopian community, collectivism, and abusive capitalistic traditions; that it flourished, grew, and was imported to America via Canada as a response to abuses and inequities of early capitalism. On the other hand, As Miller and most American historians purport, the cooperative movement is not only specifically and indigenously American but also rural and farm; and a cooperative is a farm-owned business directed toward meeting farmers' economic needs. It is "ideological twins with conservatives," and a vital segment of a successful capitalistic private enterprise system." These then have been the two poles representing the extremes of thought about the philosophic and ideological background of co­ operatives. Even so, up to this point we are still unaware of the true nature of the ideological position of farmer cooperatives as held by the people who manage them and who are members of them. An attempt to gain some insight into this problem is the purpose of this thesis. ^Ibid., pp. 8-9. lb Sociological Analyses of Cooperatives For the most part it can be observed that sociological effort in the study of cooperatives has been deficient in the following areas: 1. Very little attention has been paid to the histori­ cal perspective. 2. Little work has been done on the historical relation­ ship between consumer and producer cooperative ideology. 3. While sociologists have often referred to the phenomenon as the "cooperative movement" it has not been studied as a social movement. 4. Most sociological work has handled farmers' coopera­ tives within the framework of farmers' organizations. This in itself is not a glaring fault, but it may have contributed to a lack of interest in ideological issues. 5. Because cooperatives (especially farriers' coopera­ tives) have not been viewed as a movement, they have not been studied within the broader framework of either the world cooperative movement or the American agrarian movement. Consequently, no adequate, systematic study of cooperative ideology has been made, much less studies which would allow one to observe ideological change over 15 time, fusion with business ideology or insti­ tutionalization into the broader societal "cultural norms." This has been abdicated to essayists, speculative propagandists, and thoughtful historians. Within the past eight to ten years there have been two attempts to review and organize sociological research done on farmers' coopera­ tives. These efforts were directed toward developing a research frame of reference and general hypotheses for future guidance and testing. Unfortunately both attempts have been heavily influenced by Taylor's contention that since farmers' organizations and agricul­ tural cooperatives grew up together they can be researched together. Wakeley's report to the Rural Sociological Society,5 a report of the Ad Hoc Subcommittee on Farmers' Organizations and Agricultural Cooperatives, reflects the influence of Taylor's theoretical approach to conceptually combining farmers' organizations with.farmers' co­ operatives of all kinds. This is a position held by Taylor since 1933 when he stated that cooperative marketing was the end product of the farmers' movement.^ This in itself deserves no criticism ^Ray E. Wakeley, "Sociological Research on Farmers' Organizations and Agricultural Cooperatives, " Rural Sociology, XXII, No. 3 (September, 1957)/ 27^-280. This is a report of the Ad Hoc Subcommittee on Farmers' Organizations and Agricultural Cooperatives for the Rural Sociological Society.- Members of the committee were Carl C. Taylor (chairman), Howard W. Beers, Lowry Nelson, Macklin John, Duane L. Gibson, George M. Beal, and Emory J. Brown. ^Carl C. Taylor, Rural Sociology (rev.). (New York: Harper & Brothers, 1935)^ P* 6 7 ^ 16 except that it has in some ways stifled the development of theoretical thinking about cooperatives. It has had, as pointed out above, some effect on the treatment of farmers' cooperatives outside of the theoretical realm of the world cooperative movement and restricted them to an ancillary result of econo-political farmer movements. C. C. Taylor was chairman of the Ad Hoc Committee; Wakeley's report reflects Taylor's early views on how cooperatives should be studied. Wakeley continued to reflect this thinking even until 1961, when he published an article with Beal, to be discussed in detail later, on research on farmer cooperatives in the United States. According to Wakeley's report the task of the_committee was to explore and outline the uses of sociological analysis in investigating the problems of farmers' organizations and agricultural cooperatives in three ways: 1. Definition of the major research units. 2. Consideration of useful sociological frameworks. 3. Description of research areas, with selected illustration of testable hypotheses.^ References made to the study of farmers' organizations, per-se, have little relevance for this thesis. Therefore, the literature cited from this point forward will be done selectively in terms of farmers' cooperatives, and preferably farmers' purchasing operatives. co­ Wakeley's report states (in the section on the definition ^Wakeley, op. cit., p. 274. IT of research units) that Loomis and Beegle agree with Taylor that cooperatives were organized to right actual or imagined wrongs re­ sulting from the development of the market and price system over which farms had no effective control and to which as individuals Q they were unable to make any satisfactory a d j u s t m e n t s ). When compared to farmers' organizations, cooperatives are more economic in function and more limited in scope, and the forms of organization and the techniques of operation are more rigidly specified.9 Therefore, the various possible definitions of a cooperative present somewhat different implications for research. Three basic definitions exist. One, the legal definition-- legally a cooperative is what the law says it is. In most cases this restricts or defines the possible scope, range of operations, financial posture, and liability characteristics of the cooperative. The Wakeley report states that this offers no common basis or framework for scientific research. This represents an oversight on the part of the committee because the legal restrictions and privileges placed on and granted to cooperatives have great in­ fluence upon their structure, mode of operation, relationship to members, managerial capability, response to competition, capital flow, marketing strategies, and tax obligations. As evidence, the American Institute of Cooperation devotes two sections of its ^Ibid., p. £75 . Also see C. C. Taylor, 195°; Chapter 29, where he presents this contention in great detail. 9Ibid. 18 annual meeting to these problems: e. g., one section was entitled "Attorneys Working With Co-ops" and another section "Cooperative Accountants."1*1 The second definition of a cooperative presented in the Wakeley report was the business definition. This definition, consistent with the conservative historical point of view discussed earlier, purports that a cooperative is merely a business enterprise con­ trolled by a membership corporation instead of a stock corporation and hence is only an alternative organization and method of con­ ducting a business.11 The implication here is that if the "just another type of business" hypothesis were true, cooperatives could be studied within the "theory of the firm" framework placing em­ phasis on investigation of line-staff relationships, flow charts, marketing strategy, response to competition, leadership, executive succession, and channels of distribution. The third definition is an economic definition. It describes agricultural cooperatives as participating farm firms 'joined by agreements to conduct some business deemed essential by the par­ ticipants. It is a means by which farm firms maximize returns from the farm operation. Thus, the decision to join becomes a management decision.1^ The Wakeley report states that not all farmers' cooperatives "conduct their affairs for prudential objectives alone . . . " In ^American Institute of Cooperation, American Cooperation: A Collection of Papers, pp. 151-17^ 201-217* 1952• 11Wakeley, op cit., p. 275* lgIbid., pp. 275-276. 19 such asituation the sociologist analysis may be called upon to make an of the cooperative from the standpoint of competing value systems. The Wakeley report makes the following suggestions or sociological frameworks for the analysis of human relationships in cooperatives: 1. Problem solving or social action framework— Problems which call for research relate to the logical steps in problem solving, the rational choices among al­ ternatives, and the application of means-ends analysis to the attainment of chosen objectives. 2. Formal organization framework--Emphasis in the past has been placed on reasons for joining, on member participation, and on factors affecting participation. Studies of participation have not been fruitful because of the difficulty of measur­ ing both economic and sociological aspects. Measures of social distance, social status, ef­ fectiveness of communication, and functioning of leaders are needed. 3. Ideal type and polar type framework— Measures need to be developed so that the actual and the ideal can be compared more accurately and completely from both the sociological and the economic points of view. 13wakeley, Ibid., p. 276 4. Ecological framework--The spatial distribution of cooperatives and their members. 5. Social systems framework--"Cultural sub-systems which are composed of persistent patterns of roles and relationships, of structured systems of values, comprise the cultural basis on which groups operate and by which they are re­ lated to the social system. The Wakeley report concludes by listing a number of hypotheses which could be tested. Those hypotheses which have some bearing on the degree of cooperative and/or business ideology, the subject of this thesis, will be cited. A. These are as follows: Group objectives and -long-time ends 1. Making or saving money for members is nec­ essary, but it is not a sufficient reason for maintaining an agricultural cooperative. 2. Farmers' organizations or agricultural co­ operatives which have only punitive, yard­ stick, or antimonopoly objectives will decline when need for such objectives is no longer recognized. B. Personnel maintenance and participation Farmers identify more closely with farmers' organizations and agricultural cooperatives than they do with other private businesses 1^Wakeley, Ibid'., pp. 276-277. 21 because they are members and patrons of the former but only customers of the latter. C. Processes of social interaction and change Decisions regarding methods of interaction and strategy are more often made by pro­ fessional or managerial personnel than by the members of the organization."^ In 1961 Wakeley and Harp broadened their notion of research needs on farmer cooperatives to include social systems; ecological, interdis­ ciplinary, and typological analyses; and social change. Of past research, they noted that: A majority of the sociological research on farmer cooperatives has been of a problem solving nature, and as such is reflective of the melioristic tradition of rural sociology. Numerous studies on member relations and participation have been carried out over the years. There is a need, however, for research on the genesis and transformation of cooperatives in American society, viewed as a social movement. To date only a few at­ tempts have been made at a typological analysis of. socia movement. The preceding constitutes a somewhat neglected field of sociological inquiry. Although research cannot say what the goals and values of the cooperative movement ought to be, it can play a useful role in identifying the values that are actually held by cooperative leaders. It seems clear that there is not just one set of values or principles of cooperation held by persons in positions of leader­ ship but rather that many different viewpoints are held by different individuals and that some of £hese view­ points may be out of harmony with others.-'-0 ■^Wakeley, Ibid,, pp. 2f8-279* •'-'-’Ray E. Wakeley and John Harp, "An Overview of Sociological Research on Farmer Cooperatives in the United States," International Archives of Sociology of Cooperation, Paris, France (Summer" 1966), p. 6 5 . 22 If one were to heed the advice of Wakeley and his associates it would appear that his concern about "conflicting value systems" could be combined with the "identification of values" and the study of the "genesis and transformation of cooperatives viewed as social movements" for fruitful research. In the absence of adequate longitudinal data on farmers' coopera­ tives it would appear that the suggestions that cooperatives be studied as a social movement could be approached by studying the degree of commitment on the part of cooperative leaders and members toward co­ operative ideology in modern farmers' cooperatives. CHAPTER III THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS IN THE STUDY OF COOPERATIVES Literature on Social Movements Departing from the very broad definition of farmers' movements, as outlined above in reference to Taylor, and within the framework of social movements, it is pertinent to address ourselves to the question of whether or not the cooperative movement can in fact be considered within the theoretical frame of social movements in general. Gerth and Mills discuss social movements within the structural context of collective behavior and view this phenomenon. . . . in terms of the degree of explicit organization: at one end of the scale there are what appear to be purely spontaneous activities; at the other, there is a merging of collective behavior with institutional organization it­ self . . . there does seem to be a sort of drift exhibited by collective behavior, if it endures beyond the momentary, towards institutionalization. Furthermore, all forms of collective behavior, no matter how momentary, are related to various institutional orders and spheres: they cannot be explained without reference to them. For institutional structures are the precipitants and the foci of collective behavior of every sort; they are the larger frameworks within which such behavior arises and through which it runs its course . . . but this does not mean that collec­ tive behavior does not modify the institutional structure.-1Gerth and Mills, for the sake of classification, conceive of move­ ments, parties, and pressure groups as sub-classes within the general concept of collective behavior. -LHans Gerth and C. Wright Mills, Character and Social Structure. (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1953 )> P- ^28. 23 24 A movement attempts to change institutions, from the outside, from the inside, or both. Like institutions, movements are organized enough to permit a turnover of members without loss of identity as movements, and their members are more or less aware of themselves as having common interests and/or principles. It recruits members, usually from selected class and status levels, who are more or less ready to act in certain ways, and it lends to them its orienting aim: in some way to change some institutional setup. Whether based on interest, on principle, or on both, people are united in voluntary associations in a more or less energetic struggle for power, which, so far as the leadership is concerned, means power of an instituted sort for the leaders,. . . Pressure groups are associations which use political means for the promotion of strictly economic, usually class, interests; parties do the reverse; even declared "class parties" use economic means, as well as political, for both economic and political ends."1 Movements are composed of people who are attempting to change their position with reference to the'personnel or the structure of institutions. The people involved need not share common values; and they may be quite variously motivated in such a way as to converge or coincide in the movement's direction. But whether or not the people involved are conscious of common ends or are propelled by similar motives is not necessary to their definition as a movement, but must be deter­ mined in any given case . . . movements may be located in any one or in several of the institutional orders . . .(and) may also be classified in terms of how fargoing their aims may be . . . therefore, in examining a social movement one may first locate it at each phase through which it runs, within institutional orders and spheres, and within classes and status levels--in terms of at least three aspects: 1. Its professed goals and policies, whether they are reformative or revolutionary and what their specific contents are; 2. The recruitment and composition of its members and leaders; and 5. Its objective functions; that is, one must 2Ibid., pi. 458-439. 25 ask cui bono--to whose benefit does its existence and operation redound?3 Gerth and Mills conclude their treatment of social movements on a methodological note when they say: We can describe them (anti-capitalistic move­ ments and parties) systematically, as we can describe any movement or party, by examining their (l) u l ­ timate goals and (2) typical ways of attaining them, (5) their immediate expectations and (k) demands, (5) their general conception of history and (6) the organizational levers they would use, (7 ) their dominant mode of action and (8) the composition of their predominant membership, (9 ) the types of leaders and staff they have displayed, and (lO) their objective political results. Broom and Selznick, in their discussion of social movements, tend to emphasize the primacy of ideology as a necessary feature in the development of such movements. They also treat their study within the framework of collective behavior and social change, with heavy emphasis on the latter. Like Taylor, they are concerned with felt maladjustments and presumed evils as the impetus of the movement. In discussing social movements, they state: For the most part, social change occurs gradually and without design. However, new perspectives and as­ pirations often generate collective action to combat presumed evils and to institute new ways of life. Sometimes the action is sporadic and temporary, as in the case of isolated uprisings against oppressive con­ ditions. When collective action is more unified and lasting and has certain characteristic features, we call it a "social movement." The main features of a social movement' are: 1. A distinctive perspective and ideology. "’Ibid., pp. AbO-44l. Ibid., p. A51- The 26 ideology of a movement provides direction and self­ justification; it offers weapons of attack and de­ fense; and it holds out inspiration and hope. Great emphasis is placed on ideology, particularly when other sources of orientation and cohesion are lacking. 2. A strong sense of solidarity and idealism. Membership in a movement typically means more to the individual than other affiliations. He is a "dedicated" man and feels part of an idealistic and active enterprise. Idealism plays a role in all movements, political or religious, "progressive" or "reactionary," and it is especially important in the early stages. 3. An orientation toward action. The very word "movement" suggests unconventional methods of appeal, such as street meetings and the sale of propaganda tracts. Small movements can sometimes gain wide attention by dramatic actions, particularly if they involve violence.-. The stress on action in part reflects the problem of maintaining interest and solidarity. There is a constant need to "give the members something to do" to keep them from slipping away to other interests and involvement is usually made up of a variety of forms and groupings . . . tends to follow a roughly discernible "career," from its origins in unrest to its end in institutionalization.5 Turner and Killian suggest four types of movements, based upon the public definition of the movement's relation to the basic value scheme of the society, and accordingly involving the general type of opposition that will be evoked and the access to legitimatechannels of action. For example: Public Definition Type of Opposition Means of Action (1) Respectable-nonfactional Disinterest and token Legitimate means (2) Respectable-factional Competing movements advocating same gen­ eral objective Legitimate means ^Leonard Broom and Phillip Selznick, Sociology: A Text With Adapted Readings. (Evanston, Illinois: Row Peterson and Company, 1955)> pp. 302-304 . 27 (5) Peculiar Ridicule and ostracism Limited access to legitimate means (*0 Revolutionary Violent suppression Chiefly il mate means1 Hopper suggests a natural history approach to the analysis of social movements and postulates that revolutionary movements pass through four stages in their development. These stages are: 1. The preliminary stage of mass (individual) excitement 2. The popular stage of crowd (collective) excitement and unrest 3. The formal stage of the formulation of issues and ■formation of publics k. The institutional stage of legalization and social organization? Smelser distinguishes between norm-oriented and value-oriented movements. The norm-oriented movement he defines as one which attempts to restore, protect, modify, or create norms in the name of generalized belief. Participants may be trying either to affect norms directly Q or to induce some constituted authority to do so. Likewise, a value- oriented movement is a collective attempt to restore, protect, modify, or create values in the name of a generalized belief; however, such a belief necessarily involves all the components of action; that is, it envisions a reconstitution of values, a redefinition of norms, a ^Ralph H. Turner and Lewis H. Killian, Collective Behavior. (Englewood Cliffs, N. J . : Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1957); PP* 307-308* ^Rex D. Hopper, in R. H. Turner and Lewis H. Killian, Collective Behavior, pp. 310-319• ®Neil J. Smelser, Theory of Collective Behavior. (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1963), p. 270. 28 reorganization of the motivation of individua's, and a redefinition of situational facilities.' In discussing the concept of social movement, Heberle points out that the criteria for defining such a movement are as follows: 1. That a social movement aims to bring about funda­ mental changes in the social order, especially in the basic institutions of property and labor rela­ tionship . 2. That mere similarity of sentiments occurring inde­ pendently among a large number of people does not constitute a movement, nor does mere imitative mass action. A sense of group identity and solidarity is required, for only when the acting individuals have become aware of the fact that they have sentiments and goals in common--when they think of themselves as being united with' each other in action through these sentiments and for these goals--do we acknowledge the existence of a social movement. In short, Heberle treats social movements as a "kind of social collective" as distinguished from pressure groups, parties, and action groups.