INFORMATION TO USERS This material was produced from a microfilm copy of the original document. While the most advanced technological means to photograph and reproduce this document have been used, the quality is heavily dependent upon the quality of the original submitted. The following explanation of techniques is provided to help you understand markings or patterns which may appear on this reproduction. 1. The sign or "target" for pages apparently lacking from the document photographed is "Missing Page(s)". If it was possible to obtain the missing page(s) or section, they are spliced into the film along with adjacent pages. This may have necessitated cutting thru an image and duplicating adjacent pages to insure you complete continuity. 2. When an image on the film is obliterated with a large round black mark, it is an indication that the photographer suspected that the copy may have moved during exposure and thus cause a blurred image. You will find a good image of the page in the adjacent frame. 3. When a map, drawing or chart, etc., was part of the material being photographed the photographer followed a definite method in "sectioning" the material. It is customary to begin photoing at the upper left hand corner of a large sheet and to continue photoing from left to right in equal sections with a small overlap. If necessary, sectioning is continued again — beginning below the first row and continuing on until complete. 4. The majority of users indicate that the textual content is of greatest value, however, a somewhat higher quality reproduction could be made from "photographs" if essential to the understanding of the dissertation. Silver prints o f "photographs" may be ordered at additional charge by writing the Order Department, giving the catalog number, title, author and specific pages you wish reproduced. 5. PLEASE NOTE: Some pages may have indistinct print. Filmed as received. University Microfilms International 300 North Zeeb Road Ann Arbor, Michigan 40106 USA St. John’s Road, Tyler’s Green High Wycombe, Bucks, England HP10 8HR I I 77-11,618 BECK, John Henry, 1949STATE AID AND EQUAL EDUCATIONAL OPPORTUNITY IN MICHIGAN. Michigan State University, Ph.D., 1976 Economics, general Xerox University Microfilms, Ann Arbor, Michigan 48106 STATE AID AND EQUAL EDUCATIONAL OPPORTUNITY IN MICHI G A N By John Henry Beck A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michi g a n State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DO C T O R OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1976 ABSTRACT STATE AID AND EQUAL EDUCATIONAL OPPORTUNITY IN MICHIGAN By John Henry Beck In an effort to make education expenditures inde­ pendent of school district wealth, many states including M i c h i g a n have adopted variants of "percentage equalizing" state aid formulas. Under such formulas all districts are guaranteed equal dollars per pupil for each mill levied regardless of the size of the local tax base. There is a "matching" effect in that an increase in local tax levies will increase state aid as well. In districts receiving matching aid the marginal "price" to local voters of one dollar of per pupil educa­ tion expenditures is less than one dollar. Theory pre­ dicts that non-residential shares of the property tax base are also factors in the "price" of school expendi­ tures although the stimulative effect may be less than that of the matching rate if voters believe that some of the taxes on non-residential property w i l l be shifted to themselves. Theory also predicts that the marginal impact of family income on education expenditures should be equal John Henry Beck to the m a r ginal impact of a r e s i d e n t ’s share of noncategorical, lump-sum aid. This study uses regression analysis of the d e t e r ­ minants of education expenditure levels to test the above hypotheses. The results are used to predict the effects of changes in the Mich i g a n school aid formula on the level and distri b ution of expenditures wi t h i n the state. The stimulative effect of non-residential property is found to be significantly greater than, less than, that of the matc h i n g rate. rather than There is some indi ­ cation that this stimulative effect is greater in m e t r o ­ politan areas where there is less fear of loss of jobs from raising taxes on industrial property or higher prices from increasing levies on commercial property. The marg i n a l impact of lump-sum aid is greater than the m a rginal impact of family income, to expectations. also contrary The characteristics of the distribution of income w ithin the school district had no significant effect on per pupil expenditures. A lagged adjustment process is derived in which millage rates adjust with a delay, allowing increases in l ump-sum grants to temporarily raise expenditures above the new e q u i l i b r i u m level. The estimated lag is long, with only about half of the difference bet w e e n actual and desired m i l lage rates being eliminated wi t h i n two years. John Henry Beck When inequality of expenditure levels is measured by the Gini coefficient, the change to percentage e q u a l ­ izing in M ichigan is found to have reduced inequality. « The remaining inequality in expenditures still is p o s i ­ tively related to state equalized value per pupil. If the c u r rent m a x i m u m on the local levy subject to matching aid is removed, predicted expenditures show an increase in inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient but a decrease in inequality associated w i t h differences in SEV (state equalized valuation) Recapture provisions, we althy districts, per pupil and in family income. imposing negative matc h i n g rates on only partially offset the increase in inequality from lifting the ceiling on matc h i n g aid, but further reduce the inequality associated w i t h SEV per pupil and family income. Contrary to studies based on Massachusetts data, unlimited percentage equalizing with recapture would not lead to a negative relationship between SEV per pupil and expenditure levels in Michigan. While inequality in per pupil expenditures would have been greater under the 1972 foundation aid plan than under any of the three variants of percentage equalizing, a foundation plan w i t h higher levels of aid w o u l d result in a more equal distribution of educa t i o n expenditures as measured by the Gini coefficient. The ranking of the five aid formulas considered is u n a f fected by the use of the Atkin s o n inequity measure rather than the Gini coefficient. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I am grateful to D r . James L. Phelps for the opportunity to participate in meetings of the School Finance Research Group and to T o m Nicol, research analyst with the M i c h i g a n Office of the Budget for assistance in the use of the school district data tape. Eileen Healy, of the Office of Revenue and Tax Analysis, provided access to data on the composition of the property tax base by civil divisions, and Pam Ma r v e l and Jacqueline Grossman of the Michigan State University Department of Agricultural Economics furnished preliminary estimates of the portions of civil divisions falling in school d i s ­ tricts . M y greatest thanks are to Professor Byron Brown, chairman of my dissertation committee. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page LIST OF T A B L E S ...................................... vi LIST OF F I G U R E S .......................................... vii Chapter I. INTRODUCTION ................................ The Case for Equal Educational ............................ Opportunity The M i c h i g a n State A i d Plan . . . . Behavior Under Percentage Equalizing . O utline of the Following Chapters . . II. R E V I E W OF STUDIES OF THE DETERMINANTS OF E DUCATION EXPENDITURES ..................... T h e o retical Basis of Expenditure D e t e rmination ......................... The Dependent Vari a b l e .................. Taste , In terest Group and Other V a r i a b l e s ................................ Popula t i o n and Pupil Density and Urbanization ......................... Proportion of Public Students in Secondary School ..................... Scale Economies and the Political Effects of Larger Districts . . . "Interest Group" Varia b l e s . . . . Variables Reflecting Different Expec­ tations and Aspirations . . . . Other V a r i a b l e s ......................... The Price V a r i a b l e ..................... The Local and Residential Share F a c t o r s ................................ Possible Perceived Shifting of Non-Residental Taxes .............. Problems in Identifying the M e d i a n Voter's Share of the Tax Base . . The Input Price Factor .............. The Pupils Per Family Fa c t o r . . . Comparison of Estimates of "Price" E l a s t i c i t y ............................ iii 1 2 7 17 24 26 27 31 34 35 38 39 44 54 58 59 61 65 70 71 73 76 Page Chapter Ability to Pay V a r i a b l e s .............. Reasons for N o t Using Assessed V a l u e Per P u p i l ..................... Estimates of Income Elasticity . . . Variables Reflecting Permanent I n c o m e ................................ Effects of the D i s t ribution of I n c o m e ................................ The Effects of Non-Matching Aid . . Comparison of the Effect of Block G rants and Disposable Income . . . The "Municipal Overburden" Issue . . The Functional Form of the Expenditure E q u a t i o n ............................... III. 82 83 89 93 98 100 106 Ill 113 117 RESULTS OF ESTIMATION OF THE EXPENDITURE E Q U A T I O N ................................... 124 The Effect of the Price Variable . . . Effects of N o n - M atching Aid and Municipal Over burden .................. Effects of Income and the Distribution of I n c o m e ................................134 Effects of Other Variables .............. Estimates of the Distributed Lag R e s p o n s e ................................137 Comparison W i t h Estimates Based on Earlier Years ......................... C o n c l u s i o n ................................142 V. 79 80 PROCEDURES F O R ESTIMATING THE EXPENDITURE E Q U A T I O N ....................................... 106 The Structure of an Hypothesized Lagged Response ......................... A Test of the Equivalence of the Price Effects of Non-Residential Property and M a t c h i n g Aid . . . . . . . Threats to the Consistency and Effi­ ciency of OLS E s t i m a t e s .................. The D a t a ....................................... IV. 79 THE DEGREE OF INEQUALITY IN ACTUAL EXPENDITURES A N D IN PREDICTED E X P E N D I ­ TURES U N D E R AL T E R N A T I V E AID FORMULAS . . The D i s t r ibution of Actual E x p e n d i ­ tures ................................... 143 Measures of the Distribution of Pre­ dicted S p e n d i n g .........................144 iv 125 131 135 14 0 14 3 Chapter Page Comparisons With Alternative Aid P l a n s ....................................... 148 C o n c l u s i o n ................................151 VI. SUMMARY A N D C O N C L U S I O N S ...................153 BIBLIOGRAPHY .......................................... v 15 9 LIST OP TABLES Table Page 1. Survey Results Regressed o n Allot t e d Tax Base S h a r e s ....................................119 2. Symbols and Definitions of Variables 3. Regression Results for Expenditures Per Pupil, 1974-75 126 4. Other Regression Results 138 5. Actual Expenditures in 1972-73 and 1974-75 ....................................... 6. . . . ..................... 121 144 Distribution of Predicted Expenditures for 371 D i s t r i c t s ....................................145 LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 1. Budget Constraints w i t h 2. Individual Choice at Different Income L e v e l s ....................................... vii State Aid . . . . 15 87 CHA P T E R I INTRODUCTION In an effort to make education expenditures inde­ pendent of school district wealth, many states including M i c higan have adopted variants of "percentage equalizing" state aid formulas. Under such formulas all districts are guaranteed equal dollars per pupil for each mill of local school taxes levied regardless of the size of the local tax base. The purpose of this study is to analyze the degree to w h i c h the current Mich i g a n aid formula has reduced inequality in per pupil spending and how m o d i f i c a ­ tions of the aid formula would affect the distribution of e ducation expenditures. This introductory chapter discusses arguments for equalization of education expenditures, the provisions of the M i c h i g a n state aid formula designed to achieve equali­ zation, and what other studies have shown about the effects of similar formulas. The concluding section out ­ lines the contents of subsequent chapters of the present work. 1 2 The Case for Equal Educational Opportunity The desire to equalize educational opportunity has led Coons, Clune and Sugarman to advocate the normative principle that "the quality of public education m a y not be a function of wealth other than the total w e a l t h of the state." Stating the principle raises the question of why state government ought to follow the proposed norm. One answer to this question is simply that the state c o n s titution requires it. This was the ruling of 2 the California Supreme Court in Serrano vs. P r i e s t . A second possible reason for adhering to the p r o ­ posed n o r m is that it achieves a desirable distribution of income. The concern here is w i t h the d i s t r ibution of income w i t h i n the future generation. Providing equal e d u ­ cational opportunities presumably achieves the desired John E. Coons, W i l l i a m H. Clune, III, and Stephen D. Sugarman, Private Wealth and Public Education (Cam­ bridge, Mass.": Harvard University Press, Belknap Press, 1970), p. 304. 2 Cf. Advi s o r y Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, Finan c i n g Schools and Property Tax Relief: A State Responsibility (Washington, D . C . : Govern m e n t Printm g Office, January 1973), pp. 101-102, for a brief sum­ mary of r e levant court cases, and R. Stephen Brow n i n g and David C. Long, "School Finance Re f o r m and the Courts after Rodriguez," in John Pincus, e d . , School Finance in Tran­ sition: The Courts and Educational Re f o r m (Cambridge, M a s s .: B a llinger Publis h i n g C o . , 1974), pp. 81-105, for a more e x t ensive discussion. 3 income distribution b y affecting the future earning power of s t u d e n t s . 1 A third reason depends on the existence of e x t e r ­ nal benefits of education extending be y o n d the boundaries of school districts. Children may later move out of the district and the quality of their previous education wil l affect their new neighbors. For example, a good e d u c a ­ tion will enable t h e m to participate as informed citizens in the democratic processes of their c o m m u n i t i e s , but a poor education may prevent them from getting jobs and leave them a burden on the wel f a r e rolls in their new location. Without state or federal corrective action, the existence of externalities results in a socially suboptimal level of public education being provided by local school districts. If the marginal external benefits of education are greater in those districts w i t h lower expenditure levels, it is optimal for the state to give a larger stimulus to raise expenditure levels in those districts. However, an alternative assumption that marg i n a l benefits are larger in high socioeconomic districts w h e r e e x p e n d i ­ ture levels are already higher implies that state aid, 1Cf. Gail R. Wilensky, State A i d and Educational Opportunity (Beverly Hills, C a l i f . : Sage Publications, 1970), pp. 26-29. 4 following an efficiency criterion, should be allocated in a manner increasing the disparity in expenditure levels.^" Nor need the assumption that marginal external benefits are greater in low socio-economic districts imply that all differences in educational expenditures should be eliminated. Exceedingly high expenditures may be for school services that are private goods providing no e x t e r ­ nal benefits to those outside the district. There is no efficiency argument for state aid bringing expenditures in poor districts up to such high levels. This provides a rationale for upper limits on percentage equalizing aid. Equalizing expenditures beyond the level w h e r e m a r ­ ginal external benefits are zero m u s t be justified as a preferable method of achieving desired redistribution of income. A llowing inequality in spending levels m a y have beneficial effects in the long run. High expenditure d i s ­ tricts can experiment w i t h innovative educational methods that may later be adopted by other districts. A c hieving equality by a one hundred percent state funding system as in Hawaii eliminates the freedom to choose expenditure levels in accordance with local tastes. Even aid formulas designed to compensate for wealth differences while allowing variations due to tastes 1 Ibid., pp. 24-25, 127-128. 5 may be regarded as penalizing residents of districts pr e ­ ferring low expenditure levels because they will not get "their share" of state aid financed by their state tax dollars. On the other hand, wea l t h y districts desiring high expenditure levels are "penalized" if "recapture" provisions for their tastes take a share of their local tax revenues for the state aid fund. The recapture provision in the W i sconsin aid plan is currently b e i n g contested in the courts. Rich residents of districts subject to recapture might put their own children in private schools and vote for low levels of public school support, leaving children from lower income families in these communities with inferior public education.^ Plans that provide for m a t c h i n g aid to education may distort choice to the detriment of other public serv­ ices if the stimulus to education spending results in reductions of other expenditures. 2 There is also an incentive to include as many services as p o s s i b l e — recre ­ ation, libraries, transportation— under the school budget in order to receive matc h i n g aid. cation ^ C o o n s , Clune, and Sugarman, p. 278. 2 Charles S. Benson, The Economics of Public Edu­ (Boston: Houghton Mif f l i n C o . , 1961), p ~ . 245. 3 Coons, Clune, and Sugarman, p. 212. 6 Some writers have questioned the relationship between equal educational opportunity and equal dollar expenditures per pupil. Expenditure differences may fail to reflect the true variation in educational quality or even in amounts of real resources devoted to education because of the differences in the efficiency w i t h w hich school districts operate, the differences in the prices they must pay for equivalent goods and services, and the differences in the e d u c a ­ tional tasks confronting them.l Some opponents of equalizing expenditures have argued that equalization wo u l d result in inferior educational oppor­ tunities in urban areas b ecause of the greater need for compensatory education and the higher costs of inputs in central cities. However, it is quite possible to make allowances for such considerations in aid formulas. For example, Minnesota counts each AFDC child as an additional half pupil unit in calculating state aid. This presumably 2 reflects the need for compensatory education. Lastly, there is the ques t i o n of whe t h e r exp e n d i ­ tures have any effect on schools' output. Some scholars claim they do: . . . as might be expected logically because all the foregoing components [affecting student p e r ­ formance] translate into dollar costs, we find Robert D. Reischauer and Robert W. Hartman, Reforming School Finance (Washington, D . C . : Brookings Institution, 1973), p. 60. 2 Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental R e l a ­ tions, Financing S c h o o l s , pp. 104-105. 7 that measures such as expenditures per pupil and teachers' salary levels are correlated signifi­ cantly w i t h pupil achievement m e a s u r e s . 