^ Abel views social movements as a mode of pluralistic ^Ibid., p. 513 Rudolf Heberle, Social Movements: An Introduction to Political Sociology. (New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts, Inc., 1951), PP- &-9* 29 behavior--a collective effort occurring within the medium of a com­ munity. He points out the importance, in defining a social movement, of including values (ideology) which are a threat to existing values, as well as stressing the opportunity to promote certain values.^ King says that social movements may be distinguished from other phenomena on the basis of the kind of goals to which they are committed --their goal is to change relationships, or norms, or beliefs, or all of thesej they employ organization as a means of achieving their goals, and they become formalized to some extent; finally, they may be identified by their geographical scope. Contrary to Abel, King feels that social movements tend to extend beyond single communities or local bonds. His general definition is "a group venture extending beyond a local community or a single event and involving a systematic effort to inaugurate changes in thought, behavior, and social relation­ ships." King specifies the relevant elements of social movements to be (l) goals, (2) means, (3) ideology, (h) group cohesion, (5 ) or- •I Q ganization, (6) a status system, and (7 ) tactics. In summary, the central theme which runs through writings on social movements is a theme of development. Within the framework of collective behavior, most authors view social movements as a group, aggregate, or collectivity, responding to some maladjustment or felt need for change, resistance, or innovation, and that these collectivi­ ties develop, over time, distinctive perspectives, distinctive "^Theodore Abel, "The Pattern of a Successful Political Movement, " American-Sociological Review, II (April, 1937); 3^7-352. Wendell King, Social Movements in the United States. (New York: Random House, Inc.j 1956), PP* 25 - 36 . 50 ideologies, strong solidarity, strong idealism, leadership roles, and membership roles; these collectivities persist over time, have varying degrees of continuity, are oriented to varying degrees and types of action, can be said to pass through a "life cycle," and ultimately pass out of existence or become institutionalized. The Place of Ideology in the Study of Farmers 1 Cooperatives In retrospect, historical and sociological literature about co­ operatives tends to follow two different trends. The historical litera­ ture deals almost wholly with the broad longitudinal perspective, with great emphasis placed on the traditional beliefs and counter-beliefs ..hich serve as a basis for social action. The sociological literature tends to take a more pragmatic, horizontal approach, emphasizing in * turn structures, ecological systems, an; interdisciplinary models. Only when it is pointed out that sociologists have been deficient in using the social movement model for the study of farmers' cooperatives, do they recommend the historical and longitudinal approach. (The "natural history" approach to the study of social movements especially as pro­ posed by Hopper is in fact a longitudinal-historical methodology.) Throughout the published works by sociologists about cooperatives, works in which cooperatives are constantly being referred to as move­ ments, there appear to be many latent references to an underlying belief system and to cooperative values. The inference undoubtedly is to- a felt ideology, to a suspected ideological commitment, but is neither rationally nor scientifically defined. This is perhaps because the concept is, in and of itself, at best, elusive. These ideological in­ ferences are as follows: 1. Cooperatives were organized to right actual or imagined wrongs resulting from the development of the market and price system over which farmers had no control. 2. Cooperatives are merely business enterprises controlled by a membership corporation rather than stockholders. As such, they are only an alternative way for farmers to conduct business. 3. Not all farmers' cooperatives conduct their affairs for prudential objectives alone; some have a strong idealistic orientation and could be studied from the standpoint of competing value systems. h. Cultural subsystems which are composed of persistent patterns of roles and relationships and of structured systems of values comprise the cultural basis on which groups operate . . . 5. Agricultural cooperatives must have better reasons for existence than being punitive, being a yardstick to measure capitalism against., and being anti-monopoly. 6. Farmers identify more closely with . . . cooperatives than they do with other private businesses . . . 7. It seems clear that there is not just one set of values or principles of cooperation held by persons 8. As compared with the Grange and the Farmers Union, the Farm Bureau Federation has more of a business character and viewpoint and is more pragmatic and less idealistic. 9- Evolution may substitute cooperative democracy for the stat e . ^ These are but a few of the examples where sociologists have in­ dicated that there seems to be a cooperative ideologica.1 value system. The necessity for the ideological consideration in the study of social movements has been pointed out by many. Gerth and Mills state that Ih common values must be determined; Broom and Selznick emphasize the primacy of ideology inthe development of social movements;^ and Killian'discuss Turner social movements based upon the publicdefinition of the movement's relation to the basic value scheme of the society;^ Hopper lists, as one of the stages of development, the formulation of i s s u e s S m e l s e r describes value-oriented movements'as a collective attempt to create values in the name of a generalized belief; l8 Heberle points out that a social movement comes into existence when "they think of themselves as being united with each other in action through these IbR. Warbasse in 1956, as quoted by A.'J. Kress in Introduction to the Cooperative Movement, p. 291. -^H. Gerth and C. W. Mills, op. cit.,pp. 438-439* ■^L. Broom and P. ^R. Selznick, op. cit.,pp. 302-504. H. Turner and L. H. Killian, op. cit., pp. 307-480. ■^R. D. Hopper, in Turner and Killian, op. cit., pp. 310-519* ^N. J. Smelser, op. cit., p. 313* 35 sentiments and for these g o a l s " ; -*-9 Abel defines social movements as a mode of pluralistic behavior including values which are a threat to existing values, as well as an opportunity to promote certain values; PO and King specifies ideology as one of the seven relevant elements in social movements.^ In summary, therefore, there appears to be ample theoretical justification for viewing the social movement phenomena in terms of the degree and type of ideological commitment of the movement's members (participants); that is, if the presence of a well-defined ideology is viewed as an essential element of a social movement and if a given social phenomenon.can be or is referred to as a social movement, the converse is the case, viz., that if a social phenomenon is classified as a social movement, a well-defined ideology is present. Then it follows that since farmers' cooperatives are referred to as social movements, it is reasonable to hypothesize that within that movement there exists a well-defined ideology which can be called a Cooperative Ideology. This follows from Wakeley and Harp who seated that "There is a need . . . for research on the genesis and transformation of cooperatives in American society, viewed as a social movement . . . and although research cannot say what the goals and values of the coopera­ tive movement ought to be, it can play a useful role in identifying 1^R. Heberle, op. cit., pp. 6-9. 20T. Abel, op. cit., pp. 3^7-352. 2lC. W. King, op. cit., pp. 25 -38 . • 3^ the values that are actually held by cooperative l e a d e r s . T h i s , in addition to the fact that the 1957 Wakeley report defines farmers' co­ operatives in legal, business, and economic terms, and supports the contention that ideology is a legitimate sphere of investigation. It has been theoretically established that some measure of ideological commitment is a prerequisite to the identification and classification of certain collective behavior as a social movement. Therefore, if we are to try to view Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Co­ operatives as a social movement, one way in which this could be done is to attempt to operationalize and measure the degree and/or existence of an ideology as held by leaders and/or members in the hypothesized movement. Since the sociological literature on social movements does not yield useful operational models and since most of what we know to be cooperative ideology comes from historical reviews and "movement" documents, it is necessary to establish a sound theoretical justifica­ tion to aid in the operationalization of ideology. To.do this, as will be demonstrated, it is necessary to consider not only the complex theory of ideology but also its relation to the theory of the sociology of knowledge and belief-value theory, for it is within the frame of reference of social movements as related to ideology in turn related to the sociology of knowledge that the measurement of values becomes the operationalization of ideological commitment within the context of ^ R . E. Wakeley and J. Harp, "An Overview of Sociological Research on Fanner Cooperatives in the United States, " International Archives of Sociology of Cooperations, Paris, France (Summer, 1966 ), p. 35• 55 social action; that is, value theory will furnish the operational definition which can be justified by showing the logical relationships among values, beliefs, knowledge, and ideology, the latter a pre­ requisite to defining social behavior as characteristic of social movements. Norman Birnbaum was the author of Volume IX, Number 2, i960 issue of Current Sociology, entitled "The Sociological Study of Ideology (19^0-60): A Trend Report and Bibliography." In this report he re­ viewed the theoretical and research trends in ideology for the twentyyear period 19^0-60. To discuss these trends he collected a biblio­ graphy of 702 sources but classified them into five major categories and forty-five sub-categories. abstract of each publication. In addition, Birnbaum wrote a short He summarized the salient aspects of the trends in the sociological study of ideology in the following manner: The sociological study of ideology raises, in acute form, some of the most pressing problems of contemporary sociology . . . (It) is at the intersection of the empirical and philosophical components of our dis­ cipline. 23 The very diffuseness of the literature points to the continuing problem of an adequate definition of the notion of ideology. For this essay, it suffices to assume that ideologies appear wherever-systematic factual assertions about society contain (usually by implication) evaluations of the distribution of power in the societies in which these assertions are developed and propagated. We may suppose that a group generally accepts a view of society consonant with its interests; ..e need not think that ideologies are consciously fashioned to serve these interests or .^Norman Birnbaum, "The Sociological Study of Ideology (19^-0-60): A Trend Report and Bibliography," Current Sociology, IX, No. 2 (i960 ), p. 91. 36 that groups are incapable of acting upon beliefs which appear to contradict these interests. According to Birnbaum, the sociological study of ideology, since 1990, may be described as follows: 1. Empirical and theoretical work have developed in disjointed fashion . . .There have been no definitive theoretical advances to compare with the work of Karl Mannheim. 2. A revival of Marxist analysis has occurred. 5. The enormous increase in our detailed knowledge of contemporary social structures which has ac­ companied the widespread utilization of the standard techniques of sociological research has not produced a concomitant enrichment of theory. Rather, some attempts have been made to adjust the scope of the theory of ideology to the limits set by these techniques. 4. The techniques of analysis of the inner structure of ideology originally derived from neo-positivism have become less prominent.25 In a detailed discussion of Mannheim's work, Birnbaum pointed out that: Mannheim's conception of a total ideology is, in fact, a sociological formulation of the familiar notion of the Zeitgeist. His distinction between ideologies and utopias, the latter opposing new ideas to existing systems of society and thought, the former justifying these systems# contains many inconsistencies. It does insert the problem of historical movement in the analysis of ideology. Mannheim's epistemological "relationism" is surely questionable, but it does have the merit of drawing one of the possible conse­ quences of a sociology of knowledge; it faces up to the problem of a standard of truth by which ideologies may be judged.2° 2^Ibid., p. 91 . 2^Ibid., pp. 91-92. 26Ibid., p. 9k. 37 Perhaps we may assert that whereas Mannheim (who was influenced by Weber) generalized the Marxist view of ideology, abandoning class as the sole source of ideologies and replacing it by the total social structure . . . (as well a s ) a plurality of his­ torical systems in which class was but one com­ ponent . . . Weber's influence . . . consists of an emphasis on the historical study of large scale structural problems. . .2^ Birnbaum points out that the work of James, Veblen, and Dewey, American behaviorists, "clearly provided for the analysis of ideologies as modes of adaption to changing environments, and did not make an abstract conception of science the culmination of intellectual evolu­ tion. "28 Birnbaum states that the studies of ideology have been concen­ trated in the following areas: 1. Studies, chiefly psychoanalytic, of psychological processes. a) Some studies established connections be­ tween regularities in character formation and the adult acceptance of certain kinds of ideological form and content (culture' and personality). b) Studies of personal adjustment to rapid change, disappointed expectations, and personality ad­ justment, such as Erickson's studies of personal identity, and Bettelheim and Janowitz's work on prejudice, have been done. Bettelheim's study of personality in concentration camps and American studies of "brainwashing" have yielded interesting data on the ideological components of the response of personality to crisis. c) The influence of psychological mechanisms on ideology formation such as The Authoritarian Personality studies. 27rbid., p. 98. 28Ibid., p. 97* 58 2. Studies of the structure and effects of mass communica­ tion. -a) Inquiry into the mass media has utilized three techniques: content analysis derived from the history and criticism of literature; the social survey; a formalized analysis of content de­ rived from the philosophy of neo-positivism and m o d e m statistics. b) These studies have demonstrated the existence of an intellectual and ideological stratifica­ tion of modern industrial populations . . . differences of education, associated with differences of occupation, in turn produce differences of experience and taste which are reflected in, and maintained by, the distribution of communications. c) A counter-point states that communications are received, interpreted, and utilized in terms of the group's existing, ideological pre-disposition. 5- Studies of the internal structure of ideological systems (including art, myth, and religion). a) Levi-Strauss' work on myth "seeks to identify what is essential in social structure. . . He invariably arrives at problems of economic power, and sexuality (kinship) . . . in which myth and psychic structure may be understood as ideological depictions of what Marxism knows as the forces and relationships of production." b) The more orthodox sort of work on the History of Ideas has not made any theoretical advance in the analysis of ideology. Studies of class consciousness. a) The study of correlations between ideology and political behavior, or their absence, does not necessarily afford conclusive evidence on the depth or potential efficacy of ideologies ap­ parently inconsonant with behavior as observed at any one moment. b) Birnbaum criticizes contemporary data on ideology because it is gathered from questionnaires on 39 large samples. He does relent and agree that there have been advances in index construction and scaling. c) On the basis of empirical studies revolutionary proletarian sentiment has indeed not been found in Western Europe and the United States of America. d) Many studies overemphasize temporary fluctuations in working-class attitudes and beliefs. e) Scattered studies have been made on middle-class consciousness as well as studies of elites, anti­ colonial movements, and nationalism.29 Birnbaum concludes his classification of the 19^-0-60 work on ideology with the categories of (l) studies of the ideological biases of social science and (2) studies of intellectuals. These two cate­ gories will not be discussed because they have little bearing on the subject of this thesis. In summary, Birnbaum defines ideology as a view of society and/or beliefs on the part of groups consistent with their interests and adds that these views of society and/or beliefs arise wherever they (members of groups) become aware of the distribution of power within these groups (societies). This definition intimates the possibility of making an ideological analysis of total societies but does not restrict such analysis to this area. One gets the impression that he is un­ clear on this point. In the preface of his translated work of Karl Mannheim, Ideology andUtopia,30 Louis Wirth discusses two vital issues in the study of 2^Ibid., pp. 107-108 . 3°Karl Mannheim, Ideology and Utopia: An Introduction to the Sociology of Knowledge, translated from the German by Louis Wirth and Edward Shils. (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1936). ideology. His first discussion revolves around the presence of con­ flicting and anomic norms and beliefs in his contemporary society. He becomes concerned with the general distrust of the validity of ideas, where self-aggrandizement rather than truth are the goals of the in­ tellectuals. His is indeed a world of secularization, nisms, and competition, social antago­ impinging upon regions heretofore reserved wholly to the disinterested and objective search for truth. He dwells on the difficulties of social scientists in participating in open, frank, and objective inquiry of social ideas. This is difficult be­ cause in most societies an inquiry into the most sacred and cherished institutions and beliefs is restricted, i.e., societal norms prescribe what one in fact is allowed to investigate. In addition, it is diffi­ cult for social scientists to be objective, i.e., to have no prefer­ ences, predilections or prejudices, no biases, no preconceived values or judgments in the presence of facts. One must be aware of the problems and pitfalls in the search for valid social knowledge, es­ pecially when one is studying social knowledge (ideas) itself. The second issue, a philosophical-anthropological issue, is addressed to the proposition that "if . . . the social sciences are concerned with objects that have meaning and value, the observer who attempts to understand them must necessarily do so by means of categories which in turn depend on his own values and meanings. Wirth points out that . there has been relatively little attention given by American sociologists to the concrete analysis of interests and values in historical doctrines 31Ibid., pp. xx-xxi. - and movements. hi At this point, Wirth deals with ideology. He reviews what in his judgment is the treatment of the subject by Mannheim. Mannheim, according to Wirth, traces the connection between interest groups in society and the ideas and modes of thought which they hold. He (Mannheim) has shown that ideologies, i.e., "those complexes of ideas which direct activity toward the maintenance of the existing order, and utopias--or those complexes of ideas which tend to generate activities toward changes of the prevailing order--do not merely de­ flect attention from the object of observation, but also serve to fix attention upon aspects of the situation which otherwise would be ob­ scured or pass unnoticed. "3^ He points out that Mannheim, instead of positing a pure intellect, is concerned with the actual social conditions in which intelligence and thought emerge. 33 with this statement, Wirth shows that Mannheim has taken thought, ideas, and values out of the psychological into the sociological because "we must consider the fact that social life . . . is to an overwhelming extent concerned with beliefs about the ends of action."3^ Wirth concludes his discussion of the sociology of knowledge and of Mannheim's contribution as seeking "to throw light on the question of how the interests and purposes of certain groups come to find expression in certain theories, doctrines, and intellectual ^2 Ibid., p. xxi. 33xbid. , p. x x ii. 3^lbid. k2 movements."35 He further concludes that the sociology of knowledge needs to have "an adequate understanding of such phenomena (indoctrina­ tion) as these will contribute to a more precise conception of the role of ideas in political and social movements and of the value of knowl­ edge as an instrument in controlling social reality."3^ The Study of Ideology as a Function of the Sociology of Knowledge Of the contemporary scholars, Merton is undoubtedly the foremost in the area of the sociology of knowledge. Following from, but critical of, Mannheim, Merton views the study of ideology not as a subject ana­ lytically discrete but rather as one of the elements within the general framework of the sociology of knowledge. This point of view, con­ sistent with Mannheim, demands a cumbersome but vital theoretical frame of reference in the study of ideology. If one pays attention only to the contemporary collective behavior literature, he could easily be misled into the false complacency that the study of ideology consists only of the social psychological concern for attitudes and opinions and that these can stand theoretically alone. With this in mind, it be­ comes imperative that ideology be placed within the sociology of knowl­ edge context. To accomplish this, it is necessary to reconstitute Merton's formulation into what we will call the "old sociology of knowledge" and the "new sociology of knowledge." 35Ibid., p. xxviii. 3^Ibid., p. xxix. 43 Merton's Paradigm for the Sociology of Knowledge-"The Relations between Knowledge and Other Existential Factors in the Society"37 I. The Old Sociology of Knowledge A. The development of a distinct universe of discourse challenges the validity and legitimacy of others. (Hence) reciprocal distrust leads to reciprocal ideological analyses. B. Array of interpretations of man and culture 1. 2. 34. 5. 6. 7. C. Verbalization and ideas (deceptive of self and other) 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. D. Rationalizations Emotive expressions Distortions Folklore Derivations Ideologies ___ Previously conceived substrata 1. 2. 34. 5. 6. 7. E. Ideological analysis Wissenssoziologie Psychoanalysis Marxism Semanticism Propaganda analysis Parentanism Relations of production Social position Basic impulses Psychological conflict Interests and sentiments Interpersonal relations Residues The unwitting determinations of ideas by the substrata 1. 