1 Even those taking an opposing v i e w do not claim that increasing spending will have no benefi c i a l effect. . . . the teacher characteristics w i t h the g r e a t ­ est effect on pupil achievement are not those that are actually purchased. Under such circumstances it is only to be expected that money per se has a small influence on the results of schooling. Yet this does not mean that additional spending, if properly directed, w o u l d not b ring about some improvement in pupil achievement. Having recognized the weaknesses in m e a s u r i n g educational opportunity by expenditure levels, the prese n t study nevertheless takes per pupil spending as the measure of educational quality. The Mich i g a n State Aid Plan One me t h o d of realizing "equal educational o p p o r ­ tunity" is for the state to provide all funds for public education and distribute these funds to districts on the basis of equal per pupil expenditures. However, this would eliminate local choice regarding the level of expenditures. The me t h o d advocated by Coons, Clune and Sugarman to make educational expenditures independent of w ealth and yet allow varia t i o n in expenditures according ^James W. Guthrie et al. , Schools and Inequality (Cambridge, Mass.: M I T Press, 1971), p. 81. 2 A dvi s o r y Commission on Intergovernmental Rela­ tions, F i n ancing S c h o o l s , p. 248. 8 to local tastes was "power equalizing" state aid. simplest f o r m of power equalizing, the ratio of matc h i n g state aid^ In the "percentage equalizing," to the sum of m a t c h i n g aid and local revenues is given by the formula »« _ -i w x local w e a l t h key district wea l t h * U.-U where w ealth is me as u r e d in terms of assessed v a l u a t i o n per pupil. B eginning w i t h the 1973-74 school year, the State of M i c higan distributed aid to local school districts according to a modi f i e d percentage e q u a lizing formula. For that year "key dist r i c t wealth" per pupil. 2 in (1.1) was $38,000 The law differed from formula (1.1) in sev ­ eral respects: 1. It granted matc h i n g state aid only up to a local levy of 22 mills in 1973-74. 2. Districts had the option of r e c e iving the amount of aid received in 1972-73 adjusted for changes in state equalized valuation per pupil. ^■"Matching aid" refers to aid w h i c h increases in amount as local tax rates are i n c r e a s e d . 2 This formula only applied to opera t i n g levies. Millages for retiring operating deficits are included in operating levies. A separate provision, Section 27 of the State School Aid Act, took effect in 1974, p r o v i d i n g for equalization of buil d i n g fund and d e b t r e t i r e m e n t millages conditional on a reduction in such local levies equal to the amount of aid. 9 3. Districts were guaranteed no decline in total aid for two years 4. use, following annexation or consolidation. Districts levying less than 20 mills could for purposes of computing aid, their actual millage plus two-thirds of the difference bet w e e n 20 mills and the actual millage. 5. There were no "recapture" provisions. Dis­ tricts above the key district w e a l t h did n o t make payments into the state school aid fund. For districts not falling under any of the above exceptions in 1973-74, M 73 1 formula (1.1) gives 38,000 (1.2) where W 73 Is state equalized valuation per pupil for 1973-74. For districts levying operating millages above the 22 mill limit, there was no m a t c h i n g aid but a per pupil block grant B 73 °f the amount B 73 = .022 (38,000 - W 7 3 ) (1.3) F or districts falling under the "grandfather clause" p r o t ecting districts from a decline in aid c o m ­ pared to the amount received in 1972-73 there was no matching aid and all aid was a block grant. B ?3 = m a x { [B?2 - .020 [B72 - r 72 (W?3 - W ? 2 )] (W73 - W 7 2 )J} 10 where r ? M7 3 = 0 2 was (1.4) operating tax rate in 1972-73. The annexation guarantee also had the effect of making all aid a block grant in cases in w h i c h the guar­ antee was operative because the amount of aid was the amount received prior to annexation regardless of the local millage rate. For districts levying less than 20 mills, there was a block grant independent of the millage rate and matching aid w h i c h increased as local levies were raised. M 73 b ? 3 3 W 73 38,000 + 2 W ? 1 = ^ 3 ^ 3 (38,000 - W ? 3 ) (1.5) The matc h i n g rates derived above w e r e modif i e d by the provision for municipal overbu r d e n aid. If total property tax rates in the district levied by any taxing agency, e x cluding school operating levies, exceeded 125 percent of the statewide average for such tax rates, the v aluation of the distr i c t for purposes of compu t i n g aid was reduced by the percent by wh i c h the tax rates exclud ­ ing school operating levies, the statewide average, t. t, exceeded 125 per c e n t of However, there was a limit on the total amount of m u n i cipal overbu r d e n aid disbursed by 11 the state so that the amounts received were some fraction t- 1,f 5 t j t y (1.6) 'J Then the sum of matching aid and local revenues was S + r W ? 3 , so the matc h i n g rate was S 73 38,000 - S + r W ?3 [l- t~ 1|-2 5 t ] W ?3 38,000 + 25t W73 = 1 " ------------ t_i 251---------------38,000 + i t 'J Therefore M increases as t increases. (1*7) The amount of municipal overburden aid per pupil was S 0 = j, r W 73 (1.8) S0 ,, Therefore * t-1.25t „ ♦ ------ 1 ------- 73 “ — U .9) 30r if a district SEV per pupil exceeded $38,000 but [1 _ t~ 1 v2. 5. t ] w?3 < 38,000 12 and the matching rate can be expressed as ^73 «73 - 1 ------ ST (1-10> 38,000 + ™ r For districts levying less the municipal overburden S = [r + ~ than 20 provision (. 020-r) ] (38,000 - mills the effect of was £l-(f> t~ 1 v2^ -] w ? 3 > = (f + ‘°3Q) (38,000 - [1—^• t ~ 1i 25^ ] W 73> (1.11) The m a t ching rate and the block grant were m 73 ^ (38,000 - l l ~ 4 > t" 1 *2 5 t l W } = __ _______________________ s_______ L ± _______ ~ 3 (38,000 - [1-$ t~ 1l 2-5 t 3 W--,} + rW_, t 73 7. s0 38,000 + - p + 2 W ?3 B73 = E38'000 + “ w 73l C o m paring equation (1.10) (1.12) for districts receiving municipal overburden aid and levying between 20 and 22 mills with equation (1.2) for other districts levying between 20 and 22 mills, and comparing equation (1.12) for districts receiving munic i p a l overburden aid and 13 levying less than 20 mills with equation districts levying less than 20 mills, (1.5) for other one sees that the municipal overburden provision effectively increased "key district wealth" by an amount S^/r. Note that S^/r is added to 38,000 in the denominators of the expressions for the matching rate in (1.10) and (1.12) and is also added to 38,000 in the bracketed factor in the expression for block grants in (1.12). The provisions for 1974-75 were similar except that the "key district wealth" was raised to $39,000, the maximum local levy subject to matching aid was raised to 25 mills, and there was no longer any protection from a decline in state aid from the amount received in 1972-73. The provision for districts levying less than 20 mills allowed the use of the sum of actual operating millage and o n e - third the difference between 20 mills and the actual millage. ing to (1.10) Thus, and the formulas for 1974-75 c o r r e s p o n d ­ (1.12), respectively, were W M 74 1 74 39,000 + M 74 0 r 3 W, 74 S 0 78,000 + 2 r 1 B 74 " T (1.13) S 1 + w 74 t39'000 + T T - W 7 4 ] 14 The effect of the 1974-75 school aid formula on the opportunity set of school districts is shown in Figure 1. Assume: 1. The school district has a state equalized value per pupil of $19,500. 2. All taxes district. 3. There is no federal or state aid other than member s h i p aid provided according to the aid formula. 4. Disposable income per pupil wo u l d be $5,000 if school taxes were zero. If there were are paid by residents of the no state aid provisions, the budget constraint wo u l d be the dashed line AB w i t h For each additional dollar of school spending, posable income w o u l d be reduced by one dollar. a slope of -1. local dis ­ A tax levy of 40 mills w o u l d be required to finance education expenditures of $780 per pupil. Under a simple percentage equalizing formula such as (1.1), the budget constraint w o u l d be the line AE wit h a slope e qual to t-t _ (1 - M) However, 19,500 _ 39,000 1 2 (1.15) the m a x i m u m of 25 mills subject to matc h i n g aid and the special provisions for districts levying less than 20 mills give the budget constraint shown by the solid line segments GCDJ. The endpoint of the bu d g e t constraint at G corresponds to the 10 mill m i n i m u m levy required to 15 Disposable Income Per Pupil 5800 5600 5400 5200 5078 5000 V I 4800 4600 4200 200 130 600 332 I 800 780 1000 975 1200 1400 Expenditures Per Pupil Figure 1.— Budget Constraints with State Aid. 16 receive the full amount provided by the state aid formula. The segment GC represents the constraint for the district if it falls under the special provisions for districts levying less than 20 mills. From (1.14), one sees that, for a district with SEV p er pupil of $19,500, „ _ M A B = *°^° 3 x 19,500 _ 2 78,000 + 19,500 ~ 5 (39,000 - 19,500) Thus, GC has a slope of - 3 = 130 (1.16) and the h o r i zontal distance AF equals the block grant of $130 per pupil. The segment DJ is the constraint if the district levies more than 25 mills. It is parallel to AB, w i t h the slope of -1 mea n i n g that each additional dollar of educational spending reduces disposable income of resi­ dents by one dollar. The block grant for a district with $19,500 SEV per pupil is B = .025 (39,000 - 19,500) - 487.50 (1.17) This is the h o r i zontal distance bet w e e n AB and DJ. Figure 1 also allows a comparison between the opportunity sets under percentage equalizing and under the old foundation plan. equal to A i d for 1972-73 was a block grant 17 '644 - .016 W if W > 17,750 715 - .020 W if W < 17,750 B = (1.18) Thus, a district w i t h $19,500 SEV per pupil w o u l d receive a block grant of $332. The budget constraint for such a district is shown as the line segment IK, w h i c h is p a r a l ­ lel to AB. The above equations were used to calculate the matching rate, M, used as a variable in the regression analysis in Chapter IV.^ Behavior Under Percentage Equalizing The percentage equalizing formula in antees that all districts (1.1) guar­ levying the same millage will receive the same per pupil revenues. But does school district behavior under such a formula truly achieve "equal educational opportunity"? Coons, Clune and Sugar- man recognized that it might n o t . . . . the socioeconomic characteristics of a d i s ­ trict count in its ability to translate attitude about education, what e v e r that may be, into The provisions of the 1973 school aid law dis­ cussed above are contained in Public Acts Numbers 101 and 160. State of Michigan, Legislative Service Bureau, Public and Local Acts of the Legislature of the State of Michigan Passed at the Regular Session of 1973, pp. 303313, 638-646. The provisions of the 1972 foundation aid plan are found in Public Act Number 258. Public and Local Acts of the Legislature of the State of Mich i g a n Passed at the Regular Session of 1972, p p . 644-66 8. 18 results at the ballot box; and the socioeconomic characteristics of a district condition its atti­ tude toward e d u c a t i o n . F eldstein restated the rule that "educational spending not be a function of local wealth" as the more precise n o r m "that the elasticity of local educational spending per pupil w i t h respect to the value of local taxable property per pupil be z e r o . " 2 He showed that power equalization does not in general satisfy this rule. Consider the expenditure equation linear in the logarithms , In E. = 8 a + 3 . I n W . + 3 . 0 1 r In P. + 2 i K J 6. In X.. + e. I1 i (1.19) where W is we a l t h per pupil, matching rate, P equals one minus the and the X^ are other variables. Feldstein defined the elasticity of spending with respect to wealth, , to be equal to “ l = ^1 + B2YP W + 1= 3 BjYX . W J (1.20) j where 'Y'xjw is the elasticity of X^ w i t h respect to W. Let K BW = B1 + 1 Coons, BjYX_.W Clune, and Sugarman, (1.21) p. 278. 2 M artin S. Feldstein, "Wealth Neutrality and Local Choice in Public Education," Ameri c a n Economic Review 65 (March 1 9 7 5 ) :77. 19 Then a price formula of the form pi = k W± Y PW (1.22) would achieve wealth neutrality = 0 ) 1 (in the sense that if -**w YPW fTJ (1.23) Percentage equali z i n g formulas, in the pure ver­ sion w i thout mini m u m and m a x i m u m limits on aid and other special provisions, Yp^ = 1. Thus, are of the form P^ = kW^, i.e., such formulas will be we a l t h neutralizing only in the special case Empirically, $ 2 = Feldstein took the value of esti ­ mated from In E. i 4 In P. = b rt + b. i 0 1 In W. x (1.24) To the extent that the Xj are' taste variables, Feldstein*s inclusion of K jl3 ;W in is a departure from the normative position of Coons, Clune and Sugarman that variation in expenditures accord­ ing to local tastes should be allowed. Feldstein has ruled out those variations in expenditures due to tastes which are correlated with wealth. An aid formula meeting Feldstein*s criteria w o u l d eliminate w h a t Grubb and Michelson call de facto correlations bet w e e n property value and e x p e n d i t u r e s , as opposed to de jure correlation which is only concerned w i t h property values as a direct argument of the choice function. Cf. W. Norton Grubb and Stephen Michelson, States and Schools (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1974), p. 173. 