2. Distinction between real and illusionary Distinction between reality and appearance ^Robert K. Merton, Social Theory and Social Structure. (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1957)> PP. 457-459* kb F. Schemes of analysis which tend to discount the face value of statements, beliefs, and idea-systems by re­ examining them within a new context which supplies the "real meaning." 1. 2. G. Indict, secularize, ironicize, satirize, alienate, devalue Nfyths, illusions, derivations, folklore Not only error or illusion or unauthenticated belief, but also the discovery that truth is socially (his­ torically) conditioned. II. The New Sociology of Knowledge--"As long as attention was focused on the social determinants of ideology (illusion, myth, and moral norms), the sociology of knowledge could not emerge." A. Where is the existential basis of mental productions located? 1. 2. B. Social bases Cultural bases What mental productions are being sociologically analyzed? 1. 2. C. Spheres Which aspects are being analyzed? How are mental productions related to the existential basis? 1. 2. 3. Causal or functional relations Symbolic or organismic or meaningful relations Ambiguous terms to designate relations D. Why (are) manifest and latent functions imputed to these existentially conditioned mental productions? E. When do the imputed relations of the existential base and knowledge obtain? ' 1. 2. Historicist theories General analytical theories Merton, according to his paradigm as outlined above, views the unit of analysis of the sociology of knowledge to be "mental produc­ tions." While Wirth gives Mannheim credit for taking thought, ideas, and values out of the psychological into the sociological, it appears that Merton is returning them to the psychological. In any event, he views his paradigm as a means to organize the distinctive approaches to the sociology of knowledge; extreme on the one hand in that thought has no relation to its validity, to the relativist position on the other hand which says that truth is a function of a social basis, that it depends upon consensus and that any culturally accepted theory of truth is as valid as any other theory. Merton uses Marx, Scheler, Mannheim (in great detail), Durkheim, and Sorokin to illustrate the utility of his paradigm. The presentation of Merton's analysis will be limited to those sections wh:i ch directly reflect insight into the concept and formulation of ideology. ideas with Parsons', His Smelser's, and King's will be used to build the theoretical links among the concepts of social movements, ideology, and values, and will provide a framework within which the empirical investigation of Michigan Farmers' Cooperatives and cooperative and business ideologies may be studied. When attempting to utilize this paradigm, Merton admits the wide diversity of formulations " . . . from the social determination of categorical systems to that of class-bound political ideologies . . ."39 prevents an all-embracing presentation. He compromises and uses selected writings. The part of his paradigm of special interest and application to 3^lbjd., p. k6l. 39jbid., p. b6o. 46 this thesis is what mental productions are being sociologically analyzed? (The use of this formulation does not constitute acceptance on the part of the author that the "unit of analysis" is "mental pro­ ductions.") In this connection, Merton discusses the spheres and as- % pects of mental productions. The spheres are moral beliefs, ideologies, ideas, the categories of thought, philosophy, religious beliefs, social norms, positive science, technology, and the aspects are their selection, level of abstractions, presuppositions, conceptual contents, models of verification, and objectives of intellectual activity. 4o Merton points out that there is a formal consensus which gives rise to a variety of theories that thought has an existential b a s i s . ^ Within this frame­ work, he discusses the strengths and weaknesses of Marxism, which contends that ideologies are socially (class) located, Il 'P that Scheler places cultural data as "ideal" in the realm of ideas and values while "real factors" are oriented toward effecting changes in the reality of nature or society.^ Scheler's position is that these naturalistic theories are in error when they maintain that real factors determine meaningful ideas as well as assuming that the independent variable is one and the same throughout history. Merton feels that Mannheim has extended from Marx the conception of existential bases; Mannheim finds ^°Ibid., p. 46l. ^ I b i d . , p. 462. J+2Ibid., p. 463. ^Ibid., p. 464. "that an organically integrated group conceives of history as a con­ tinuous movement toward the realizations of its goals, whereas socially uprooted and loosely integrated groups espouse an historical intuition " lit which stresses the fortuitous and imponderable; that is, given the case of multiple group membership we must determine which of these affiliations are crucial in fixing ideas, values, and ideologies. Merton contends that Durkheim shares this position. In sharp dis­ tinction, Merton points out that Sorokin's is an "idealistic and emanationist theory which seeks to derive every aspect of knowledge, not from an existential social basis but from varying culture men­ talities. When Merton speaks of the spheres of mental products, he is in fact referring to the various types of knowledge. As he points out, the term knowledge has referred to every type of idea from folk belief to positive science.' In order to analyze the significance of these types of knowledge, iie points out that late in his writings Engels came to realize that the concept of ideological superstructure included a variety of "ideological forms" which differ significantly and that it is not possible to derive the content and development of belief and knowledge merely from an analysis of the historical situation.^ Thus Engels grants natural science and political economy a status distinct from that of ideology . ^ ^ Ibid., p. 465. ^5lbid.f p . hb6. ^°Ibid., p p . A67 -^-6 8 . ^ i'lbid., p. A69. That is, there is a tendency in Marxism to 1*8 consider natural science as different in relation to the economic base from other spheres of knowledge and beliefs. lift' Mannheim, according to Merton, places science in no different sphere than ideology because "social position determines the perspective; i.e., the manner in which one views an object, what one perceives in it, and how one con­ strues it in his t h i n k i n g . S c h e l e r goes to the other extreme and distinguishes a variety of forms of knowledge, ordered in seven classes: (l) myth and legend, language, (2) knowledge implicit in the natural folk- (3 ) religious knowledge, (4) mystical knowledge, philosophical-metaphysical knowledge, (5 ) (6) positive knowledge of mathematics, the natural and cultural sciences, and (7 ) technological r*,-\ knowledge .^ We may feel inclined to quarrel with Scheler's classifi­ cation, but he postulates that: The sociological character of all knowledge, of all forms of thought, intuition and cognition is unquestionable . . . (and that) the forms of the mental processes by means of which knowledge is acquired are always and necessarily co­ determined sociologically, i.e., by the social structure 51 " « • «' In fact, is the generation of ideas, a "mental production," and if so do these productions ap>pear out of nothing or do they arise as a response to and because of the social system in which the actor finds himself? Merton's preoccupation with "scientific" or existentially ^ Ibid., p. ^69 . if9ibld., p. 470. ^^ibid., pp. i*7G-V 71. 51ibid., p. V 71. k9 based knowledge seems more of an overreaction to Durkheim's relativism and Sorokin's "ideational-sensate" approach to intuition as a source of scientific d i s c o v e r y ^ than an attempt to answer the question "Does man live by one universal truth alone?" He ignores the logical possi­ bilities that existentially based truth (scientific thought) may., with logic, itself be of a relativistic sociological origin. Scientific ethnocentrism is no less misleading than any other kind. The theoretical approach (frame) up to this point has been an at­ tempt to link the rural sociological approach to the study of coopera­ tives with other theoretical formulations. Rural sociologists (see Wakeley, Chapter II, page 19) have intimated that the study of farmer cooperatives has been rather pragmatic and devoid of a sound theoretical basis. He suggests, however, that cooperatives be studied within the theory of social movements. Accepting this cue, the theory of social movements was investigated. The longitudinal requirements for the ■ study of a social movement(s) were beyond the scope of' the present study. A potentially fruitful approach, however, was to study coopera­ tives from an ideological point of view. This was indicated by the reiteration of numerous theoreticians that an essential characteristic of a social movement is a well-defined and well-articulated ideology. This point being theoretically sound, an investigation of ideologi­ cal theory was made. It was found that ideology is theoretically handled from many points of view. From one point of view it is regarded as a philosophical-anthropological phenomenon bent on the discussion of the psychic and perceptual nature of man; from another point of view it is 5 ^ I b i d . , p. 471. thought to be a study of the social origins of knowledge, existentially derived from the ultimate truth; and finally it is viewed as the social psychological functions of personally and collectively held opinions, feelings, inclinations, attitudes, values, and commitments. Through­ out, theoreticians speculate and formulate on the basis of all social scientific dilemmas, e.g., what is the origin of the motivation of man in collective action? Does the movement of man to motivated social and collective action spring from within individuals or does motivated social action originate from social action, itself? i.e., social interaction Also, is it a combination of both? If man lives by his beliefs and values, if man is, as Becker con­ tends, a valuing animal, the proper study of man, therefore, is to locate the seat of his values and beliefs, hence, his motivated collective behavior. The answer to this global question is hardly the purpose of this thesis. The purpose is, however, a modest attempt to gain some insight into the place of ideology in the study of social movements. To do this, it now becomes necessary to theoretically com­ bine the notion of values with the notion of the sociology of knowledge, within the framework of cooperatives as a social movement and within the context of the sociology of knowledge and the theory of ideology, i.e., to derive value-belief hypotheses. If this is the case, co­ operatives can be studied in terms of the commitment of members to the values and beliefs of a hypothesized cooperative movement. 51 The Relation of Belief Systems and/or Value Orientations to the Theory of Ideology As pointed out above, King views an ideology as an essential element of a social movement. He defines ideology as: 1. Written or unwritten justification for the move­ ment's existence. 2. The values and ideals it cherishes. 3- The rules by which participants abide, and the sanctions behind these rules. k. A negative doctrine stating what the movement is against. 5* The source from which a movement derives its rationale, its doctrine, its course, and its disciplinary principles. 6 . Dedication to common aims and values,'benefits incidental to the major objectives, negative sanctions, and inspirational l e a d e r s h i p . 53 When discussing the internal factors in the growth of a social move­ ment King states that: Since goals are incorporated in ideology, an ideology stands or falls with the goals it encompasses and from which it is largely derived. Values, attitudes, and norms justify and interpret goals; they also reinforce belief in goals and the need for action in their achievement. At the same time, the ideology defines (through norms) and justifies (through values) the kind of action and machinery necessary for the attainment of goals . . . The minimum function of an ideology in a successful movement is to provide a rationale not only for the objectives, but for the tactical and or­ ganizational means to those objectives . . Ideology . . . (is) often codified as a body of tenets closely woven around the central ideas and ideals of the movement . . . ideology is the dogma deduced from goals . . . (and) is a statement of justification for seeking them . . . Ideology relates(more or less logically) the various elements of the movement into a pattern and also relates the movement to its social setting.^ • 53xing, Passim, pp. 32-33* ^King, op. cit., pp. 69-70* 52 Parsons deals with the concept of ideology within the framework of non-empirical beliefs and/or (shared) evaluative beliefs within and toward a collectivity. Like King, he defines ideology directly in terms of beliefs and values. It is from this point of view, with others, that we will operationalize ideology for empirical testing. According to Parsons: In the context of interaction there is (the) aspect (of) the sharing of beliefs. Beliefs like other elements of culture are internalized as part of the personality of the actor who holds them. That there should be a common belief system shared by ego and alter is in certain respects as important as that the beliefs should be adequate to reality outside the particular interaction system. Be­ cause of this duality of functional reference it is not uncommon for cognitive distortions to have positive functions in an interaction system and thus for them to be resistant to correction in terms of pressures of reality. The primary "pure type" of cognitive orientation, then, is what we may call the system of existential beliefs. It is necessary then to subdivide this category into empirical and non-empirical beliefs. The distinction is simply that ideas or beliefs will be called empirical when, in terms of the major orientations of the cultural tradition of which they are a part, they concern processes which are defined as subject to understanding and manipula­ tion in a pattern of "practical rationality" . . . nonempirical beliefs (are beliefs) concerning subjects which are defined as beyond the reach of the methodology of empirical science or its equivalent in the culture in question.55 Parsons deals with collective values and' views existential beliefs as parallel to evaluative beliefs. This could be connected with Merton's existential basis of mental products. 55Talcott Parsons, The Social System. Glencoe, 1951), PP- 327-329- Parsons ignores the (New York: The Pree Press of 53 mental-productions point of view and deals with the double classifica­ tion of belief systems. He deals with the need to distinguish between the empirical and non-empirical references as well as existential and evaluative references to the system of action. In his discussion of the relevance of the evaluative category in social action, he deals with the issue of the relationship of how does man come to know (sociology of knowledge) and how does man come to evaluate (theory of ideology and the value-belief system)? In his ex­ planation of the evaluative process, he shows the operational relation­ ship among beliefs, values, and ideology. Parsons points out that: When we turn to the evaluative category we may make a parallel distinction. Where the primary reference is empirical we may speak of ideology. The only diffi­ culty with this term is that it refers primarily to the belief system shared by the members of a collectiv­ ity, and for some purposes it may in the theory of action be important to speak of this aspect of the belief system of an individual actor. When the in­ dividual actor is the point of reference we shall try to avoid this difficulty by speaking of a "personal ideology." Finally, when the primary reference is non-empirical we may when the problems of meaning are of paramount significance speak of religious ideas, as distinguished from philosophical. According to this view, then, there is a fundamental symmetry in the relations, on the one hand, of science and ideology, on the other of philosophy and religious ideas. In both cases the transition to the evaluative category means a change in the "stake" the actor has in the belief system, it means the transition from acceptance to commitment. The primary question is no longer that of interest in whether a proposition is "true," but, in addition to that, in a commitment to its implications for the orientation of action as such .-5 Parson's next point emphasizes the evaluative primacy in ideology. 56Ibid., pp. 331-332. 54 He thus establishes the case for the operationalization of ideology as a belief system. When we move to the consideration of ideologies we are no longer dealing with cognitive primacy, but with evaluative primacy. It may be noted that it is impossible for there to be a type of belief system where expressive interests have clear primacy, for there the cognitive interest would be subordinated to the expressive and we would have a system of expressive symbols, not of beliefs An ideology, then, is a system of beliefs, held in common by the members of a collectivity, i.e., a society, or a subcollectivity of one--including a movement deviant from the main culture of the society--a system of ideas which is oriented to the evaluative integration of the collectivity and of the situation in which it is placed, the processes by which it has developed to its given state, the goals to which its members are collectively oriented, and their rela­ tion to the future oourse of events .^ Next, Parsons establishes beliefs as a basis of action: To constitute an ideology there must exist the additional feature that there is some level of evaluative commitment to the belief as an aspect of membership in the collectivity, subscription to the belief system is institutionalized as part of the role of collectivity membership . ™ But as distinguished from a primarily cognitive interest in ideas in the case of an ideology, there must be an obliga­ tion to accept its tenets as the basis of action. As dis­ tinguished from a purely instrumental belief there must be involvement of an idea that the welfare of the collectivity and not merely attainment of a particular goal hinges on the implementation of the belief system.0^ His discussion of the relationship between systems of beliefs and value-orientations as a means to action-dilemmas follows: 5?Ibid., p. 349. 58lbid. 59xbid. 6o Ibld., p. 350. 55 Since there must be relative consistency in the valueorientation patterns of a collectivity--though perfect consistency is not possible--this consistency must ex­ tend to the system of beliefs which give cognitive mean­ ing to these value-orientations, again imperfectly to be sure. If ideological beliefs and value-patterns are, as assumed, interdependent, relative stability and con­ sistency of the belief system has the same order of functional significance as do stability and consistency of the value-orientation patterns. Hence, there must be a set of beliefs, subscription to which is in some sense an obligation of collectivity membership roles, where the cognitive conviction,of truth and "moral" conviction of rightness are merged. Ideology thus serves as one of the primary bases of the cognitive legitimation of patterns of value-orientation. Value-orientation patterns, it will be remembered, al­ ways constitute definitions of the situation in terms of directions of solution of action-dilemmas. It is not possible in a given situation to give primacy both to technical competence independent of particularistic solidarities, and to the particularistic solidarity, and so on through the list of dilemmas. So far as this is possible in empirically cognitive terms, an ideology "rationalizes" these value-selections, it gives reasons why one direction of choice rather than its alternative should be selected, why it is right and proper that this should be so.°^ And finally Parsons makes the point that if a value-system exists in a collectivity, an ideology exists. But within the deviant collectivity there is very definitely a value-system and hence an ideology. This ideology will always include a diagnosis of the basis for the break with the main society and its value system.^3 In summary, Parsons demonstrates, as do others, that the essential 6l Ibid., p. 351. 62 Ibid. 6 3 Ibid., p. 355 . prerequisite to defining social action (such as deviant collectivities) as evaluative behavior is that a well-defined belief system must be present, internalized, and accepted as the basis of action. As such, within the framework of value-belief theory as derived through the theory of knowledge, ideology, and social movements, the general hypotheses to be tested deal with the commitment to or agreement with differential cooperative-business beliefs on the part of cooperative leaders. This leads to a formulation of the general hypotheses of con­ cern in this thesis. General Hypotheses I. Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives can be viewed as a part of the cooperative social movement; this can be ascertained by the presence of a welldefined cooperative ideology and the concomitant commitment to that ideology on the part of a sig­ nificant proportion of selected leaders and members. II. Under certain circumstances, certain selected co­ operative leaders and members will be more highly committed to a business ideology than to a co­ operative ideology. III. If a high commitment to cooperative ideology is found, cooperatives can be analyzed as a social movement. 57 IV. If a high commitment to business ideology is found, cooperatives can be analyzed as business organiza­ tions. CHAPTER IV METHODOLOGY, PERTINENT VARIABLES, ANALYSIS OF DATA, TESTS OF HYPOTHESES AND FINDINGS In 1961-62 , 7 ;110,240 members belonged to 9*039 farmer cooperatives in the United States. Of this number, 3/206, or 35-5 percent of the total, were classified as farm supply cooperatives. Farm supply co­ operatives accounted for 3*634,690, or 53*1 percent, of the national membership for that period .1 The number of marketing cooperatives de­ creased from 6,519 in 1950-51 bo 5*626 in 1961-62 , a decline from 64.8 to 62.2 percent of all cooperatives in eleven years. Farm supply coop­ eratives showed a smaller decrease, from 3*283 to 3*206 , for the same period, or a percent of all cooperatives’ increase from 32.6 to 35*5 percent between 1950-51 and 1961-62 . While in actual numbers supply cooperatives nationally represent only a little over one-third of the cooperatives they accounted for over half the nation's membership. In general, over the twelve-year period, 1950-1962, it can be concluded that: 1. 2. Cooperatives decreased in numbers. Membership in marketing cooperatives declined slightly, from 4.1 million in 1950-51 to 3-4 million in 1961-62 . 