20 as an estimate of 3W - From his various estimates of 8 W, Feldstein calculated that with “price" proportional to wealth or = 1 , the elasticity of spending w i t h respect to wealth, a^, would be between -.630 and -.832. He con ­ cluded: . . . power equalizing grants w o u l d not neutral­ ize w ealth but could create a stronger (but nega­ tive) relation between we a l t h and spending than currently exists.^ The negative correlation bet w e e n we a l t h and expenditures per pupil under percentage equalizing was also found by Grubb and Michelson, but Gini coefficients measuring the inequality of expenditure levels increased in their simulation of a percentage equalizing formula. The correlation between expenditures and income levels in 2 the same simulation was reduced but remained positive. In contrast to Feldstein, Stern found: . . . power equalizing would produce a pattern of taxing and spending in which per-pupil expendi­ tures remained substantially higher, on average, in w e a lthier school districts. From the particular preference function Stern used, he derived a marginal rate of substitution of expenditures, g, for tax rate, t, ^"Feldstein, p. 2 3 8 6 . Grubb and Michelson, pp. 163-165. David Stern, "Effects of A l t e r native State Aid Formulas on the Distribution of Public School Expenditures in Massachusetts," Review of Economics and Statistics 55 (February 1 9 7 3 ) :91. 21 I ? = n at n Ut — a g (1.25) where n and u are taste parameters depen d i n g on d e m o ­ graphic variables, u reflecting homeownership and n reflecting socioeconomic status. Under percentage e q u a l ­ izing the budget constraint is g = kt. Equating the m a r ­ ginal rate of substitution to the slope of the budget constraint and substituting for g n ut - kt = k or t = — u + k Stern's estimates (1.26) led to the conclusion that percentage equalizing wo u l d reduce but not eliminate the disparities in per pupil expenditure associated w i t h property values but w o u l d increase the disparities associated w i t h socioeconomic status. 1 In criti c i s m of Stern's work, Feldste i n argued that the . . . price effect in Stern's analysis . . . is essentially imposed by the form of the function and not estimated from the s a m p l e . 2 Inman analyzed the effects of various school aid formulas in a general e q u i l i b r i u m framework allowing for relocation of family residence and move m e n t into or out of 1 2 Ibid., pp. 95-96. Feldstein, p. 85, n. 25. 22 private schools in response to public educa t i o n e x p e n d i ­ tures and taxes. He den o t e d the decisive voter's net taxes by Trrb, where i is a factor reflecting federal and state income tax credits and deductions, b is the indi­ vidual's taxable base and the tax rate is r = ^ ( 1 B - m) - z (1 + e) q with k(E) b e i n g costs per child for service level E; lump sum aid per child; m, on family income) value per child; aid the m a t c h i n g rate for E S E A Title I aid; 2 7 ) z, (which depends B, the assessed and e, the percentage rate of tax effort (presently applicable under revenue sharing to local income taxes). Thus, the marginal tax cost, assuming changes in E have a negligible effect on public school enrollment, is tt t where 0 (1 - m) b k' (E) (1 + e) + ------------------ B . db dE 7rr0 fl (1.28) is the percentage of the tax base that is indus­ trial or commercial p r o p e r t y . 1 Percentage equali z i n g guarantees each dist r i c t a per pupil base B . For a district in w h i c h B than the previous tax base, is greater the implementation of such an 1 Robert P. Inman, "Optimal Fiscal Reform of M e t r o ­ politan Schools: Some Simulation Results w i t h a General Equilibrium Model," October 1975. (Mimeographed.) 23 aid plan initially lowers x and thus increases the desired level of E. But, in response to this change, land values will rise as families migrate into the district. more, as r is reduced, Further­ housing consumption is stimulated. Thus b increases, w h i c h increases r, possibly undoing mu c h of the initial effect of the aid and returning expenditures to near the initial level. While the initial impact on x of a perce ntage equalizing plan is equalizing, the sec­ ondary impact of capitalization and investment on x will be unequalizing. Inman concluded from his simulation results: For our sample cities, these unequalizing longrun adjustments in fact dominate! . . . the e q u i l ibrium effects of a DPE plan in this economy with its strong capitalization effects is to spread rather than condense the distribution of school spending. Finally w e note that DPE and DPENC m u s t both attempt to control for drop-out in the EXIT ALL O W E D economy. This is accomplished by increasing B*. Drop-out only reduces further their ability to equalize educational s p e n d i n g . 1 Ibid., p. 43. "DPENC" refers to a dist r i c t per ­ centage equalizing plan wit h o u t "recapture." The long-run effects of an aid pro g r a m through the capitalization of tax advantages in property values will not be considered in the present study due to two problems, James M. Buchanan and Charles J. Goetz, "Effi­ ciency Limits of Fiscal Mobility: An A s s e s s m e n t of the Tiebout Model," Journal of Public Economics 1 (April 1972): 25-43, have questioned the use of a Tiebout model that ignores locational fixity in assuming all income is divi ­ dend income. Inman's specification of the equation for median home value does not provide an adequate means of dealing w i t h the pro b l e m of locational rents in a state­ wide sample nor are any solutions to the p r o b l e m readily apparent. Furthermore, in studying a recent change in the aid formula, there is a question of h o w rapidly tax adva n ­ tages will become capitalized in m a r k e t values and how quickly assessed values w i l l reflect changes in m a r k e t values. 24 The criterion Inman used to evaluate the degree of equalization was the Atkinson inequity measure, E/E. E is the average level of education services received by all children and P 1/y I E = where f=l (1.29) is the amount of education services received by each family, F is the number of families and the value of Y used was -. 5 .^ Even in the short run, w i t h no c a p i t alization or exit to private schools Inman found that, although a p e r ­ centage equalizing formula had an equalizing effect, there were foundation and "matching aid" proposals w h i c h domi2 nated it according to the equity criterion. Outline of the Following Chapters The pre s e n t study investigates the degree to whi c h the "percentage equalizing" aid formula in Mich i g a n has Inman, "Optimal Reform," pp. 33-34. The use of a measure of equality as a n o r m goes beyond the principle that expenditures per pupil be inde­ pendent of wealth to the egalitarian principle that expenditures per pupil be equal. Not surprisingly, Inman found that his notion of equality of opportunity is inco n ­ sistent w i t h local autonomy in d e t e r mining expenditure levels. Cf. ibid., pp. 43-44. 2 Ibid., p. 42, n. 35. Recall that Inman's "match­ ing rate" is a function of income, not assessed property values. 25 reduced inequality in per pupil expenditures and the effects on equalization of modifications of the current formula. Predicting responses to changes in the aid formula requires m easuring the effect of the variables determining the level of school expenditures. Chapter II surveys p r e ­ vious studies of the determinants of education exp e n d i ­ tures. Chapter III discusses problems associated with estimating an expenditure equation, and Chapter IV pre­ sents estimates of such an equation b a s e d on Mich i g a n data. Chapter V discusses changes in the distribution of actual per pupil expenditures bet w e e n 1972-73, year under the foundation plan, and 197 4-75, year under percentage equalizing. Also, the last the second the levels of state aid and total expenditures and the distribution of per pupil expenditures are predicted under the assumptions that the 25 mill max i m u m on levies subject to matching had been removed and that districts above the $39,000 guaran ­ teed tax base had been subject to a "recapture" provision. Chapter VI provides a summary and conclusion. CHA P T E R II REVIEW OF STUDIES OF THE DETERMINANTS OF EDUCATION EXPENDITURES Numerous empirical studies have been made of the determinants of educational expenditures and of local government expenditures in general. These studies have differed in the explanatory variables considered, the functional forms used, the theoretical assumptions about how expenditure levels are determined, the choice of dependent variable in the regression equation and the nature of the observations vidual districts, (state- or county-wide totals or indi­ cross-section or time series, etc.). M o s t of the studies reviewed here were considered by D e n z a u . 1 Denzau's survey used specifications from 13 empirical papers to estimate educational expenditure equ a ­ tions for a common set of observations, districts in 1969-70. Virginia school This common data base allowed com ­ parison of the performance of the various specifications. The following sections review the studies con­ sidered by Denzau along w i t h other related work. Rather ^Arthur T. Denzau, "An Empirical Survey of Studies on Public School S p e n d i n g , ” National Tax Journal 28 (June 1 9 7 5 ) :241-249. 26 27 than considering each study separately, we shall survey the field of studies w i t h respect to (1 ) the assumed the­ oretical basis for the determination of expenditure levels, (2 ) the choice of dependent variable used in regression analysis, tastes, (3) the various explanatory variables reflecting interest group influences and political institu­ tional factors, (4) "price” variables, reflecting ability to pay, and (5) variables (6 ) the specification of the functional forms estimated. Theoretical Basis of Expenditure Dete r m i n a t i o n The variety of assumptions regarding the the­ oretical basis for the determination of expenditure levels in empirical studies is remarkable in that, however much studies differ in their assumptions at this level, do not, for the most part, they test the assumptions. The approach used in the pres e n t w o r k is w h a t Miner^ calls a "political a p p r o a c h . " Politicians seeking voter support w i l l be led to make decisions according to the preferences of the med i a n voter. This occurs because, in a two-candidate election in w h i c h v o t e r s 1 preferences can be m e a s u r e d along a single dimension and citizens vote for the candidate w h o s e position is closest to their own ^Jerry Miner, Social and Economic Factors in Spending for Public Education (Syracuse, N 1Y .: Syracuse University Press, 1963), p. 6 6 . 28 preferred point, the candidate w h o takes a position clos ­ est to the median of the d i s t ribution of voters' ences will w i n a majority of the votes. prefer­ Citizen preferences about school expenditures are even more directly expressed in states where school boards must submit tax levies to a referendum. If the initial millage proposal is at least as high as that preferred b y the median voter, if each citizen votes against millages above his own preferred level and for millages that do not exceed this level, and if school boards incrementally decrease the pr oposed millage after any defeats, the median preferred millage will be adopted.^In a "political" model, then, the explanatory variables to be considered are those wh i c h influence the median voter's preferred point. Am o n g the studies reviewed, this approach was used by Davis, Barr and 2 Davis, and Ladd. However, Ladd explicitly disclaimed 3. Cf. Randall G. Holcombe, "Equilibrium in the Public Sector: Theoretical Models and Empirical Obs e r v a ­ tions," paper presented at the annual mee t i n g of the Pub­ lic Choice Society, Chicago, April 3-5, 1975. 2 Otto A. Davis, "Empirical Evidence of Political Influences upon the Expenditure Policies of Public Schools," in The Public Economy of Urban C o m m u n i t i e s , ed. Julius Margolis (Washington: Resources for the Future, 1965), pp. 92-111; James L. Barr a n d Otto A. Davis, "An Elementary Political and Economic Theory of the Expenditures of Local Governments," Southern Economic Journal 33 (October 1966): 149-165? Helen F. Ladd, "Local Public E x p e n ditures and the Composition of the Property Tax Base" (Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University, 1974), and "Local Educa t i o n E x p e n d i ­ tures, Fiscal Capacity, and the C o m p o s i t i o n of the Property Tax Base," National Tax Journal 28 (June 1975) :145-158. 29 her regression results as a test of the median voter model. *** In contrast, M i n e r followed w h a t he called an "economic approach" despite his recognition of its limita­ tions : Problems of ascertaining preferences and of giv­ ing equitable weights to divergent individual preferences w h e n known make it impossible for any government to achieve the goal of utility maximization. Still, m a x i m ization of the sum of individual utilities is the basis of an economic model of government behav i o r . . . . This study uses the economic m o d e l of g o v ­ ernment behavior bec a u s e public spend i n g p r i m a r ­ ily influences economic welfare, and a model based on economic rather than political p r i n c i ­ ples seems a p p r o p r i a t e . 