3 . Farm supply cooperative units of operation decreased in numbers but increased in percent of all coopera­ tives from 32.6 to 35 •5 • ^A. L. Gessner, Farmer Cooperative Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, General Report, (April, 1964), pp. 2-8. 58 59 k. In terms of membership, farm supply cooperatives increased from 2.9 million in 1950-51 to 3*6 million in 1960-61 . 5. The most dramatic change, in the face of drastic reductions in the number and proportion of people engaged in farming, is the real and the percent increase in farm supply membership. Farm supply cooperatives accounted for ^-0.6 percent of the nation's membership in 195O -51 tut this had in­ creased to 51*1 percent in 1961-62 . In the period 1950-51* 10,06h farmer cooperatives did a gross business valued at 10.5 billion dollars with a net value (exclud­ ing inter-cooperative business) of 8.1 billion. In the 1961-62 period the number of farmer cooperatives decreased to 9*039 but in­ creased their gross business volume to 17.2 billion and the net to 13.0 billion dollars. Farm supply cooperatives accounted for 20.7 per­ cent, or 1.7 billion, of the net volume in 1950-51 * a slight decline to 19.7 percent, but increased in real income to 2.6 billion dollars by 1961-62.2 Michigan Cooperatives Data collected by the Farmer Cooperative Service show that for the years 1961-62 , a total of 225 cooperatives of all kinds did business in the state of Michigan. Of this number, 201 were principally located in Michigan and ninety-nine were exclusively farm supply cooperatives .3 2 Ibid., p. 8 . 3Ibid., p. 25 . 6o The total number of members in the 201 cooperatives doing business in the state of Michigan was 165,475* Of that number, 83,195 members were members of the ninety-nine exclusively farm supply cooperatives. In the year 1961-62 , all cooperatives in Michigan did a gross business of $481,57^,000 and a net business of $397*020,000. Those cooperatives dealing in farm supplies did a total gross business in farm supplies of 90.7 million dollars and a net of 64.5 million dollars. This does not necessarily mean that this volume of business is represented in the activities of the ninety-nine cooperatives classified as farm supply be­ cause cooperative business activities tend to be rather diversified; that is, the 90.7 million dollars of gross volume is represented in the business activity of all cooperatives dealing in farm supplies doing business in the state. tive enterprises.^ In 1961-62 , in Michigan this was 164 coopera­ The ninety-nine of concern in this thesis would be slightly less, but no data for this group alone are available. Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives are intrinsically bound up in the elevator business; that is, the function of purchasing cooperatives is to collectively purchase for and resell to its members grain, feed, seed, supplies, and fertilizer in order to minimize the cost of these materials which are needed to run the farm enterprise. The sum of the amount ex­ pended by farmers for these items Sorenson calls the Elevator Factors Total. The EFT is that amount of potential business which is and could be transacted by conventional grain elevators.5 Since the major busi­ ness activities of Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives is done in grain, 11Ibid., p. 2 5 . ^V. L. Sorenson, Elevator Outlook Committee Progress Report. Agri­ cultural Economics Department. (East Lansing, Mich.: Michigan State University), 1961. feed, seed, supplies, and fertil izer, they, by necessity, must operate for the most part as a grain elevator, and are in competition with grain elevators, and traditionally are organized much like elevators in Michigan. 6 . This indicates that the ninety-nine local cooperatives of interest in this study constitute only about 19 percent of the total elevator population in Michigan. Sorenson publishes no data on the total or individual business volume. He does allude to the fact that small, local elevators are on the decline and are being replaced by larger units necessary for profitable operations as a result of the cost-price squeeze experienced by farm enterprises in the early 1960 's. In summary, the situation of Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives in Michigan in 1961-62 was as follows: 1. Ninety-nine cooperatives operated in Michigan ex­ clusively as farm supply cooperatives. 2. These ninety-nine cooperatives had 83,195 members. 3. All cooperatives did a total gross business in farm supplies of 90.7 million dollars and a net 64.5 millions. 4. In 1956 (no data are available for 1961-62 ) there were 534 active licensed elevators in Michigan. Over 80 percent of all elevators are non-cooperative elevators. While cooperatives do, in whole or in part, touch the lives of a large number of farm people in Michigan, if it can be inferred that 6 Ibid., p. 59 . 62 the business volume of cooperatives is proportional to their in­ cidence in the elevator population, they do not command as large a segment of the farm supply economy as may be believed. Therefore, the universe of cooperatives of concern in this study is the ninety-nine farmers' Supply Cooperatives in Michigan. The Sample When the sampling decision for this study was made, certain com­ promises had to be considered to satisfy various requirements of the study, as well as to circumvent some subject enumeration problems. First, it was not possible to obtain a complete listing of cooperative members because of the confidential nature of membership lists; second, up-to-date lists of newly elected officers and board members were - sketchy and not reliable; and third, while a list of the ninety-nine Purchasing cooperatives was available, turnover among managers made such a list unreliable; therefore, it was decided that the sampling unit must be the cooperative itself. Of the ninety-nine operating Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives in 1961 a simple random sample of thirty was drawn. The precision of this sample of cooperatives applies also to the sample of managers, i.e., the manager of each of the co­ operatives drawn in the sample was interviewed. It was felt that it would be most likely that cooperative leader­ ship would be most committed to whatever values were prevalent in the cooperative; that is, it was felt that the major "ideology carrier" would be the professional managers and the farmers who were on the 63 cooperative boards. Due to time and financial limitations it was de­ cided that a large sample of board members could .not be .taken. It was decided that in addition to the cooperative manager one member of the board would be interviewed. The sampling technique used is as follows: each of the cooperatives in the random sample was contacted by telephone to establish its identity and to arrange for an interview with the manager. While these arrangements were being made, the identity of all board members was ascertained, as well as their telephone numbers and the location of their farms. After the interview appointment with the managers was made, one board member for each cooperative was randomly drawn to be contacted by telephone to arrange an interview appointment. A random substitution procedure was devised to replace the board member chosen if he were not available. To get some indication of the ideological position of farmer members, one farmer member was interviewed from each cooperative sampled. This member was chosen with the aid of the cooperative manager during the telephone conversation. Imaginary concentric circles were drawn around the cooperative location at one-half mile intervals out to ten miles (the average sphere of geographical influence held by a coopera­ tive). These circles were divided into north-east, east-south, south­ west, and west-north sectors. The sector north, east, south, west was drawn at random as was the concentric circle distance from the center point. The cooperative manager was then asked the name of the farmer nearest that point who was a member of the cooperative. A random and systematic technique for substitution was used if the sampling point were 64 confounded by geographical characteristics or if the farmer could not be located by telephone and could not be available for interview on the day the interviewer was in the area. This sampling technique produced the following results : TABLE I PERCENT OF POPULATION REPRESENTED BY THE SAMPLE Sample Universe: Michigan Farmers 1 Purchasing Cooperative Number in Population Managers Number in Sample Percent of Population 99 30 30.3 495* 30 6.1 (99) (8 ) (25 .0 ) Other Officers (198) (2 ) (4.0) Directors (198) (20 ) (71 .0 ) Board Members Presidents Farmer Members Total unknown 30 - 90 unknown - *Based on an average of five Board members per Cooperative Board. Table I shows the relative representativeness of the sample. The cooperative managers' sample is most representative (30 .3 %), the board members considerably less (6.1%), and the fanner members' sample representativeness unknown. For each of the thirty cooperatives in the sample, the manager, one member of the cooperative board, and one farmer member were per­ sonally interviewed. These interviews were conducted by trained inter­ viewers who traveled to the cooperative office for the manager interview. 65 The board and farmer members were interviewed at their farms. It took an average of one and a half hours to complete the manager interview and approximately one hour for the board member and three-quarters of an hour for the farm member. Of the ninety persons approached all cooperated and submitted to interview. The manager schedule was most extensive because of the need to gather information about the business operations of the cooperative. Likewise, considerable information was asked of both board and farmer members. Pertinent Variables ana Hypotheses As discussed in the theory chapters, it is assumed that there will exist on the part of cooperative leaders a differential degree of com­ mitment to cooperative and/ox- business ideology anu that these commit­ ments will vary according to or be dependent upon demographic, attitudinal, and social characteristics of individuals and/or the structure, size, and configuration of the social system (organization) in which they operate. In this regard then, the independent variable will be some measurement or measurements of cooperative and business ideology. The problems of developing reliable and valid indexes of ideology will be discussed in the Construction of Indexes follow. section of this chapter to A discussion of the significant dependent variables follows. Age: Table II shows the ages of managers, board members, and farmer members. Managers' ages range from 30 to 69 , with 62 percent in the dO -59 age group; board members range in ages from hO to over 70, with 5$ p e r ­ cent in the hO-59 bracket; while farmer members show a greater age range than managers and board members. Their age range is from 20 to over 70 years 66 with only 48 percent in the 40-59 age bracket. This shows, in gen­ eral, that board members are the oldest group, followed by managers, and that the farmer member group is slightly younger but from a greater age range. The difference in age between board members and farmer members is quite significant. Table III shows this difference. Farmer members are significantly younger than board members. TABLE II PERCENT OF MANAGERS, BOARD MEMBERS, AND FARMER MEMBERS BY AGE IN THE SAMPLE Age Grouping Managers 20-29 30-39 L0 -L-9 50-59 Board Members - 7 21 38 10 21 3 - 21 31 31 17 - 60-69 70 or over Fanner Members - 3A 24 28 14 TABLE III DIFFERENCE IN AGE BETWEEN BOARD MEMBER s AND FARMER MEMBERS IN THE SAMPLE Age Board Members Farmer Members -t-9 years and less 3b0 percent of the total business annually.* *See Verl R. W. Franz and A. 0. Haller, Big and Little Co-ops: Attitudes of People in Locally Owned Cooperatives Toward Mergers with Large Cooperatives, Final Report of Project of Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Michigan State Agricultural Experiment Station, East Lansing, Michigan, February, 1962, for a more complete treatment of these significant dependent variables and the-.r association with "willingness to merge" with larger cooperatives. 70 Independent Variables The independent variables of concern as deduced from theory can be viewed as dimensions of the general case of ideology. Operationally, according to Parsons, ideology can be characterized as: 1. A system of beliefs held in commoh by the members of a collectivity. 2. Beliefs held by members which are deviant from the main culture of the society. 5. A system of ideas (beliefs) oriented to the evalua­ tive integration of the collectivity to the collectively oriented goals and related to future events. Some level of evaluative belief as an aspect of member­ ship. 5. Subscription to a belief system on the part of members as an essential part of the institutionalized role. 6. An obligation on the part of the member to accept the beliefs (tenets) of the collectivity as the basis of action. 7. The members (actors) must accept involvement in the idea that the welfare of the collectivity hinges on the implementation of the belief system. 8. The actors (members) must feel that the welfare of the group is bound up with maintenance of the belief system and its implementations into action. Therefore, the following general and specific hypotheses derived from propositions are formulated and tested: 71 Proposition I; Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives can be viewed as a part of the cooperative social movement; that this can be ascertained by -Ihe presence of a well-defined cooperative ideology and that the concomitant commitment to that ideology on the part of a significant proportion of selected leaders and members is present. General Hypothesis A : A series of items can be constructed to represent a system of beliefs about cooperatives and that these items, when endorsed by members, are indicators of the latent variable of beliefs about co­ operatives; that each of these items is consistently related to the latent variable (i.e., these items will scale or trace) and that values on the latent continuum can be assigned to individuals or groups on the basis of the endorsement of particular items; i.e., individuals or groups can be given a score from low to high dependent upon their relative endorsement (commitment) to the beliefs repre­ sented by the items in the scale so endorsed. Operational Hypotheses B : It is hypothesized that within the overall cooperative ideology there exists the following subsets of variables or indexes: 1. The Competitive Yardstick Index: This is an index of the belief that cooperatives are a means to maximize profits and prices and minimize expenses and costs for the farm operator. 72 QX Item No. Matrix No. C-5 23 2k C-7 26 C-13 C -^2 36 2. Item Endorsed Response f Endorsed $ Endorsed If farmers didn't belong to a cooperative, they would not get a fair price for the things they produce. agree 53 58.8 Cooperatives help to keep down the number of middle­ men who make profits off farmers. agree 69 76.6 Cooperatives help keep down the price of things which the farmer must buy to run his farm. agree 78 86.6 Farmer cooperative members' first consideration should be in cutting out the middleman's profits on the things they must use. agree ^5 50.0 The Anti-Big Business Index; This is an index of the belief that the goals of capitalism as represented by modern large business or­ ganizations are not compatible with the goals of cooperatives. The co­ operative member consequently views his cooperative as a means to counteract the dominance over and the control of farmers by big business, QX Item No. C-3 C-31 Matrix Endorsed No._______________ Item______________ Response 22 32 f Endorsed $ Endorsed Without cooperatives a few big businesses would have too much control over farmers. agree 8l 90.0 In the long run coopera­ tives should become strong enough to have dominant control over business and agriculture. agree 23 25.6 73 QX Item No. Matrix No. c-54 33 3. Item Most farmers think private business can do the job better than cooperatives. The Pro-Business Index: Endorsed Response f Endorsed Endorsed disagree 45 84.4 This index measures the belief that a business-like operation is most consistent with cooperative goals and that cooperatives are effective only if they are run as a business. Consequently, as farmer-owned businesses cooperatives1 can best fit the needs of their1 owners. QX Item No. c-10 C-53 Matrix No. 25 39 4. Item It is only through co­ operatives that farmers can buy and sell in a business-like manner. Endorsed Response f Endorsed Endorsed disagree 26 28.8 ' 88 97-8 The only successful farmer cooperative is the one that is run primarily in a business­ like way. agree 1o Index of Cooperatives as a Source of Political Power: This index tends to measure the belief that cooperatives' economic position is dependent upon a solidified political power position and that the goals of cooperatives can be met and farmers' interests protected byusing them to promote their political views. QX Item Matrix Endorsed ________ Response No.______ No_.______________ Item______; C-lo 27 Cooperatives help the farmer to get the best deal he can out of federal government regulations. agree f Endorsed % Endorsed 63 70-0 lb QX Item No. Matrix No. c-23 29 c-62 b3 5- Item The Farm Bureau would be more effective if it stayed out of politics. People in cooperatives should use them to pro­ mote their political views. Endorsed Response f Endorsed Endorsed disagree 21 25-3 11 12.2 agree Index of Cooperative Idealism: This index tends to measure the the traditional beliefs about cooperatives. These items encompass be­ liefs about mutual help, cooperative idealism, open membership, the im­ portance of belonging, democratic participation and altruism. It measures the traditional mutual aid and mutual help values as expressed in the Rochdale principles. 'QX Item No. C-20 C-26 C-27 C-35 Matrix No. 28 30 31 3^ Item Endorsed Response i Endorsed Endorsed A cooperative is the united action of a group of people engaged in a similar enterprise to promote their mutual interests. agree 86 95-6 Cooperatives do more for large farmers than for small farmers. disagree 79 87.7 It is the successful farmer who patronizes the cooperative more than the farmer who is having a hard time. disagree 57 63 o agree kj 52.2 If a farmer really b e ­ lieves in individualism he would not belong to a cooperative. 75 QX Item No. Matrix No. C-37 35 C-^5 37 C-kd 38 C -56 c-59 C-bO 1+1 k2 Item The trouble with coopera­ tives today is that there are not enough idealists and liberals in the move­ ment. Endorsed Response f $ Endorsed Endorsed agree 31 3i+.4 Membership in coopera­ tives should be open to all farmers. agree 87 96.6 Being a member of a co­ operative is more im­ portant than buying products from the coopera­ tive for most farmers. agree 2k 26.6 There is more democratic participation in coopera­ tives now than there has been in the past. agree 59 65.5 To be a true cooperative land should be owned co­ operatively. agree .10 11.1 79 87.7 For most farm members, the cooperative is just a matter of dollars and cents. disagree Proposition II: Under certain circumstances a significant proportion of selected Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperative leaders and members will be more highly com­ mitted to the American Business Ideology than to the Cooperative Ideology. General Hypothesis A : If a high commitment to the American Business Ideology is found it would be theoretically and empirically more appropriate to analyze coopera­ tives within the framework of some theory of the firm. Operational Hypotheses B: It is hypothesized that within the general American Business Ideology there exists the following subsets of latent variables or indexes; 76 1. The Traditional Individualism Index: This is an index which measures the traditional values and beliefs that work and the job are in­ trinsically good, that the whole benefits if individuals are motivated by self interest and the will to do one's best. QX Item No. Matrix No. 1 B-l 2 B-b k B-l1*- lk B-41 2. Item Endorsed Response f Endorsed Endorsed Everyone wants to do a good job. agree 69 76.7 Every worker should do his best no matter whom he may hurt in the process. agree 59 65.5 The good of all will best be served if each indi­ vidual pursues his selfinterest with little interference. agree ^7 52.2 17 18.8 The team is more im­ portant than the in­ dividual* disagree The Index of the Centrality of the Free Enterprise System to the American Society: This index measures the beliefs that American business is the personification of the free: enterprise system. It is the central influence in economic social rewards and opportunity, and that American business and the free enterprise economy are responsible for America's greatness and success. QX Item No. B-ll E-28 Matrix No. 3 8 Item Business creates equality of opportunity and rewards. A heavy tax on business is bad for the country. f Endorsed Endorsed agree 83 90.0 agree 72 80.0 Endorsed Response 77 QX Item No. Matrix No. B-44 15 16 B -46 3. Endorsed Response Item f Endorsed Endorsed 1° American business is singly responsible for our high standard of living. agree 46 51.1 The reason America is great is because of its unique economic system. agree 85 d0.2 The Index of Individual Opportunity, Desire for Achievement, Success, and Upward Mobility: This index measures the belief that op- portunity to get ahead is present if one accepts the moral duty to want to get ahead, to work hard, and to succeed. If one ; accepts these tenets. is competent, and works hard, he will be rewarded with success and upward mobility • QX Item No. B-17 B-21 B-30 B-36 B -38 B-50 Matrix No. 5 6 9 11 12 17 Item Endorsed Response f Endorsed Endorsed 1o Everyone has equal oppor­ tunity to get ahead. agree 72 80.0 Everyone has the moral duty to try to make the most of himself. agree 87 96.7 The incompetent do not succeed very often in business. agree 83 90.2 Those who work and have ability will be rewarded with success. agree 79 85-5 The test of reward should be one's ability to con­ tribute to the productive purposes of the company. agree 86 95-6 If a man fails it is his own fault, and he should be ashamed of himself. agree 24 26.6 78 4. The Index of the Definition of the Rigors and Demands of Managerial Leadership: This index measures the belief in the moral re­ quirement necessary to be a business leader. It specifies that tension is normal, contentment is elusive, that a manager must be sober, punctual, and cheerful and that he must sacrifice his personal life for success, for there is no legitimate excuse for failure. QX Item No. B-24 B-40 B-52 B-55 B-6 l Item 7 13 18 19 21 Endorsed Response r' f Endorsed Endorsed A manager in business should have no excuse for failure. agree 35 38.8 The tensions of business are normal and should be accepted. agree 84 93-3 If workers are contented the supervisor is not doing his job. agree 7 2.2 A manager in business should have the virtues of sobriety, punctuality, discipline, avoidance of waste, and cheerfulness. agree 88 97.8 In business a manager should be willing to sacrifice all leisure and private life. agree 7 9.8 Proposition III: Under certain circumstances a significant proportion of selected Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperative leaders and members will ex­ hibit a general belief that cooperatives are alienated by choice and necessity from the main stream of the general economy and society.and 79 that these beliefs exhibit a feeling of powerlessness, normlessness, and social isolation from the society and economy. General Hypothesis A: If a high incidence of alienation is found it would be theoretical­ ly and empirically more appropriate to analyze cooperative members within the framework of alienation theory. Operational Hypotheses B: « It is hypothesized that within the general framework of coopera­ tive members' alienation there exist the following subsets of latent variables or indexes: 1. Index of Cooperative, Economic, and Occupational Normlessness: This index measures a lack of normative prescription in interpersonal relations between the role sets of manager, board member, and farmer member; that the job of cooperative leader as well as cooperation in general is not clarified, defined, or stable to the role incumbant or external actors with whom they must interact. QX Item No. N-2 Matrix Endorsed No._______________ Item______________ Response f Endorsed $> Endorsed Sometimes I feel that the Board tries to block everything I try to do. * Sometimes I feel that the manager tries to block everything we try to do.** Sometimes I feel that the board and manager try to block everything the mem­ bers want to do.*** agree 5 5-6 QX Item No. Matrix No. N-29 ^5 Item Endorsed Response °jo f Endorsed Endorsed agree 53 58-9 agree 14 15-6 When a number of sup­ pliers all present dif­ ferent technical specifications for their products I some­ times don't know what to buy. * When a number of sup­ pliers all present dif­ ferent technical specifications for their products, the board sometimes doesn't know what to buy.** When a number of sup­ pliers all present dif­ ferent technical specifications for their products farmers sometimes don't know what to buy.*** N-39 ^-6 $ Sometimes in this job, it gets so you can't trust anyone. * Sometimes in this job, as board member, it gets so you can't trust any­ one .** Sometimes in farming, it gets so you can't trust anyone.*** ^1-^+3 ^7 Sometimes I feel that this is a "dead end" job without a future. * Sometimes I feel that cooperatives are a "dead end" operation without a future.** 8i QX Item Matrix Endorsed No.______ No.______________ Item______________ Response Sometimes I feel that farming is a "dead end" operation without a future.*** N-^7 N-5^ ^8 ^9 Sometimes I really don't know what co­ operatives are trying to accomplish. f Endorsed $ Endorsed agree 12 13*3 agree 23 25.6 agree 37 4l.l Many times this job gets so confusing and demand­ ing that I wonder where I'm at. * Many times this job on the board gets so con­ fusing and demanding that I wonder where I'm a t .** Many times farming gets so confusing and demand­ ing that I wonder where I'm at.*** *Asked of Managers only. **Asked of Board Members only. ***Asked of Farmer Members only. 2. Index of Powerlessness Over Economic Transactions; This index measures the general feeling of powerlessness over the largeness of economic organizations, the complexity of the economy, the unpredict- aoility of fluctuations in supply, demand, and prices, and the helpless­ ness of cooperatives when they must do business with city people, large suppliers, and producers. 82 QX Item No. P -8 P-12 P-15 Matrix No. 50 51 52 Item P-49 53 54 Endorsed Endorsed I get the impression that big city people with whom we do business try to take unfair advantage of us* ** I get the impression that big city people with whom the cooperative does busi­ ness try to take advantage of it.*** agree 31 54.4 The present-day economy is so big and complex that local businesses like this cooperative don't have a place any more. agree 85 94.4 disagree 4l 45.6 When you deal with sup­ pliers would you say that you usually are in a position to deal on your terms. * When your cooperative deals with suppliers would you say that it usually is in a position to deal on its own terms. ** *** P-32 Endorsed Response The bigger a supplier gets the more we are at his mercy.* ** The bigger a supplier gets the more the farmer is at his mercy. *** agree 49 54.4 Sometimes it gets almost impossible to follow the fluctuations in supply, demand, and prices. agree 66 75.3 83 QX Item No. Matrix No. 55 P-51 P-58 56 3- Item In the long run a co­ operative manager doesn't have much to say about his operation. The big producers can pretty well control the supply and distribution of products. Endorsed Response f Endorsed Endorsed agree 9 10.0 agree 58 64.4 Index of Isolation from Social Interaction in the Community: This index measures the feeling of social deviance on the part of cooperative leaders. Items deal with the feeling of being rejected by the community, by friends, and by outsiders. One item is addressed to the feeling of isolation from non-cooperative job opportunities on the part of managers. QX Item No. Matrix No. s-4 57 S-9 S-l8 58 59 Item I participate in many community activities. I have very few really close friends in this community. Endorsed Response f Endorsed $ Endorsed disagree 27 30.0 agree. 14 15.6 agree 58 64.4 The job which would be the best promotion for me would be to become a branch manager for some larger company. * The job which would be the best promotion for a cooperative manager would be to become a branch manager for some larger company.** *** 8b QX Item No. Matrix No. S-19 60 Endorsed Response Item Most of the time the supplier representa­ tives who call on me d o n 't give a darn about me as a person; all they are after is a sale. * Most of the time the supplier representa­ tives who call on our cooperative don't give a darn about us as people; all they are after is a sale.** *** S-22 3-25 6l 62 f Endorsed Endorsed agree 22 2b.b I am not very well accepted in this com­ munity.** *** agree 7 7.8 I would like to live in most any other com­ munity than this one. agree 5 5.6 When my family and I moved to this community it took a long time b e ­ fore people accepted us. * Test of Hypotheses The test of the operational hypotheses (outlined above) can be accomplished by establishing some measure of internal consistency within the items which were thought to make up a series of subsets of variables within the general case of an ideology. That is, the hypothesis will ootain if after utilizing some technique of item analysis it can be es­ tablished that the items so hypothesized are reliable indicators of the latent variable of beliefs about specific aspects of cooperatives, 85 business, and society. To test this hypothesis the item analysis tech­ nique of Trace Line Analysis was used. Copp presents Trace Line Analysis as an extension of Lazarsfeld's con­ cept of latent structure. A trace line is a curve resulting when the per­ centages of subjects endorsing an item at different points on the latent variable continuum are plotted. In Trace Line Analysis the presumption is that the proportion of subjects endorsing an item will monotonically increase as the strength of the latent variable increases if the item is a consistent indicator of the latent variable. Thus, when items monotonically related to the latent continuum are combined in a scale,the number of items endorsed is taken as an indication of the subject's position on the latent variable continuum. This scheme of measurement is based on prob­ ability rather than on the summation of standard units of measurement. As the number of items in a scale increases, the precision with which a subject can be located on the latent continuum increases. scale is ordinal in nature.^ The resulting This method was used because it represents the most rigorous criterion for item analysis. Twenty-two items were anticipated to measure five subsets or underlying continuum of cooperative ideology. Cooperative Ideology Proposition I: Michigan Farmers ' Purchasing Cooperatives can be viewed as a part if' the cooperative social movement; that this can be ascertained by the 7 'James H. Copp, Trace Line Analysis, An Improved Method of Item Analysis (unpublished. Department of Rural Sociology, Pennsylvanis State University, February 9, 1959), PP» 19, 86 presence of a well defined cooperative ideology and that the concomitant commitment to that ideology on the part of a significant proportion of selected leaders and members is present. General Hypothesis A : A series of items can be constructed to represent a system of beliefs about cooperatives and that these items, when endorsed by members, are indicators of the latent variable of beliefs arout cooperatives; that each of these items is consistently related to the latent variable (i.e., these items will scale or trace) and that values on the latent continuum can be assigned to individuals or groups on the basis of the endorse­ ment uf particular items; that is, individuals or groups can be given a score from low to high dependent upon their relative endorsement (commitment) to the beliefs represented by the items in the scale so endorsed. Operational Hypotheses B ; It is hypothesized that within the overall cooperative ideology there exists the following subsets of variables or indexes: 1. The Competitive Yardstick Index consisting of items C-5, C-T? C-15, and C-42. 2. C-3^. (See Appendix B) The Anti-Big Business Index consisting of items C-3> C-31, and (See Appendix C) 3. The Pro-Business Index consisting of items C-10, C-35> and C-53* (See Appendix D) The Index of Cooperatives as a Source of Political Power con­ sisting of items C-l6 , C-23, and C-62. (See Appendix E) 87 5. The Index of Cooperative Idealism consisting of items C-20, C-2o, C-27, C-35, C-37, C-*+5» C-*4-8, C-5&, C-59, and C-60 (See Appendix F) All five subsets were subjected to Trace Line Analysis and were found not to trace. Therefore, Hypothesis I, B, 1-5 did not obtain. Based on this evidence and within the frame of reference of these items, no valid latent variables of beliefs about cooperatives were constructed. It was felt at this point that either no valid measure of cooperative ideology existed or that instead of the five sub-indexes the twenty-two o items may be measuring a general Popular Cooperative Ideology. When the items with low marginals (less than 10$ and more than 90$ endorsed; were discarded, the remainder were tested for the Popular Cooperative Ideology; they were found not to trace. It was then felt that some of the items may have traced in different fashions; namely, an Index of Orientation Toward Economic Democracy and Cooperatives made up of Items 55, 37, *t-8 , 56 , 50, 2o, and 27 may exist. (See Appendix F) analyzed, they were also found not to trace. After being Likewise,'what we thought may be an index of Favorability Toward Economic Goals of Cooperative, including items 13 , 3*4-, 7 , and 5 , was found not to trace, with the possible exception of item 13 . (See Appendix G) The.other index, which was called the Index of.Orientation Toward Economic Democracy, made up of items -26 , 27 , 56 , and 60 , was also found to be inadequate to meet the Trace Line Analysis criteria. (See Appendix H) American Business Ideology Nineteen items were anticipated to measure four subsets or underlying eontinua of American Business Ideology. Q The author is indebted to Professor Copp of Pennsylvania State University for his insight and encouragement in establishing this formulation. 88 Proposition II: Under certain circumstances a significant proportion of selected Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperative leaders and members will be more highly committed to the American Business Ideology than to the Coopera­ tive Ideology. General Hypothesis A ; If a high commitment to the American Business Ideology is found, it would be theoretically and empirically more appropriate to analyze co­ operatives within the framework of some theory of the firm: Operational Hypotheses B: It is hypothesized that within the general American Business Ideology there exist 1. four subsets of latent variables or indexes: The Traditional Individualism Index consisting of items B-l, 3-6, B-l4, and B-4l. 2. (See Appendix I) The Index of the Centrality of the Free Enterprise System to the American Society consisting of items B-ll, B-28, B-^4, and B -k6. (See Appendix j) 3. The Index of Individual Opportunity, Desire for Achievement, Success, and Upward Mobility consisting of items B-1T> B-21, B-30> B-3&, B-33, and B-50. J+. (See Appendix K) The Index of the Definition of the Rigors and Demands of Leadership consisting of items B-2^, B-^0, B-52, B-55> and B-6 l. (See Appendix L) Each of these subsets were item analyzed using the Trace Line Analysis. After the Trace Line Analysis had been completed for all of 89 the sub-indexes, it was found that none of the items traced satisfactorily. This led to the belief that there may be within all nineteen items a gen­ eral Free Enterprise Creed latent variable. . After rejecting all items whose marginals did not represent at least 10 percent or exceeded 90 percent endorsement there remained eight items. These included items 1, 6 . lb, 17, 2k, 28, 36, and bb, the Free Enterprise Creed A. Appendix M) lb, 17, A second trace line analysis was performed on items 1, 6 , 2k, 38, bb, and 50 and was (See Appendix N) 1. lb. 17, (See labeled Free Enterprise Creed B. The final Trace Line Analysis was computed on items 2k, and 50* (See Appendix 0) At this point it was felt tnat these items were tending to measure an Index of Individualism. It was found, however, that none of these items gave a true trace line and hence did not constitute a scale. With these findings in mind it was decided to subject all items to a less stringent mode of analysis; therefore, the traditional item analysis was used where one point was arbitrarily given for each item endorsed and each item was tested for its power to discriminate the highlow dichotomy of the array of total crude scores. of independence was employed. The Chi squared test From the business ideology items it was found that four items were discriminatory--items 1 , lb, 17, and 50 . They were all significant at the .01 level or greater. This index appeared to be measuring the underlying variable of Moralistic Individualism. Of the twenty-two cooperative ideology items analyzed with this method it was found that only three items discriminated on the high-low iichotoray of the array of crude scores and these were C-5> 0-7, and C-13* 90 It was felt that this index was measuring an underlying variable of Economic Control Over Costs and Prices and was not associated with any of the more idealistic elements of cooperative ideologies. In an effort to test this proposition further, the Index of Economic Control Over Costs and Prices was correlated with independent characteristics of the cooperative leaders. No significant relationships were found. Likewise, the business ideology index of Moralistic Individualism was correlated with other cooperative variables. No significant relationships were found. Proposition III; Under certain circumstances a significant proportion of selected Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperative leaders and members will exhibit a general belief that cooperatives are alienated by choice and necessity from the main stream of the general economy and society, that these beliefs exhibit a feeling of powerlessness, normlessness, and social isolation from the society and economy. Proposition III was used to generate the General Hypothesis III A and the Operational Hypothesis III B. General Hypothesis A ; If a high incidence of alienation is found it would be theoretically and empirically more appropriate to analyze cooperative members within the framework of alienation theory. Operational Hypotheses B: It is hypothesized that within members' alienation there exist indexes. the general framework of cooperative three subsets of latent variables or 91 1. Index of Cooperative, Economic, and Occupational Normlessness consisting of items N-2, N-29, N-39> N-^7} and N-5^* (See Appendix P) 2. Index of Powerlessness Over Economic Transactions consisting of items P-15> P-32, P-^9j and P-58 . (items P-8 , P-12, and P -51 were not included because of low and/or high marginals.) 3. See Appendices Q and R) Index of Isolation from Social Interaction in the Community consisting of items S-b, S-9, S-22, and S-25* (See Appendix S) These subsets were subjected to the Trace Line Analysis in various combinations. No valid latent trace lines could be ascertained. Therefore, it was concluded, based on these items, subsets, and instruments used, and using the Trace Line Analysis method to test the validity of these instruments, that the hypotheses that were generated from Propositions I, II, and III could not be upheld. As such it can be concluded that: 1. Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives cannot be viewed as a part of the cooperative social movement because a well defined coopera­ tive ideology is not present among a significant proportion of selected leaders and members. 2. A significant proportion of selected Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperative leaders and members are not committed to the American Business Ideology and that the analysis of cooperatives, within the framework of some rational theory of the firm, would be more theoretically and empirically appropriate. 3- A significant proportion of selected Michigan Farmers' Pur­ chasing Cooperative leaders and members do not exhibit a general belief 92 that cooperatives are alienated by choice and necessity from the main stream of the general economy and society and that beliefs of powerless­ ness, normlessness, and social isolation from the society and the economy do not exist significantly. In short, on the face of it, it appears that the complex formulation of hypotheses taken from the theories of social movements, ideology, sociology of knowledge, and values cannot be tested by these data. But scientific inquiry is not for the faint of heart. Assuming that the author understood the theory, contrived a reasonably valid in­ strument, and utilized reasonable precision and diligence in all aspects of the scientific process, the alternative question arises--what explana­ tion can be forwarded to account for results contrary to established theory? Reformulation of Hypotheses Through Factor Analysis Cattell pointed out that the scientific method deals with four kinds of order: (l) constant association of properties; (2 ) an invariable sequence; (3) numerical relations; and (4) relations among constructs, i.e., order among theoretical entities abstracted (inferred) from observed phenomena.9 He states that historically when scientists have attempted to establish one of the four types of order the law that had been ex­ pected to be found may have been stated before the observation of events in some cases, while in others the observations were made first and a law was sought to fit them later. He views the latter (i.e., the observa­ tion of orderly covariation) as an ideal compromise between the two, for 9 'Raymond B. Cattell, Factor Analysis: An Introduction and Manual for the Psychologist and Social Scientist. New York: Harper & Brothers, 1952 , p. 12. 93 then the observed covariation may lead to many possible hypotheses. 11^ Cattell presents factor analysis as a technique useful to the study of covariation as it occurs naturally. As such, when using factor analysis, it is not necessary, but it is sufficient to hypothesize that some structure lies in the observations and that the technique will demonstrate how certain variables can be viewed together because they behave, statistically, in the same way. That is, factor analysis helps to delineate new, independent, underlying factors which account for their grouping together.^ In this sense, Cattell's factor analysis can be regarded as "factor synthesis," or at least variable synthesis, for although it analyzes out the distinct factors at work among the variables, it also groups the variables together in ways which permit one to synthesize new entities. 12 These new entities considered as variables can be used as "hypothetical causes, intervening constructs, or independent influences."^ Since all of the hypotheses generated from theory about coopera­ tives, business, and cooperative alienation did not obtain, it seems logical to follow Cattell's advice that in their absence it is sufficient to hypothesize that some structure lies in the observations taken from farmer members and leaders in Michigan Purchasing Cooperatives. Formally then, a factor analysis of the sixty-two items of concern in this thesis could yield a delineation of the pertinent factors or variables within the item response universe. factored. iQpbid., p. 13- 11Ibid., pp. lh-15. 12Ibid., p. 15 . To this end the data were 9b The data were factored using the Michigan State University Computer Laboratory FANOD 1 Factor Analysis Program for the CDC 36OO. The output of this program includes eigenvalues, the Varimax factor loadings, the proportion of the total variable represented by each rotated factor, the "observed communality" of each test (the proportion of variance of each test accounted for by the factors), the means, standard deviations, and the correlation m a t r i x . ^ (For correlation matrix, see Appendix A) The Kiel-Wrigley criterion for number of factors to be rotated was not used. In view of the small N of 90, the trace line results, and the large number of variables (6 2 ), the number of factors to be rotated was arbitrarily fixed at t h r e e . ^ Following are the three principal factors evident after the Varimax rotation. If it is sufficient to hypothesize that some value structure lies in the observations (items responded to by Michigan Farmers Purchasing Cooperative members and leaders), the factors resulting from the Varimax solution could help to delineate new, independent, underlying variables. In short, if a new underlying structure of values is dis­ covered, new concepts can be formulated as hypothetical causes, inter­ vening constructs, or independent influences. Figure 1 shows the first factor which resulted from the Varimax rotation. The items in Factor 1 are reproduced showing their question­ naire and matrix identification (see Appendix A), as well as their factor loadings. Because of the large number of items in the matrix and because of the small percent of variance (6) accounted for by lb Michigan State University Computer Laboratory, MSC, East Lansing, Michigan, CISSR Program, Description 1, October 7> 1963* P* 1- See also Harry H. Harman, Modern Factor Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, i960 . 15Ibid., p. 3 . 95 Figure 1. Qx Item No. C-27 P- 8 C-31 C-62 C- 5 B-52 3-19 P- 32 Factor I (6/0 of Variance of 62 x 62 Matrix) Matrix No.________________ Item________________ 31 50 32 43 23 l8 60 53 Factor Loading It is the successful farmer who patronizes the coopera­ tive more than the farmer who is having a hard time. •55 I get the impression that big city people with whom we do business try to take unfair advantage of us. .^7 In the long run cooperatives should become strong enough to have dominant control over busi­ ness and agriculture. •^5 People in cooperatives should use them to promote their political views. •95 If farmers didn't belong to a cooperative, they would not get a fair price for the things they produce. •^3 If workers are contented the supervisor is not doing his job. •^3 Most of the time the supplier representatives who call on me d o n 't give a darn about me as a person; all they are after is a sale. .h2 The bigger a supplier gets the more we are at his mercy. .hi 96 each of the three factors only those items with a factor loading of .40 or greater were viewed as significant items in the factor. This also eliminated doublets except in the case of C-5 in Factors I and III and B-4l in Factors II and III. When the items in Factor I are examined it can be discerned that they represent such diverse values as type of farmers who patronize co­ operatives, anti-big-city-people impressions, cooperative dominance over business and agriculture, promotion of political views through coopera­ tives, membership to get fair prices, worker-supervisor relations, and fear of being controlled by large suppliers. As such it is difficult to conceptualize or identify a unified theme which runs through these items. It appears to be impossible to attach an identifying name to this cluster of items in any meaningful way. Therefore, Factor I does not seem to identify an underlying structure; i.e., there seems to be no logic as to why the subjects' responses to these items are interrelated. The items which occur in Factor II (see Figure 2) do not reflect gen­ erally a business value structure. They do reflect, at best, what could be called a moralistic achievement orientation. only But since Factor II accounts for 6$ of the variance of the matrix it is doubtful whether this factor represents an identifiable structure of values. Figure 3 shows that the items which goto make up Factor III, with the' exception of item B-4l, seem to be structuring values about the economic necessity of farmer cooperatives. The value expressed does not appear to be stronger or more complex than the need to belong to a trade association may be. It certainly does not appear to reflect a strong ideological base about cooperatives. 97 Figure 2. Qk Item No. B-38 B-17 B-21 Factor II (6 $ of Variance of 62 x 62 Matrix) Matrix Factor _______________ Item______________ •_______ Loading 12 5 6 The test of reward should he one's ability to contribute to the productive purposes of the company. .66 Everyone has equal opportunity to get ahead. .59 Everyone has the moral duty to try to make the most of himself. .4-5 B- 1 1 Everyone wants to do a good job. .43 £-41 14- The team is more important than the individual. .4-2 3-25 B-50 B-4-0 62 17 13 I would like to live in most any other community than this one. -.4-2 If a man fails, it is hi.s own fault, and he should be ashamed of himself. .4-1 The tensions of business are normal and should beaccepted. ■ .4-0 98 Figure 3- Factor III (6 $ of Variance of 62 x 62 Matrix) Qx Item No. C- 7 C- 3 C-54 0-13 C-26 C- 5 B 41 Matrix Fact o r No. __________________ Item____________________L o ading 24 22 33 26 30 23 14 Cooperatives help to keep down the number of middlemen who make profits off of farmers. .64 Without cooperatives a few big businesses would have too much control over farmers. .58 Most farmers think private business can do the job better than cooperatives. -.54 Cooperatives help keep down the price of things which the farmer must buy to run his farm. .50 Cooperatives do more for large farmers than for small farmers. -.48 If farmers didn't belong to a cooperative, they would not get a fair price for the things they produce. .45 The team is more important than the individual. .40 Figure 4 shows the items which have communalities (h^) greater than .31. These are the variables with the largett amount of variances shared with other variables. They are, therefore, the most reliable, valid, and discriminating items in the 62 x 62 matrix. except one occur in Factors II and III. primary Factor I. All of these items Only C-27 occurs in the 99 Figure k. Qx Item No. Matrix No._________________ Item___________________ B-17 B-38 B-^l B-50 C-3 C-5 C-7 C-13 C-26 C -27 Variables With Communalities (h^) Greater Than .30 5 12 Ik 17 22 23 2k 26 30 31 Everyone has equal opportunity to get ahead. The test of reward should be one's ability to contribute to the pro­ ductive purposes of the company. The team is more important than the individual If a nian fails, it is his own fault and he should be ashamed of himself. Factor II II III II Without cooperatives, a few big businesses would have too much control over fanners. III If farmers didn't belong to a co­ operative, they would not get a fair price for the things they produce. III Cooperatives help to keep down the number of middlemen who make profits off of farmers. III Cooperatives help keep down the prices of things which the farmer must buy to run his farm. III Cooperatives do more for large farmers than for small farmers. III It is the successful farmer who patronizes the cooperative more than the farmer who is having a hard time. I 100 In summary, therefore, the factor analysis of these data does not clearly demonstrate or delineate new, independent, underlying relation­ ships. As such, the factor structure does not permit one to assume that there is a factor snythesis which groups the variables together in ways which permit the postulation of new entities. In short, there are no new entities which can be considered as hypothetical causes, intervening constructs, or independent influences. In summary, it can be concluded that: 1. Traditional theory has not in this case provided adequate hypotheses to establish contemporary Michigan Purchasing Cooperatives as a defineable social movement because no discernible and/or significant cooperative ideology exists. 2. No discernible and/or significant business ideology can be found; consequently, it would be difficult to conclude that Michigan Purchasing Cooperatives are typically business-like. 3. Finally, as the factorial study shows, there ip no evidence to indicate than, based on sixty-two value items, there exists an un­ anticipated underlying value structure held by members and leaders of contemporary Michigan Purchasing Cooperatives. In conclusion, therefore, pretations are possible. it can be stated that the following inter­ Using contemporary Michigan Purchasing Coopera­ tives as a case in point: 1. It is likely that American Farmers' Cooperatives are not in fact true cooperatives because a discernible, significant ideology does not exist. 101 3. Cooperatives need not be studied any differently than any other social-economic social system. k. It would probably be more fruitful to study farmer organiza­ tions apart and separate from farmer cooperatives. 5. Historically, sociologists, psychologists, economists, and historians have written about and interpreted Farmers' Cooperatives within the framework of social movement theory. One characteristic that identifies a social phenomenon as a social movement is its well-defined cooperative ideology. The results of this study indicate that it is difficult, if not impossible, to establish the fact that a well-defined cooperative ideology exists among selected leaders of the Michigan Farmers Purchasing Cooperative. Therefore, using the social movement model to study Farmers' Cooperatives is at best tentative and specula­ tive. (Note: A score was computed for each respondent in terms of each of the three factors involved (see Factor I, page 95; Factor'll, page 97; and Factor III, page 98)- The scores were cross tabulated with a sequence of variables such as age, father's occupation, education, length of time with present cooperative, size, sales, profit of cooperative, attitude toward manager's job, choice of type of supplier, composition of the board, attitude toward merger, size and type of farm, brand of products used, and favorable attitude toward own cooperative. The three factors constituted the independent variables for the purpose of this study (see page 65 ). ships. The Chi squared test of association was used to test relation­ In all cases, the values did not approach a reasonable degree of significance to warrant a non-chance interpretation. CHAPTER V SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS Historically, cooperatives have been regarded as a grass-roots movement to rectify the wrongs suffered by consumers and/or industrial workers by an "evil" capitalistic system. As such the cooperative movement in its early stages was a response to the results of indus­ trialization and urbanization. Cooperatives which developed in the rural sector of western culture were a response to the serf-like status of the agrarian, in relation to the emerging industrial worker. In any event cooperatives had their origin in Europe, especially in England, as a response to the abuses of capitalism and its factory system. These abuses included sweatshop working conditions, uprooting, dismal under­ payment for labor and child-labor practices. The fundamental ideology, if one existed, was built around the value system which said that man need not be the victim of the economic system which abused employees as a material aspect of the means of production. The hope was that man could, through cooperative, peace­ ful, and evolutionary processes, become part owner in the mode of production, and develop an economic system which guaranteed managerial democracy, broad-based equalitarian ownership, and utopian distribution of the fruits of his labor. This last element of the ideology, "utopia now," seems to have had the greatest appeal for the followers of "co­ operative movements." Utopianism was indeed the underpinning of the historical approach to the cooperatives and the "Cooperative Movement." As the migration of industrial workers followed East-to*-V/est, 102 and as European and British people began to migrate to Canada and the United States the cooperative idea naturally migrated with them, and diffused. an example, the As Robert Owen Utopian Communities of 1799 in England and the Charles Fourier Community of 18A 3 became the Rappite Community in New Harmony, Indiana, the Northern American Phalanx in Red Bank, New Jersey, and the Brook Farm Society in New England. Out of the utopian community ideal there tended to develop the fundamentally anti-capitalism and pro-Fabian socialistic school of thought. Except for isolated farmers cooperatives, such as the Connecticut River Valley Farmers Marketing Cooperative in 180A and the first associated dairy cooperative in New York in 1851, the cooperative movement idea remained primarily one of anti-capitalism, especially in Canada. This fact is demonstrated in the cooperative commonwealth school in Canada which persists even today in the Province of Saskatchewan and remains relatively influential. The diffusion of the cooperative idea, then, came'from Europe via the utopian community tradition, through Canada, and ultimately diffused to the United States. With the exception of farmers' marketing and producer associations, the primary interest of the cooperative idea in the United States became rural. Historically, the rurality of the cooperative ideal seemed to have been powerful enough to influence most rural sociologists' treatment of farmers' cooperatives. One gets the impression that rural sociologists tend to neglect the historical diffusion of the cooperative idea and view it almost completely as a North American phenomenon. At best, the history of thought about farmers' cooperatives in the United States switched from an anti-capitalism point of view to one of 104 economic self-dependence for farmers caught in the price-squeeze which exaggerated the difference between what they needed to run their farm enterprise and the price they got for their produce. The reality of this situation seems to be greatly neglected by most sociologists. Until the early twenties the farm enterprise in the United States was very much a subsistence-type enterprise; consequently, the marketing cooperative became an effort on the part of farmers to create a countermonopoly against the wholesaler and the retailer. The efforts of farmers' cooperatives were toward the: competitive yardstick ideal. This school of thought attempted to keep the capitalist honest and was in reality an effort to monopolize, or at least to control, the production of food stuff which would guarantee fair prices for their produce. To demonstrate the legitimacy of the farmers cooperative activities after 1952 the New Deal made as a part of its total program the encouragement of farmers' cooperatives of all types and in a sense legalized and legitimized the cooperative enterprise. At best, farmers' cooperatives then became a New Deal type business operation. It was not until after World War II that the Farm Bureau became ex­ tremely anti-New Deal, anti-government, and pro-capitalistic. At present, the sympathies and/or "ideologies" of modern farmers' coopera­ tives are more in accord with the business, capitalism, and free enter­ prise philosophies and less with the traditional anti-capitalism ideals which generated the Rochdale principles. In summary, based on a search of the historical and sociological literature on farmers' cooperatives, we can conclude that it is not sur­ prising that we should be concerned about the theoretical frame-of 105 reference used in studies of modern cooperatives. Also it is not sur­ prising that we should be concerned with the legitimacy of approaching the study of modern cooperatives from a social movement point of view. In the scientific community, it is not enough to say that what scholars in the past have done does not seem reasonable. Instead it behooves the social scientist tc test these hypotheses in the arena of the empirical phenonenon. To do this, we must first be aware of what has gone before and how our intellectual forefathers came to believe as they did. In the course of this study it became necessary to approach the problem from where it had been approached by many of the giants in the field. This obviously leads to the study of social movement theory, and since in this thesis we were concerned primarily with testing the proposition that we can study farmers' purchasing cooperatives as a social movement we needed to isolate social movements definitionally. '.•/hen reviewing the literature it became obvious that one of the common « prerequisites for classifying a phenomenon as a social movement was the presence of a well-defined ideology. Since it is very difficult, if not impossible, to operationalize the concept of ideology, it was necessary to look to the theory of ideology for possible guidance to operationalization of that concept. In reviewing the literature on ideology it soon became apparent that much of it dealt with the notion of how man comes to know his environ­ ment. Obviously this required that the literature on the sociology of knowledge be perused in order to deal with the problem of knowing and believing as a function of an ideological base. This phase might be called the sociology of the knowledge of ideologies, i.e., how do 106 collectivities tend to know, embrace, and believe certain things about the relationship between themselves and the external world. King, Parsons, and others have helped to make this transposition from the knowledge and ideology theoretical sphere to one of values and/or be­ liefs. Consequently, it was felt that it was legitimate to assess the ab­ sence or presence of a cooperative ideology based on the operationaliza­ tion of empirical items which would tend to measure the values which participants place on various aspects and ideas in relationship to membership in the cooperative society as well as in society in general. Data were gathered on a sample of managers, board members, and members of Michigan Purchasing Cooperatives who were asked to respond to a variety of statements hypothesized to measure relative commitment to the ideologies and/or values and beliefs represented by these em­ pirical items. As was pointed out and presented in Chapter IV, keeping in mind the limitations of the sixty-two items, the limitations of the sample, and the limitations of a variety of statistical techniques used to analyze the data, the following conclusions were made. (1) As far as we know there does not seem to exist at this time among the leaders and members of Michigan Pur­ chasing Cooperatives a well-defined ideology about cooperatives as a social movement or as a discreet belief pattern which would differentiate farmers' purchasing cooperatives from any other k:ind of socio-economic enterprise. (2) As far as we know, based on this study, we cannot state that leaders of Michigan Farmers' Purchasing Cooperatives hold a strong belief in what has been con­ sidered by sociologists and business researchers to be a strong traditional business belief system. (3) As far as we know, based on this study, we cannot say that the leaders of Michigan Purchasing Co­ operatives have any degree of isolation and dis­ sonance which would separate them from the general population. That they do not feel any more isolated or alienated from the society as a whole than other members of the population of comparable nature. (4) Based on our study, we can conclude that the theory of social movements does not seem to be an adequate and/or appropriate frame of reference for the study of purchasing cooperatives, especially in Michigan, and that we might infer that it is an inappropriate frame of reference for the study of modern co­ operatives in the United States. In short, it is doubtful that cooperatives do exist generally in the United States which resemble in any degree the traditional anti-capitalistic, anti-industrial, proutopian tradition. (5) Our evidence seems to indicate that it might be a fallacy on the part of sociologists to pursue this line of research, especially if they persist in treating farmers' cooperatives theoretically in the 108 same light as they treat farmers' movements. If we were to assume, as do most modern sociologists, that farmers' cooperatives and farmers' movements are one and the same, we could then infer, based on this research, that farmers' movements also could not be fruitfully researched from a social move­ ment point of view. On the whole, we can assume that farmers' cooperatives as a social movement either did not exist throughout the historical development, which is not demonstrable empirically, or that if they did exist as a social movement, they have now entered a new sphere of ideological commitment which could not be identified in this study. If these points are legitimate, it is possible that if farmers' cooperatives were ever a social movement they have passed on into an institutionalized state and have in fact, from a value point of view, blended somewhere between the self-help principles of traditional cooperation and the social service values of modern business beliefs. APPENDIXES A p pend ix A . Question­ n a i r e I t em Matrix No. No. B- 1 B- 6 B -11 B -14 B-17 B-21 B -24 B-28 B -30 B-33 B -36 B -38 B -40 B-41 B -44 B -46 B-50 B-52 B -55 B-57 B-fil C- 3 C- 5 C- 7 C -18 C-13 C -!fi 0 -21 ) 0-23 0-28 0 -27 C -31 0-34 0-35 0-37 0-42 0-4 5 0-48 0-53 0-58 0 -58 C-fiO 0-82 N- 2 N -20 N-30 N -43 N -47 \ -54 1>- 8 1 1 1.0000 2 .0979 .0361 .2613 .4227 .0442 .1706 -.1445 .0361 .0725 .1954 .2637 -.0420 .2706 -.0139 .1341 .1547 .0620 .0949 -.0442 .0620 .0791 -.0339 -.0558 .0040 -.0770 -.0743 .0088 -.1301 -.1950 .0706 .1427 -.0531 .0545 .1904 .0789 -.1025 .09.53 .0949 .0295 .1116 -.1474 .2060 .0189 .0197 .0920 -. 1698 -.0379 - . 1135 .0683 . 1335 .0826 . 1284 .1426 -.0787 .1264 -.1113 -.0720 . 1472 .0359 -.0361 -.0955 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 5-10 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 4!) 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 8-22 6 1 S -25 62 l' - 1 2 H -15 l ‘ -32 [‘-40 I‘-51 l'-5H S- I S- * 8 - 1 it 2 C o r r e l a t i o n m a t r i x fo r th e 62 s e l e c t e d i t e m s 3 4 5 7 6 9 8 10 1.0000 .0518 .0089 .3127 .1263 .0987 -.1283 .0518 .2344 -.0563 .0704 .1815 .2477 .1799 -. 0355 .2257 .1233 .0496 .0047 .1233 .0702 .0598 .0979 .0496 -.0316 -.0663 .1839 .0683 -.0151 .1487 .2104 -.0758 .0847 .1477 .0703 -.0039 .1728 .0496 .1945 .2565 -.0686 .1276 .0734 .1073 .2466 -. 1968 -.0040 . 0516 .0827 . 1757 .0529 .0413 .1975 .0856 -.0354 . 1323 . 0320 . 1632 . 0671 . 0360 -.0488 1 .0000 -.0287 .2563 -.0540 .0617 -.0413 .2254 -.0010 .1450 .3401 .4217 .1781 .2140 -.0842 .0817 .0843 -.0433 .0540 -.0706 .0418 .0104 .1341 .0935 -.0010 .1718 -.0630 -.0361 -.2717 .0372 .0752 .0101 .1945 .0421 .2074 -.0540 -.0121 -.0433 .2178 .1026 -.0222 .1085 -. 1109 .0947 .0101 -.0077 . 0752 -.0037 .0360 - . 1109 -.06 75 - . 1823 .0129 -.1800 .1790 .2346 .0016 -.0374 -.0121 .0843 .0433 1.0000 .3229 .0705 -.0127 .0221 -.1948 .0499 -.0173 .2254 .0120 -.0637 .1771 .2203 .1745 .1116 .1574 .0538 .1947 .0517 -.0305 -.0542 .1189 .0499 .0533 -.0985 .0543 -.1186 .0048 .1524 .0423 .0242 .106 3 .2891 .1944 .0236 -.1441 -.0133 .0550 .0862 -.0507 .0376 .1051 .1037 -.0829 . 0504 -.0831 .2722 .0376 .2497 - . 0264 .1778 .0964 -.0305 - . 2515 -.1130 .1739 . 1242 -.2207 -.0071 10) 1.0000 .0554 .1336 -.1225 -.1502 .2521 .3057 .2849 .1892 .2373 .1478 .0530 .1889 .0483 .1065 -.0558 .0483 -.0818 .0105 .0364 .1497 -.1351 -.04 16 -.1118 -.1)362 -. i397 .0889 .1161 -.0031 .1678 .1568 .1907 .0554 .1273 -.0781 .0139 .0961 -.0472 .1098 .0065 .2873 .0720 -.2774 -.0713 . 0 0 14 . 2032 . 12 53 . 2000 0736 .1190 .08 15 .0105 .0963 - . 0 196 .1113 .0042 -.0533 -.1071 . 1.0000 .0213 -.0927 -.0540 .0997 -.0696 -.0396 .1978 -.0891 -.1817 .1772 .1123 .0540 -.0277 .0341 .0540 -.0612 .0961 .0442 -.0184 -. 0764 1217 .26 09 -. 0438 .06!)1 .006 3 -.0331 .0802 -.0701 .1382 .06 1 6 -. 0351 .1123 -.0277 .1208 -.1310 -.0498 .0691 .04 4.7 -.0297 .0802 - . 1091 -.033 1 - . u"l 9 .0043 . 0445 . 1701 - . 1697 -.1119 -.1446 -. 1555 .0 0 0 0 .076 4 .1415 . 1123 .0540 .0266 1 0000 - 0568 1468 1334 2280 1720 1217 1.0000 .0624 -.2053 -.0170 -.1078 -.0220 .0427 1419 - . 1 0 0 1 0617 .0624 3952 .1132 1941 .0416 1205 .1133 0213 .0931 0238 -.0621 1139 .1111 2960 .0902 0448 .1838 0449 .1963 061 1 .1897 0746 -.0243 .0270 0492 0990 -.0525 0889 .1018 1918 .2 0 0 1 0551 .1 0 2 0 1535 -.09 18 2407 .0333 16 95 -.0346 1139 .0554 1483 -.0927 0687 .1 132 i)339 -.0750 1164 -.0229 2255 -. 1767 .0890 0610 0889 .1018 0055 .1212 .1467 0746 0 *' 1 8 1608 17 88 . 1145 2642 - . 11890 . 0340 082 ! .01 19 0984 2101 - - - - - - - - 1049 11026 1804 1205 1137 2033 1291 0036 0551 1375 0238 - 1198 1170 - 1082 0630 0891 2841 0349 0842 1755 0843 0433 0540 0843 1800 0947 1341 0010 17 18 - 0630 0620 - 0181 0372 - 0199 0101 2776 1288 04 15 - 0540 . 012! 5190 1311 1026 144 1 108 5 07o 1 01 04 124 5 1143 0752 o»o3 - 1005 . 2676 .0 126 0 158 .141.7 -. 176 5 .04 75 .0347 .1132 .0416 .07 56 1362 0645 1434 2056 - 0226 1170 1048 1193 1524 0997 1193 03 15 0222 - - - - - 0725 0529 1689 13 11 06 45 0027 1535 0265 0957 0850 1401 1072 03 18 0764 038 1 ]524 02.40 1453 0592 - 0 31'4 O"o;-i - 0222 171.7 - 02 4 5 - o 3 2 ’’ 0 2 '',:', 0 3 18 13 86 0701 -.1112 1 0000 0020 - 1 2 12 . - . 1 0000 i i - ' i ' i 'I 13 1 8 o l 58 01. 8 5 1747 1800 ■M04 0332 1 372 - - (12 1* 2 1 1“ 6 - - 0374 - - 0121 0843. (1433 2 14 ■ 11440 - 0 1 1II. ol5 3 03.34 oilI3 152 1 110 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 1.0000 2 4 ' *2 1.0000 ■1997 .3748 .1718 .2205 -.0630 .1303 -. 1389 .3324 -.2600 .0625 -.0716 -.0707 -.1187 .0186 -.0889 .0944 -.0467 .1191 -.2487 -.0620 .0027 .0928 .0981 .0477 .2160 .2609 .0084 -.0331 .0656 .0759 -.2016 -.084 1 .0524 -.0707 .0928 -.0736 3401 1771! 1 470 1483 1082 1737 1104 0184 0115 3776 27 56 0882 1362 1260 0800 0456 0680 123 1 2180 1205 1531 0646 0341 0606 0716 0562 2101 0842 077 1 0356 0577 0320 06 66 1526 0143 0243 0563 0577 2050 13 54 0716 1246 1010 0060 15 32 0025 0820 0184 17 30 1.0000 .0991 .1841 .0891 .1613 -.0891 -.0406 .0491 .0772 .0591 -.0423 .06 34 -.0262 -. 1 1 0 0 .0198 -.0576 -.0628 -.3086 .0093 .0547 .1151 .0772 .1984 -.0002 .1987 -.0401 -.0406 .0808 .0942 .0179 -.0366 .0646 .1388 -.0078 -. 1573 . 1263 -.0477 .07 53 .0483 . 0427 .0064 .0524 .0646 -.0193 -.0236 .0190 -.2447 -.0080 -.1610 .071 1 -.0592 -.0707 -.0423 .0763 .0950 -.0640 -.1434 .0526 .1110 .0084 -.0401 .0625 .0772 -.3338 .0407 1.0000 -.0176 .0722 .1627 .1401 .1194 -.0691 .0341 .1232 .0008 .2035 .1199 .0441 -.0060 .0341 .1320 -.0800 .0745 .1526 -.2628 .2343 .2401 -.0284 -.0891 -.0298 .1194 .1161 .0801 -.1669 .0067 .1167 .2315 .1288 -.1442 -.0425 -.0473 -.0084 .1167 -. 1285 .1287 -.0985 -.12 32 .0008 .0203 .0368 .0139 -.1581 .1401 -.3123 1.0000 .0481 .2883 .0351 .0029 -.0664 -.0479 -.0299 .0862 .0387 .0839 -.0226 .0388 -. 1034 .0665 -.1102 .0631 .2672 .1132 .1343 .0298 .3113 .0660 .0873 .0029 .0629 .0628 .0652 -.0423 -.2484 -.1396 .0519 -.0740 .1653 .0261 .1478 .0429 .2251 -.0020 .1140 .1038 .1314 .0631 -. 1040 .0984 .0370 -.0479 -.1542 1.0000 .0817 .0843 -.0433 .0540 -.0706 .1800 .1790 .1341 .1850 .2350 -.0092 .1388 .0620 -.1447 .1179 .1703 -. 1043 .1115 .1288 .0415 -.0 540 .0817 -.0433 .1311 .1026 -. 1053 -.0181 -.1109 -.0739 .0101 -.1300 -. 1149 -.0037 .0360 .0701 .0158 .01 58 .0129 -. 1800 .0104 -.1172 .0016 .0487 -.'>121 -.2255 .0433 1.0000 .2943 .0912 .1677 .2943 .1175 .1463 .0359 .0591 -.0381 .0110 .1303 .0238 -.0716 .0094 .1652 -.0504 .1779 .1821 .3520 .1123 .1478 .0912 .0806 .0268 .0101 .1587 -.1464 .0952 .0881 -.0887 .0500 .0950 .0389 ..0729 .2555 .0976 .0229 -.0334 .1463 .0534 .1099 .0627 .2046 .0126 -.0914 1.0000 .0433 .1772 -.0851 .0969 .1585 .0620 -.0933 .0013 .0092 .0625 -.0622 .1448 .2051 .2103 -.1245 .2204 .3043 .0413 -. 1772 .1065 .0433 .0426 .0294 .1051 .1448 -.0701 .0741 .2188 -.1140 .1152 .0877 .2262 .1109 .1506 .0156 .1753 -.0973 .1585 -.0587 .1170 -.1348 .1065 -.0851 -.0441 1 .0000 -.3909 .0433 -.0510 -.1257 -.0832 -.0703 -.06 18 -.0989 -.0331 .0831 .0569 -.0435 .0882 .0651 -.0066 -.0454 .1506 -.0277 .0912 -.0224 -. 1.119 .0533 .0104 .0569 .0361 .0273 .06 51 .0596 .0882 -.0235 -.0496 .0361 -.0137 .1645 .0795 .0497 .0273 - 1058 .06 18 -.0421 .0912 .04 33 -.4888 1.0000 -.0540 .0618 .0290 .1 0 2 1 -. 1 186 .0764 .12 17 .0404 -.1021 -.0696 .1138 .1755 -.0793 -.0535 .2501 .0619 .0341 .0277 ■ .0288 .1379 -.0660 -.0750 .3090 -.0445 .1549 -.0793 -.0725 .0331 .0919 .1260 -.0445 .0789 -.07 89 -.0277 -.0618 .1.549 .13 13 -.0764 .1154 .1677 -.0540 .3926 1.0000 .0969 -.0104 -.0361 -.0018 -.1167 -.0813 .0625 .0358 .01 77 -.0370 -. 1704 -.1245 -.0287 -.0426 -.0417 .0540 -.0812 .0433 .0426 .1614 .0219 .1448 -.0701 -.0947 -.0101 -.1140 -.0750 .0037 .0516 .1109 .0673 -.2344 -.1064 -.0973 -. 1791 -. .1587 -.OHIO -. 1348 .2005 -.0851 -.0441 1.0000 .3990 .3418 .2126 .3901 .0244 -.0716 .0089 -.2149 .2278 .1105 -.4698 .0963 .09 31 .1113 -.06 12 -.049!) .2007 .0618 -.1182 -. 1633 .0112 .0804 -.0527 .0413 .0218 -.3139 -.0900 .1638 .0804 -.0668 .0670 .1339 -.1363 -.1280 .0788 .1371 -. 0540 .0338 -.0414 .0504 Ill Appendix A . C o r r e l a t io n m a t r i x for the 62 s e l e c t e d i t e m s (contd. ) Question­ naire Matrix No. Item No. c:- 5 C- 7 C-IO C-13 C -16 C -20 C-23 C -26 C -27 C-31 C-34 C -35 C -37 C -42 C -45 C -48 C-53 C -56 C -5!) C'-61) C -62 N- 2 N 29 M -66 N -43 \ -47 N 54 1'- H P -12 P 1.5 P -32 P-46 P -51 P-58 S-4 s- u S -1!! S -P> S -22 S -25 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 1 .0000 .3933 .2834 .2989 .1923 .0388 -.0195 -.0331 .3515 .1790 -.1398 .1663 .1959 .1580 -.0297 -.0069 .1804 .1815 -.1358 .0332 -.0331 .0054 -.1475 -.0775 -.0710 -.0799 -.0630 .2729 -.0931 .0841 .1878 .0579 .1280 .0362 .2714 .1508 -.0672 .0952 -.0947 .1259 1.0000 .1780 .3715 .0976 .0088 -. 1301 -.2752 .2431 .1427 -. 1980 .1070 .2452 .2365 -.1025 .0359 .2734 .3039 -.0556 -.0421 .0456 .0189 .0730 .0193 .0620 -.2789 -.0072 .1789 -.0957 -.0229 .1284 -.0950 .0089 .0730 .2231 .1521 .1472 .0953 .0620 .’0833 1.0000 .1923 -.1175 .1376 -.0618 -.0132 .2798 .1324 -.0706 .0775 -.0124 : .2452 -.1550 .0591 .0959 -.0384 -.0692 .0066 .1365 -.0479 .0842 -.1382 -.0335 -.1487 -.1973 .2604 -.0479 .0077 .1893 .1073 .1964 -.0155 .0868 .0172 -.1287 .1699 -.0933 .0699 1.0000 .2139 -.0889 .0027 -.2325 .0966 .1682 -.3465 .0136 -.0910 .0946 .0997 .0334 .1524 .0910 .0448 .0592 .0570 -.0387 -.1507 .0024 .0684 -.1940 .03 13 .1648 -.3145 -.0683 .1320 -.0332 -.0738 .1062 .1 1 2 0 .0793 .1 160 -.0381 -.2348 .0625 1.0000 -.1409 .0175 -.1260 .0703 -.0055 -. 1199 .0439 .1319 .1697 .2839 -.1534 .0655 .1217 .0 0 0 0 .0682 .0 2 2 0 1587 -.0047 .0 8 0 6 -.0284 -.1166 .06 89 .01 56 .0526 .06 32 .0341 -.0110 -.0242 .1923 .1544 -.2136 .1460 -.0986 -.0813 .0990 1.0000 -.0084 1 . 0 0 0 0 .1150 1 . 0 0 0 0 .0805 .0429 -.0194 .1407 -.2445 -.0822 -.0628 .0.928 .2141 .1260 -.2256 .0510 -.0173 .0477 .0294 -.1355 .0003 -.0261 -.1700 -.0396 .1025 -.3090 .0084 .0832 .0051 -.0331 .0831 -.1737 -.0473 -.0839 .0648 -.0957 .1396 -.1322 -.0935 .0421 .0771 .0805 -.1256 .2751 .0524 .2058 .2104 -.1803 -.1262 -.0331 -.0564 .0535 -.0666 -.07 36 .0 155 -.0463 .0927 -. 1209 .2792 -. 1430 .2731 .0243 .0427 -.1787 .0149 .0524 .0957 .0578 -.1276 -. 0301) .0674 .01 90 .0826 .1370 .I139 .2139 ■ .1485 .07 11 .1667 .1016 -.0707 -.0729 -. 1 0 2 1 .0763 .0557 -.0960 -.0640 .1473 .0398 .1799 -.0729 .0526 .1303 .0238 .0051 .0625 -. 1603 -.1089 .0322 -.0828 -.0569 1.0000 .2439 -. 1962 .2118 .1695 .0784 -.1142 .1255 .1030 .2540 .0334 -.0104 .2726 -.0713 -.0274 .0049 -.1406 -.0039 .1159 .2779 .1174 .0094 .1640 .1375 .2045 .0440 -.0209 -.0964 -.0883 .2233 -.1985 .1906 1.0000 -. 1 108 .2556 .0970 .0764 -.0331 .2228 .0882 .1 160 -.0452 -.0648 .0927 -.0308 -.0282 .1 0 0 0 -.1548 .0072 .0664 .1652 -.0308 .1 8 0 2 .1266 .1229 .1441 .17 90 .0362 -. 1681 .1 8 8 6 -.0076 -.1704 .0850 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 1 . (11)1)0 -.1036 -.1264 .0002 -.0006 .1574 -.1427 -.0652 •■9541 .2174 .0270 •9301 •(,77'> ••9992 •1925 .1792 •9058 "■18 18 •9301 .2231 ■0233 •9185 .1636 •ll47> .1987 -•0019 ■1188 .0188 -.0101 •1440 1.0000 .1725 1.0000 .0667 .1856 1.0000 -.1941 .0085 .0616 1.0000 .0269 .0771 .1006 -.0277 .1445 .1119 .1506 -.0277 .1530 .0184 .0464 -.1379 .1571 .0329 .0000 .0660 -.0862 -.1427 -.0445 -.0498 .1184 .0064 .1694 -.3090 -.0379 .0223 -.1455 .0445 .1211 .2431 .0677 -.1555 .1419 .1296 .1227 .0802 -.1132 -.0864 .1311 .0730 .1027 .0438 .0255 .1088 .2631 .1639 .0900 -.0919 .1961 .2432 .3040 -.1263 -.0379 .0223 -.0485 .0445 .0629 .0663 .1116 -.0785 -.1078 .0736 .2453 -.0454 .0236 .1329 .0504 .0281 -.0967 -.0155 -.0372 .0618 -1211 .1959 .1129 -.1555 .0630 .1313 .1885 .0000 .1767 .0250 .0948 -.4518 -.0816 .2056 .2076 .1415 -.0233 .1821 .1509 -.0277 -.0287 .1310 -.1247 -.1772 -.1443 .0459 -.0004 .0266 1.0000 .0912 -.0244 -.0531 -.1410 .0820 -.0367 -.0579 .0881 -.0148 .1076 .0441 -.0139 .0729 .1546 .1480 .2503 .0504 -.1090 .0534 -.0330 .1148 .2046 -.0812 .0792 1.0000 -.1119 .0533 .0104 .0569 .0361 .0273 .0651 .0596 -.0844 .1290 .1088 .0361 -.0137 .1645 -.0908 .0497 -.1257 .0540 .0618 .1142 .0912 .0433 .0225 1.0000 .0410 -.0433 .2065 -. 1235 .0400 .1908 -.1183 .0628 .1181 .1477 -.1235 -.0196 -.1)736 -.0803 -.06 1 8 .0872 .0165 .1733 .0355 .1331 .1293 .1 ) 2 1 1.0000 .2597 -.1322 -.0860 -. 1358 .1409 -.0349 .1169 .0554 -.0329 .0682 -.0396 -.0.318 -.0268 .0 0 0 0 .1516 -.0501 -.04 45 -. 1225 .1067 -. 1026 -. 1)5.34 1.0000 -. 1268 -.0651 -. 1027 .1558 .0396 .0885 -. 1023 -.0720 -.0651 .0954 .0835 -.0101 .2.378 .2142 .0 0 0 0 .1310 -. 1 2 0 1 .0605 .02 19 .1412 1.0000 -.0903 .1737 -. 0666 -.1461 .01 50 .1617 .2290 -.0903 .2036 .0689 -.0048 -.1246 .2426 .04 78 .0398 .0679 .2354 -.1089 -.0569 1.0000 .0054 -.1036 -.0944 -. 1420 .0871 -.0737 .1529 -.1244 .1244 .1464 -.0808 -.0931 -.0.342 -.0996 .2181 -.1464 -.0701 -.0.371 Appendix A. •ii•.stion1Matrix naire No. Item No. N -29 N-39 N-43 N -47 N-54 P- 8 1’- 1 2 P-15 P-32 p -49 P -91 P-58 •S- 4 S- 9 S -18 S -19 S -22 S -25 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 45 C o r r e l a t io n m a t r i x for the 62 s e l e c t e d i t e m s (contd. ) 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 1.0000 -.0152 -.0710 .0236 .1656 .0354 .0054 .0387 .0064 -.0442 .0527 .1738 11 18 .0864 .1672 -. 1600 .1585 .1259 1.0000 .1025 .1702 .1299 -.0528 .0301 .1 0 0 1 .2079 .1 2 0 1 .1636 -.0775 -.0864 .0852 .0552 .0881 .1044 -.0640 1 .0 0 0 0 .0702 .1941 .0599 -.0944 -.0963 .0964 .0148 -.0215 -.0046 -.0691 .0253 -.0946 -.0148 .0080 -.0585 1.0000 .1695 -.2101 -.0308 .0268 .0243 .0653 .1441 .0755 -.1258 .0491 -.0756 .1652 -.0750 -.0879 1.0000 .0904 -.1095 -.0140 .0140 .0068 -.0601 .2570 -.0157 .1608 .0965 -.0577 .0037 .1762 1.0000 -.1758 .182! .0526 .1727 .0702 -.0121 .2151 -.0316 -.0177 .1446 -.1231 -. 1094 1.0000 .1677 -.0703 .0367 -.0808 -.0931 -. 1370 -.0996 .1175 .1825 -.0701 -.0371 1.0000 .0303 -.0035 .0670 .0841 .0316 .0685 .0909 .1546 -.0993 -. 1381 1.0000 .1546 .2305 .0971 .1104 .1218 .1867 .0976 .0156 -.0141 1.0000 .2008 .0069 .0534 -. 1095 .0420 .0797 -.0126 .0913 liU 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 1.0000 -.0225 .0788 -.1372 .1305 .1341 .0410 .2003 1.0000 -.0160 -.0420 .1203 .0442 .0741 .1259 1.0000 .0895 .0978 .0 0 0 1 .0293 .1068 1 .0000 -.1158 .1099 .1170 -.0619 1.0000 -.0415 -.1348 .1977 1.0000 .0126 -.0914 1.0000 -.0441 1.0000 ________________ Appendix A-l. Questionnaire Items Included In the Correlation Matrix________________ ^aestionr.nire Item Matrix No. No. 3- : 3-■ B-i: ?-;4 1 2 3 4 5 6 ?-33-2“ 7 8 ) r-;; 10 11 II- ?-3o 2--_ 3--I E— r-Jl 3-52 3-35 13 lb 15 lo 17 18 19 3-5" 20 3-C- o 7- 3 21 22 23 7- 7 "-11 2b 25 :-l; 2 7-1; 2i :-u- 20 3-25 7-2' 7-27 29 30 31 "-■j, 32 33 7-:‘ 7-• ' 34 35 7-13 3'J 7-~5 3 i’ 38 C-5j> 39 3-3 w0 7-59 3- 5 7-o2 N- 2 N-1’9 41 42 N-;' N-;*3 N-h 4 43 44 35 5 4-7 40 Item Everyone wants to do a good Job. Every worker should do his best no matter whom he may hurt in the process. Business creates equality of opportunity and rewards. The good of all will best be served if each individual pursues his self-interest with little interference. Everyone has equal opportunity to get ahead. Everyone has the moral duty to try to make the most of himself. A manager in business should have no excuse for failure. A heavy tax on business is bad for the country. The incompetent do not succeed very often in business. The "law of supply and demand" is real and works in business transactions. Those who work and have ability will be rewarded with success. The test of reword should be one's ability to contribute to the productive pur­ poses of the company. The tensions of business are normal and should be accepted. The team is more important than the individual. American business is singly responsible for our high standard of living. The reason America is great is because of its unique economic system. If a man fails it is his own fault, and he should be ashamed of himself. If workers are contented the supervisor is not doing his job. A manager in business should have the virtues of sobriety, punctuality, dis­ cipline, avoidance of waste, and cheerfulness. A manager in business should work "day and night" so lesser men will show them­ selves worthy by copying him. In business a manager should be willing to sacrifice all leisure and private life. Without cooperatives a few big businesses would have too much control over farmers. If farmers didn't belong to a cooperative, they would not get a fairprice for the things they produce. Cooperatives help to keep down the number of middlemen who make profits off farmers. It is only through cooperatives that farmers can buy and sell in a business-like manner. Cooperatives help keep down the price of things which the farmer must buy to run his fnrm. Cooperatives help the farmer to get the best deal he can out of federal government regulations. A cooperative is the united action of a group of people engaged in a similar enter­ prise to promote their mutual interests. The Farm Bureau would be more effective if it stayed out of politics. Cooperatives do more for large farmers than for small farmers. It is the successful farmer who patronizes the cooperative more than the farmer who is having a hard time. In the long run cooperatives should become strong enough to have dominant control over easiness and agriculture. Most farmers think private business can do the job better than cooperatives. If a farmer really believes in individualism he would not belong to acooperative. The trouble with cooperatives today is that there are not enough idealists and liberals in the movement. Farmer cooperative members' first consideration should be in cutting out the middleman's profits on the things they must use. Membership in cooperatives should be open to all farmers. Being a member of a cooperative is more important than buying products from the cooperative for most farmers. The only successful farmer cooperative is the one that is run primarily in a business-like way. There is more democratic participation in cooperatives now than there has been in the past. To be a true cooperative land should be owned cooperatively. For most farm members, the cooperative is Just a matter of dollars and cents. People in cooperatives should use them to promote their political views. Sometimes I feel that the board tries to block everything I try to do. When a number of suppliers all present different technical specifications for their products I sometimes don't know what to buy. Sometimes in this Joo it gets so you can't trust anyone. Sometimes I feel that this is a "dead end" job without a future. Sometimes I really don't know what cooperatives are trying to accomplish. 115 116 ^ ues t i on- naire Item Matrix No. No. i*9 ?- - 50 P- 13 51 ■- i : 52 ?-S2 P- •'*? 53 51* P -^l r-50 33- ) 3 -:o 55 55 57 58 59 60 ^“wC 61 62 Item Many times this Job gets so confusing and demanding that I wonder where I'm at. I get the impression that big city people with whom we (the cooperative) do (does) business try to take advantage of us (it). The present-day economy is so big and complex that local businesses like this co­ operative don't have a place any more. When you (your cooperative) deal (deals) with suppliers would you say thatyou (it) usually are (is) in a position to deal on your (its) terms. The bigger a supplier gets the more we are (the farmer is) at his mercy. Sometimes it gets almost impossible to follow the fluctuations in supply, demand, and prices. In the long run a cooperative manager doesn't have much to say about his operation. The big producers can pretty well control the supply and distribution of products. I participate in many community activities. I have very few really close friends in this community. The Job which would be the best promotion for me (a cooperative manager) would be to become a branch manager for same larger company. Most of the time the supplier representatives who call on me (our cooperative) don't give a darn about me as a person (us as people); all they are after is a sale. When ray family and I moved to this community it took a long time before people accepted us. I am not very well accepted in this community. I would like to live in most any other community than this one. Appendix B, A Trace Line Plot of the Competitive Yardstick Index composed of Items C-5, C -7, C-13, and C-42. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (C-7) Item (C-13) »• 80 Item (C-5) 60 Item (C-42) 40 20 0 1 2 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 4 item s. 117 Appendix C, A Trace Line Plot of the Anti-Big Business Index composed of Items C-3, C-31, and C-34. Item (C-3) 100 Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) Item (C-34) 80 60 40 • Item (C-31) 20 0 1 2 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 3 item s. 118 3 Appendix D, A Trace Line Plot of the P ro-B u siness Index consisting of Items C-10 and C -53. Item (C-53) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 80 60 40 20 0 2 1 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 2 item s. 119 3 Appendix E, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Cooperatives As a Source of P olitical Power consisting of Items C-16, C-23, and C-62 . Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (C-23) Item (C-16) 80 60 40 20 em (C-62) 0 2 1 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 3 item s. 120 3 Appendix F, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Cooperative Idealism consisting of Items C-20, C-26, C-27, C-35, C-37, C-45, C-48, C-56, C-59, and C-60. (Items 20, 45, and 59 had m arginals below 10% or above 90%) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (C-26) 80 —-i Item (C-60) 60 Item (C-27) 40 Item (C-35) Item (Cr37) /<», Item (C-48) 20 0 1 3 2 4 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 7 item s. 121 5 Appendix G, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Favorability Toward Econom­ ic Goals of Cooperation consisting of Items C-13, C-34, C -7, and C-5. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (C-13) Item (C-7) Item (C-34) 80 Item (C-5) 60 40 20 0 1 2 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 4 item s. 122 3 Appendix H, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Orientation Toward Econom­ ic Democracy consisting of Items C-26, C-27, C-56, and C-60. Item (C-26) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (C-27) Item (C-56) Item (C-60) 2 1 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 4 item s. 123 3 Appendix I, A Trace Line Plot of the Traditional Individualism Index con­ sisting of Item s B - l, B -6, B-14, and B-41- Item (B-14) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 v Item (B -l) 80 Item (B-6) 60 40 20 Item (B-41) 0 2 1 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 4 item s. 12k 3 Appendix J, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of the Centrality of the Free Enterprise System to the American Society consisting of Items B - l l , B-28, B-44, and B-46. Item ( B - ll) 100 Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) Item (B-46) Item (B-28) 80 60 Item (B-44) 40 20 0 2 1 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 4 item s. 12-5 3 Appendix K, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Individual Opportunity, Desire for Achievement, Success and Upward Mobility consisting of Items B-17, B-21, B-30, B-36, B-38, and B-50. Item (B-38) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (B-21) Item (B-36) 80 60 40 Item (B-50) 20 0 1 2 3 4 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 6 item s. 126 5 Appendix L, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of the Rigors and Demands of Leadership consisting of Items B -24, B-40, B-52, B-55, and B -61. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 80 Item (B-52) 60 40 20 Item Item Item Item 0 2 1 3 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 5 item s. 127 4 (B-55) (B-40) (B-24) (B-61) Appendix M, A Trace Line Plot of the Free Enterprise C reed- A, con sist­ ing of Items B - l, B-6, B-14, B-17, B-24, B-28, B-36, and B-44. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 1 2 4 3 5 6 7 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 8 item s. 128 8 Appendix N, A Trace Line Plot of the Free Enterprise Creed - B, consisting of Items B - l, B-6, B-14, B-17, B-24, B-44, and B-50. Item (B-17) Item (B-36) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item (B-6) 80 Item (B-24) Item (B-50) 60 (B-141 40 20 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 8 item s. 129 7 Appendix O, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Individualism consisting of Items B - l, B-14, B-17, B-24, and B-50. Item (B-17) Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 r ....... 80 •Item • • • • •• • • •• I • • • ,Item • ••• iItem t M M M 60 • / 40 •y / / / *1 f / ^ > / i 20 > / \ 1 2 3 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 5 item s. 130 / ' M M M (B-14) (B-24) (B-50) Appendix P, Index of Cooperative Economic and Occupational N orm lessness consisting of Items N-2, N-29, N-39, N-43, N-47, and N-54. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 80 60 40 cn 20 ■ 0 1 3 2 4 . 5 Adjusted item sco res on latent continuum of 6 item s. 131 6 Appendix Q, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Economic P ow erlessness-A , consisting of Items P -8, P-15, P-32, P -49, P -58, and N-29. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 Item ( I *1-29 Item (P -49) Item (P-58) Item (P-32) 80 +»• +7 Item (P-8) 60 40 •• •• •• 20 0 1 3 2 4 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 6 item s. 152 5 Item (P-15) Appendix R, A Trace Line Plot of the Index of Economic P ow erlessness B, consisting of Items P-15, P -32, P -49, and P-58. Proportion of total sample endorsing items (N=90) 100 80 Item (P-49) 60 Item (P-32) 40 Item (P-15) 20 0 2 1 Adjusted item scores on latent continuum of 4 item s. 133 3 Appendix S, Index of Isolation from Social Interaction in the Community consisting of Items S-4, S-9, S-22, and S-25. A Trace Line Plot was not drawn because of the low marginals. Ex: % Endorsed Item S-4 3 0 .0 S-9 15.6 S-22 7.8 S-25 5 .6 13^ A p p e n d ix T , The I n t e r v i e w S c h e d u le U sed * M ic h ig a n S t a t e U n i v e r s i t y D e p a r tm e n t o f S o c i o l o g y and A n th r o p o l o g y M ic h ig a n C o o p e r a t i v e S tu d y M anager, Board Member, Farm er Member S c h e d u l e s For interviewer use only: Respondent: (M, B, F) Interviewer's name: Date of interview: Interview started: " terminated: Cooperative name: Town: Respondent's name: Check one: Manager Board Member Office Farmer Member Sample Number: Book Number: Schedule Number: (Present PERSONAL INFORMATION In t h i s s e c t i o n we would l i k e t o g e t some i n f o r m a t i o n a b o u t you a s a p e r s o n and a b o u t y o u r a c t i v i t y w i t h t h e C o-op. 1. 2. What What 2 .0 . 2 .1 . 2 .2 . 2 .3 . 2 b . Sex: 3. i s y o u r a g e ( t o n e a r e s t b i r t h d a y ) ? ________________ is your m a rita l s ta tu s : Widower ____ , and h ave b e e n f o r _________ y e a r s . D iv o rc e d o r l e g a l l y s e p a r a t e d f o r _______ y e a r s . S i n g l e ______ M a r r ie d and have b e e n f o r _______ y e a r s . Male ______ Fem ale _______ What was y o u r f a t h e r ' s o c c u p a t i o n ( o r t h a t o f t h e p e r s o n who r e a r e d an d s u p p o r t e d you f o r most o f y o u r p r e - w o r k i n g l i f e ) ? I n t e r v i e w e r : G et a c o m p l e te d e s c r i p t i o n su c h a s ''owned and o p e r a t e d a 2 5 0 - a c r e f a r m w h i l e he worked a s a m e c h a n ic i n a stam p p l a n t 3 m i l e s aw ay, w hich employed 200 p e o p l e who l i v e d i n a s m a l l town o f 2 , 0 0 0 l o c a t e d i n t h e r o c k y fa r m land a re a o f s o u th e rn , n o r th e r n M ich ig an "). A. E s t i m a t e t h e l a r g e s t am ount o f t o t a l income w hich y o u r f a t h e r r e c e i v e d d u r i n g any one c a l e n d a r y e a r . L e s s t h a n $2000 $2000 t o $2999 $3000 t o $3999 $4000 t o $4999 $5 000 t o $5999 5. $6000 t o $6999 $7000 t o $7999 $8000 t o $8999 $9000 t o $9999 $ 1 0 ,0 0 0 t o $ 1 1 ,9 9 9 $ 1 2 ,0 0 0 o r more What was y o u r g r a n d f a t h e r ' s o c c u p a t i o n ? * T h ree s e p a r a t e i n t e r v i e w asked of m anagers, b o ard s c h e d u l e s w ere c o l l a p s e d 5 -B o a rd Member, F - F a r m e r s c h e d u l e s were u s e d . D i f f e r e n t an d v a r i a t i o n s o f q u e s t i o n s were members, and f a r m e r mem bers. F o r economy o f s p a c e , t h e t h r e e i n t o one s c h e d u l e . I t e m s w h ich d i f f e r e d a r e co d e d : M-M anager, Member. I f n o t co d ed , t h e i t e m was t h e same f o r a l l t h r e e s a m p l e s . 135 136 t 6m . What was the last year of school that you completed? 1 2 3 k 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 oBF. How many acres do you farm? ______ Do you own all of this acreage? Yes 15 No (Circle one) l6 Don't know If no, how many acres do you own: ____ Acres rented or leased ______ Other ______ Don 11 know ______ What are the major types of farming you do? 7M. Of the courses you took in school, which ones do you feelgave you the kind knowledge which serves you best in your present job? 1. 7B. 8m 7F. :8m . 20B. High school ____________________ What kind him for a 2. of training do you think a man should job as Co-op manager? of College_______________________ have before you would recommend Can you tell me something abcut the type and size of the farms in this area? iype of farming (dairy, fruit, wheat beans) Proportion of farmers of this type. 0BF. Would you encourage a young man to seek employment witha local cooperative en7M. gaged in the same type of business as this cooperative? Yes _____ No If yes, why?____________________________________________________ If no, why? ________________________________________________________________________ 9 V. Of the major products and supplies which are handled by your Co-op, would you tell 19M. me what products you use most often? (Probe for feed, seed, and farm supplies.) 20B. List product: Brand Name: Others: OCCUPATIONAL INFORMATION: JOB HISTORY We would like to know about the kinds of jobs you have had in the past and how you got into management. Let's start with your present job. How long have you been with this co­ operative? Years ______ Months . (interviewer: code the years worked on each job by marking a 1 for each year on that Job; start with and include present Job. Code a 2 for each year on the job before the present one, a 3 for the one before that, etc.) DM. Year 11M. Past Employer (by type of business). Start with present job and work back. How long have you been a Co-op mana­ ger here? 12M. Code Job Se­ quence 15M. What was your job title;i.e., what kind of work did you do? llM. 15M. How did you feel about your past jobs? Do you think they were necessary ex­ perience in pre­ paring for your present job? Yes No Why 16m. What types of training and experience do you think would have been better background for your present job (if any)? l>Jl iJx) Comments: 17M. Now I would like to get more information about your operation, especially in relation to competition. What do you consider to be the trading area; i.e., how far around your store do you consider the best area to be in terms of service and location of your patrons? Here is a map of your area, would you draw a line around your location which shows where your customers are located? 2-M. Of the products listed in 19M, could you estimate the percent of mark-up which you get? _________ 21M. 'Which of these do you feel are best received by your patrons? (Check best re­ ceived) Read list back to respondent one at a time and record mark-up. Mark-up Dollar Value Best Received 22M. What is the total dollar value of all these items which you purchased in the last fiscal year? 2jM. What is the total dollar volume of all products purchased for the last fiscal year 1 $_____________ 2lM. H o w much of this are products which you buy from farmers and resell? $_____________ 25M. 22B. Generally, how would you say this cooperative stands in relation to the competition in this area? Size; ~~ ~ ~ It's larger than the competition. It's about the same as the competition. It's smaller than the competition. Don't know. Gross Sales: Its gross sales are much higher. Its gross sales are about the same. Its gross sales are much lower. Don't know . Net Profit: Its net profit is much higher. Its net profit is about the same. Its net profit is much lower. Don't know. 2oM. I n r e g a r d t o t h e g r o s s m a r k e t i n y o u r a r e a f o r t h i n g s w h ich you p r o c e s s and s e l l , c o u l d you e s t i m a t e t h e t o t a l am ount s p e n t b y f a r m s a n n u a l l y i n t h i s a r e a f o r : ( i f r e s p o n d e n t d o e s n ' t know, code b l a n k s DK ( d o n ' t know). Product Total Amount Spent Annually What Proportion of That Market Do You Get Feed _______________ _____________ Seed______________ _______________ _____________ G r a i n _____________________________________________ Fertilizer _______________ _____________ Farm Supplies _______________ _____________ O th er 27M. 23B. Considering the facilities of your Co-op, do you feel you are (it is) getting your (its) share of the market? Yes _____ No If no, what share do you think you (it) should have? _____ $ If no, do you have any sale or market programs planned which you (it) hope will get the share of the market you (it) desire(s)? Yes ____ No_____ What type of program(s) have you (they) planned? __________________________ _ How l o n g w i l l i t t a k e y o u (th e m ) t o a c c o m p l i s h t h e s e p ro g r a m s ? _______________ _ _ _ We would l i k e t o know how you f e e l a b o u t y o u r ( t h e Co-op m a n a g e r ’s ) j o b : Here a r e some s ta te m e n ts a b o u t th e m a n a g e r's jo b . Some p e o p l e a g r e e w i t h th e m , w h i l e o t h e r s d i s a g r e e . As I r e a d them t o y o u , p l e a s e t e l l me i f yo u a g r e e o r d i s a g r e e w i t h e a c h s t a t e m e n t . 28 m . 10BF. 29M. :OBF. 30M. 10BF. 31M. 10BF. 32M. 10BF. 53M. 10BF. 3AM. 10BF. Agree A good c o o p e r a t i v e m anag e r i s o n e who g e t s o f f e r s f o r ______ b e t t e r jo b s. A good c o o p e r a t i v e m an age r i s one who d e v o t e s h i s l i f e t o o ne c o o p e r a t i v e . _____________________________________________________________ B e in g a Co-op manager i s more I m p o r t a n t t h a n j u s t h a v i n g a jo b . ______ A Co-op m an ager i s d i s l o y a l i f he a c c e p t s a jo b w i t h a b i g company. ______ A good Co-op m an age r s h o u l d t a k e ti m e on t h e jo b t o r e a d one o r two C o o p e r a t i v e t r a d e j o u r n a l s ______ A good Co-op m an ager s h o u l d go t o s t a t e and r e g i o n a l m e e t i n g s f o r Co-op m an ag e rs r e g u l a r l y . ______ A l l t h i n g s c o n s i d e r e d , a good Co-op m anage r g e t s b e t t e r i n f o r m a t i o n b y taL k i n g t o o t h e r m a n a g e rs t h a n by t a l k i n g ______ t o h i s Co-op members. D isagree ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ 139 55M. From whom do you expect the best quality for the fairest price H B F . w h e n you deal with them: Which Ones Large Cooperatives _____ Large privately owned suppliers _____ Local suppliers _____ D o n 't know 3bM. A Co-op manager (A Cooperative) should purchase all of his (its) 12BF.supplies from large cooperatives because: He (They) believe(s) in the cooperative idea. Cooperatives must support each other to survive. He (They) get(s) the best price in the long run. He (They) get(s) the best service in the long run. (if) None of the above (why or why not)? _______________________ D o n ’t know. Other. 3 7M. A Co-op manager (A cooperative) should buy the same type of product from more BF13*than one supplier because: He (it) can play one against the other and get the best deal. His (its) customers benefit from a variety of brands. This is the way a good manager should act (BF: This is the way a good business should operate.) Don't know. Other. 36m . As the manager of this cooperative, how would you say you are considered by the community? ILBF.How do you think the manager of your cooperative is considered by the community? A very important part of the community. An important part of the community. Not a very important part. Not important at all. Don't know. Other. 39M. How active would you say your board members are in the affairs of the Co-op? ?5BF.How active would you say most members are in the affairs of the Co-op? Very active Fairly active Not very active Not active at all AOM. Would you say that all of the interests of various sections of the membership ioBF.are equally represented by your board? Yes No D o n 't know 'Which interest groups are over represented? _________________________________ __ Which are u n d e r - r e p r e s e n t e d ? ________________________________________________________ _ llM. I s there a harmonious atmosphere among the board members or is there consider17BP. able bickering and strife? Harmonious Strife D o n 't know ^2M. If you were picking the board would you pick these men or different ones? i8b f . Same Different Don't know If different, 43M. what type of men would you pick? __________________________________ Are there one or two men on the board whom you use to "sound out" before you present a new idea or program to the board? Yes No Don't know If yes, do these men usually help you to see the idea to the other board members Yes No D o n 't know If yes, can you think of some examples? ____________________________________________ -»4M. Would you say that one or two m e n on the board tend to influence the rest on 19BF. most issues? Yes No Don't know M. If yes, are they usually the ones you "sound out?" Yes No Don't know B. If yes, would you say that you are one of those who influences others? Yes No Don't know If no, what type of person usually influences others? ___________________________ 20F. Do you think the board and the manager don't pay enough attention to the wishes of the membership? Yes No Don't know Ikl Some people believe that today's competition makes It hard for a local Cooperative to sur­ vive by itself. These people think that big organizations of Co-ops may be the answer. ••1. We would like to know how you feel about this. As things stand now, are you for or against this Co-op becoming part of a larger Cooperative? For a. _____ Against _____ Don't know If for, (l) why are you for it? ___________________________________________________ (2) is there any particular large Co-op you'd favor joining up with? Yes _____ No If y e s , which one? ____________________________________________________ b. If don't know (l) please explain: ________________________________________________ (2) is there any particular Co-op your local Co-op should consider joining up with? _______________________________________________ c. If against (l) why are you against it? ___________________________________________ (2) under what conditions would you consider changing your mind? (3) is there any large Co-op you'd consider joining up with? (A sk t h e f o l l o w i n g f o r c e d - c h o i c e q u e s t i o n s r e g a r d l e s s o r u n fav o rab le r e s p o n s e .) of h is fa v o ra b le (A ) H e r e a r e a s e t o f c o n d i t i o n s c o - o p p e o p l e m i g h t t a k e i n t o a c c o u n t i f t h e y had t o c o n s i d e r w h e t h e r t h i s C o -o p s h o u l d j o i n u p w i t h a la r g e r one. W hic h o f t h e s e make y o u t h i n k more f a v o r a b l y a b o u t i t ? M anagers: Yes I f t h e s a l a r y w o u ld b e h i g h e r . ______ I f t h e r e w o u ld b e a b e t t e r c h a n c e o f g e t t i n g a h e a d . ______ I f t h e r e w o u ld b e go od f r i n g e b e n e f i t s ( s u c h a s r e t i r e m e n t p l a n e t c . ) . _______________________________________ ______ I f I co u ld be s u r e o f k e e p in g t h i s j o b . ______ I f I c o u l d k e e p c o n t r o l o v e r t h e o p e r a t i o n . ____________ ______ I f I w e re t o b e r e l i e v e d o f some o f t h e p r e s s u r e s o f t h i s Job. I f t h e f a r m e r m em bers w o u ld b e f o r i t . ______ O t h e r _______________________________________________________ No ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ,______ ______ B oard M em bers: I f th e b o a rd co u ld keep a sa y in th e d e c i s i o n s a f f e c t i n g t h e l o c a l C o-op. I f t h e s e r v i c e w o u ld b e b e t t e r . I f t h e p a t r o n a g e w o uld b e h i g h e r . I f p r i c e s w o u ld b e l o w e r . I f t h e f a r m e r member w o u ld b e f o r i t . I f t h e m a n a g e r w o u ld b e f o r i t . O th er ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ ______ 142 Farmer Members: Yes _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ No _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ _____ If the rest (or most) of the board would be against it. _____ If the farmer members would be against it.__________ _____ If the manager would be against it. _____ _____ _____ _____ If the service would be better. If the patronage would be higher. If the prices would be lower. If the manager would be for it. If the board would be for it. If the farmer members could retain some control over the question. Other ______________________________________________ (5)M Which of the following would make you think more unfavorably about it? If the board would be against it. If the farmer members would be against it. Other _____________________________________________ B Other _________________________________________ _ F If the board would be against it.____________________ _____ If the manager would be against it. _____ If the other farmer members would be against it. _____ Other ___________________________________________ 4oM. You undoubtedly have many salesmen calling on you to solicit business. different salesmen call on you in an average week? 4'i'm . How many Do you feel that there are too many salesmen calling on you? Yes ~8m . _____ _____ _____ _____ No _____ D o n ’t know Would you say that salesmen are your major source of information on the technical aspects of products? Yes _____ No _____ D o n 11 know If no, where do you get the technical information necessary to make a decision to b u y ? ________________________________________________________________________ _ 49M. Would you say that most salesmen spend too much time with "small talk?" Yes _____ No _____ D o n ’t know If yes, would you rather have a salesman tell you about his product and leave in a hurry? Yes 50M. _____ No _____ Don ’t know Do you think there is such a thing as "sales personality?" Yes No D o n ’t know 1^3 51M. Do y o u t h i n k a s a l e s m a n s h o u l d b e a g g r e s s i v e a sale? Y es I f no, ______ No i n t h e way h e a p p r o a c h e s y o u t o make D o n ' t know s h o u l d h e b e lo w p r e s s u r e ? ________________________ • 52M. What a r e t h e s a l e s t e c h n i q u e s u s e d b y s a l e s m e n w h i c h a r e m o s t l i k e l y to buy h is p ro d u c t? 53M. Do y o u e v e r a c c e p t s p e c i a l f a v o r s f r o m s a l e s m e n e t c . )? Y es ______ No (lik e le ttin g to g e t you h im b u y y o u m e a l s , ______ D o n ' t know I f y e s , d o e s t h i s i n f l u e n c e y o u t o b u y f r o m h im ? _______________________________________ I f n o , why n o t ? ________ 5^M. Do y o u t h i n k a s a l e s m a n ' s j o b Yes ______ No i s a n e a s y one? ______ D o n ' t know I f y e s , why? _____________________________________________________________________________________ I f n o , why? _____________________________________________________________________________________ 55M. Do y o u f e e l t h a t y o u r j o b a s m a n a g e r i s m ore d i f f i c u l t t h a n t h a t o f a s a l e s m a n ? Y es ______ No ______ D o n ' t know I f y e s , why? ____________________________________________________________________________________ _ I f n o , why? _____________________________________________________________________________________ BIBLIOGRAPHY Abel, Theodore. "The Pattern of a Successful Political Movement," American Sociological Review, II (April, 1937). Abshier, George. "The Management Team," American Cooperation. Washington, D.C.: American Institute of Cooperation, 1961. American Cooperation, 1939, A Collection of Papers. American Institute of Cooperation, 1959, PP- 151-17*+ + 201-21?. Beal, George. "The Job Ahead for Our Co-ops," 1 (July, 195*0, 16-18. Iowa Farm Science, IX, No. Beal, George. "Are Farmers Satisfied with Their Co-ops?" Science, IX, No. 10 (April, 1955), 7-10. Iowa Farm Bell, Daniel. The End of Ideology: On the Exhaustion of Political Ideas in the Fifties, Rev. New York: The Free Press, 196l. Birnbaum, Norman. "The Sociological Study of Ideology (l9*+0-6o): A Trend Report and Bibliography," Current Sociology, IX, No. 2 (i960), 91* Broom, L., and Selznick, P. Sociology: A Text with Adapted Readings. Evanston, 111.: Row, Peterson & Co., 1955Brown, E. J., and Bealer, R. C. "Value Orientations and Behavioral Correlates," Rural Sociology, XXII, No. 1 (March, 1957), 51-5*+• Buck, Solon J. The Granger Movement; A Study of Agricultural Organization and Its Political, Economic, and Social Manifestations, l870-l88o~l Lincoln, Neb.: University of Nebraska Press, 1913Casselman, Paul H. The Cooperative Movement and Some of Its Problems. New York: The Philosophical Libraiy, 1951Cattell, Raymond B. Factor Analysis: An Introduction, and Manual for the Psychologist and Social Scientist. New York: Harper 80 Brothers, 1952. Chambers, C. A. "The Cooperative League of the United States of America, 1916-1961: A Study of Social Theory and Social Action," Agricultural History, XXVI, No. 2 (April, 1962), 59-8l. Copp, James H. Trace Line Analysis: An Improved Method of Item Analysis. State University, Pa.: Pennsylvania State University, February 9, 1959* (Preliminary draft) Copp, James H. "Perceptual Influences on Loyalty in a Farmer Cooperative," Rural Sociology, XXIX, No. 2 (June, 196*+), 168-180. Copp, J. H., and Rust, I. W. Exploring Communication Processes in a Farmer Cooperative: A Case Study. Farmer Cooperative Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, General Report 97. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, August, 196l. Daniels, John. Cooperation: An American Way. New York: Ikk Covici-Friede, 1938. 145 Ellsworth, R. H. The Study of Farmers' Cooperatives. Washington, D.C.: Farmer Cooperative Service, 1954. Erdman, H. E. "Trends in Cooperative Expansion," Journal of Farm Economics, XXXII (November, 1950), 1019-1030. Folkman, William S. "Board Members as Decision Makers in Farmers' Coopera­ tives," Rural Sociology, XXIII, No. 3 (September, 1958). Franz, V. R. W., and Haller, A. 0. Big and Little Co-ops: Attitudes of People in Locally Owned Cooperatives Toward Mergers with Large Co­ operatives. Final Report of Project of Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Michigan State Agricultural Experiment Station, East Lansing, Michigan, February, 1962. Fruchter, B. Introduction to Factor Analysis. Nostrand Co., 1954• Princeton, N. J.: D. Van Gerth, Hans, and Mills, C. Wright. Character and Social Structure. New York; Harcourt, Brace & Co., 1953* Gessner, A. L. Farmer Cooperative Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture General Report. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, April, 1964. Harman, Harry H. Modem Factor Analysis. Chicago Press, I960. Chicago, 111.: The University of Heberle, Rudolf. Social Movements: An Introduction to Political Sociology. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts, Inc., 1951Hicks, John D. The Populist Revolt: A History of the Farmers' Alliance and the People's Party. Lincoln, Neb.: University of Nebraska Press, Hoffer, C. R., and Gibson, D. L. "The Community Situation as it Affects Agricultural Extension Work," Special Bulletin 312, Michigan Agricul­ tural Experimental Station, East Lansing, Michigan, October, 194-1. Infield, Henrik F. "The Sociological Approach in Research on Cooperation," Rural Sociology, XIV, No. 2 (June, 1949), 157-158. Kercher, L. C.; Kebker, V. W.; and Leland, W. C. Consumers' Cooperatives in the North Central States. Minneapolis, Minn.: University of Minnesota Press, 1941. Kile, Orville M. 1948. The Farm Bureau Through Decades. Maryland: Waverly Press, King, C. Wendell. Social Movements in the United States. New York: House, Inc., 19567 Knapp, Joseph. "Are Cooperatives Good Business?" XXXXV (January-February, 1957), 57-64. Random Harvard Business Review, Kress, A. J. (ed.) Introduction to the Cooperative Movement. New York: Harper & Brother^ 1941. 1U6 Lipset, S. Agrarian Socialism. Berkeley, Calif;: University of California Press. 1950. Loomis, Charles P., and Beegle, Allan J. Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1950. Rural Social Systems. New York: Mannheim, Karl. Ideology and Utopia: An Introduction to the Sociology of Knowledge. New York: Harcourt, Brace & Co., 1936. Manuel, Milton. "The Case for Merging Co-ops," Agricultural Experiment Station Circular 375- Kansas: Kansas State University, i960. Merton, Robert K. Press 1957. Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: The Free Miller, Raymond W. A Conservative Looks at Cooperatives. Athens, Ohio: Ohio University Press, 196A. Miller, R. W., and Jensen, A. L. "Failures of Farmers' Cooperatives," Harvard Business Review, XXV (Winter, 19^7), 213-226. Parsons, Talcott. The Social System. New York: The Free Press, 1951- Salantos, Theodore. Farmer Movements in the South, 1869-1933- Lincoln, Neb.: University of Nebraska Press, 19&0. Schaars, J. "New Frontiers for Wisconsin Dairy Coope," American Cooperation. Washington, D.C.: American Institute of Cooperation" 1961. • Smelser, Neil J. Theory of Collective Behavior. New York: Press, 1963* The Free Sorenson, V. L. Elevator Outlook Committee Progress Report. Agricultural Economic Department. East Iansing, Mich.: Michigan State University, 1961. Taylor, Carl C. Rural Sociology. New York: Harper & Brothers, 1933* Turner, Ralph H., and Killian, Lewis H. Collective Behavior. Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1957- Englewood Ulrey, 0., and Howland, Arthur. Cooperative and Non-Profit Dairy Associations in Michigan. East Iansing, Mich.: State University Agricultural Experi­ ment Station, February, 1956. Voorhis, Jerry. American Cooperatives. New York: Harper & Brothers, 1961. Wakeley, Ray E., and Harp, John. "An Overview of Sociological Research on Farmer Cooperatives in the United States," International Archives of Sociology of Cooperation. Paris, France. (Summer, 1966). Wakeley, Ray E "Sociological Research on Farmers' Organizations and Agri­ cultural Cooperatives," Rural Sociology, XXII, No. 3 (September, 1957).