2 A no t h e r approach, taken by Henderson, is to assume that elected officials maximize a "social welfare" func- 3 tion. Similarly, Stern assumed that . . . local school authorities will show some consistency in evalua t i n g different combinations of local tax rates and total expenditure w h e n the state aid formula changes. . . . it is possi ble to impute a preference function to the local school boards . . . . The general form of this preference function is f[g(L); t ¥ ■ <2-3) Hi, increases with income Y 1 < Y2 < Y 3 H, < H2 < H3 (2.4) Assume all three individuals have identical utility func­ tions, represented by the indifference curves drawn in Figure 2, However, each faces a different budget con­ straint, Y i = Yd + (2.5) where Yd is disposable income after school taxes. Thus, the b udget constraint is steeper for higher income levels because of the difference in price. The middle income voter prefers expenditure level E2 1 w h i c h is smaller, both in absolute size and as a share of personal income, than the expenditure levels and E^ preferred by the low and high income voters. B rown and Saks showed that using an expression involving median income alone results in biased estimates of the Engel curve. The bias is a function of median income, Y, and the Gini coefficient, G. Specifying the local revenue per family equation in the form 89 L = 0O + &iY + ^ 2 + , fr-GY* + 5 K I i= + y 2 6 3GY + B4G y 2 B.X. 6 1 f 2 .6 ) 1 they found the bias, measured by the terms involving GY, 2 3 GY , and GY to be statistically significant at the level. .05 The unbiased estimated Engel curve was U-shaped with a m i n i m u m at about $10,300 while the bia s e d curve was m o n o t onically decreasing.^The Effects of N o n - Matching Aid In addition to the private incomes of the resi­ dents of the district, another contribution to ability to pay comes from state and federal aid. A i d that is on a matching basis is considered in the price variable but aid that is independent of the level of local revenues must also be considered. A frequently discussed question with regard to such block grants or lump-sum aid is to what extent it stimulates expenditures for the aided function and to what e xtent it merely substitutes for locally financed expenditure. Match i n g aid w o u l d be expected to have a ^Brown and Saks, pp. 18, 23. 90 more stimulative effect because its effect on price has a i substitution as well as an income effect. If the dependent variable is total expenditure per pupil and aid per pupil is among the independent variables, a coefficient for the aid variable less than one indicates that part of the aid substitutes for locally financed expenditure. This is consistent w i t h Brazer's estimate 2 of this coefficient of .29 and Renshaw's estimate of .16. However, Renshaw's estimate increased to .38 w h e n mandated revenue required to participate in the aid p l a n was con­ sidered and to .51 w h e n income per school-age child, rather than per capita, was used in the equation.^ The results from L a d d ’s log linear specification gave a m a r g i n a l impact of non-matching state aid on total expenditures of about 50 cents for each dollar of aid. But Ladd included categorical state aid in a separate term w i t h federal aid and found this variable to have a marginal impact of about $1.10. was She argued this result "consistent w i t h the view that these grants are for "^Although the difference may be small for m a t c h ­ ing and n o n - m atching plans when both have very large grants. Cf. James A. Wilde, "The E x p e n diture Effects of Grant-in-Aid Programs," National Tax Journal 21 (September 1 9 6 8 ) :343. 2 Harvey E. Brazer, City Expenditures in the Un i t e d S t a t e s , Occasional Paper No” 6 6 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1959), pp. 54-55. 3 Renchaw, pp. 17 2-173. 91 specialized purposes on w h i c h local communities w o u l d have spent less than the allotted amount in the absence of aid. This is also consistent w i t h Denzau's results that " 1 the coefficient of federal aid is not significantly dif2 ferent from o n e . Feldstein also separated state block grants from a federal grants variable which included state grants for special programs. The elasticity of the former variable was usually much less than that of the federal grants variable, as expected. The ordinary least squares esti­ mate of the state grant elasticity based on 1970 data implied a marginal impact of about 60 cents for each dollar of aid. Felds t e i n argued this was biased upward because block grants were endogenous, going only to towns that passed the limit of m a t c h i n g aid in 1970. The 1965 equations (when all aid was a block grant under a founda ­ tion plan) showed an unbiased estimate not significantly different from zero but w i t h o u t significant change in the other coefficients. Felds t e i n reported, with o u t remark, that an instrumental variable estimation based on 1970 data treating state block grants as endogenous gave an expenditure elasticity with respect to state grants 1 Ladd, 2 "Education Expenditures," p. Denzau, "Survey," p. 2 47. 150. 92 of .127 compared to that with respect to federal grants of .124.1 Stern expressed total educational resources avail­ able per pupil as g = c ^ + qc2 (2.7) where c^I» is the sum of local revenues and matching grants, L being local revenues, and the local share of local plus matc h i n g amount of block grants is c 2 parameter to be estimated reflecting the reciprocal of revenues. The and the coefficient q is a a discount factor school boards apply to block grants because such aid is not a perfect substitute for local revenue or matching aid. One r eason for this lack of substitutability is that such grants are often categorical, w i t h restrictions on their use w hich may make them less valuable according to local preferences than unrestricted moneys. Ano t h e r reason is the uncertainty about the size of block grants w h e n school budgets are made. which, The estimated value of q was for Stern's specification, .601, implied a reduction in ^"Feldstein, pp. 81-84, nn. 11, 12, 18. Barro, Theoretical M o d e l s , pp. 58-61, shows that whether categorical or unrestricted lump-sum aid has the larger m a r ginal impact on total education expenditures depends on whether expenditures for functions receiving categorical aid and other expenditures are complements or substitutes. When they are complements, theory p r e ­ dicts that categorical aid has the larger marg i n a l impact on total expenditures. 93 locally financed expenditure of about 45 to 55 cents in most districts. Since the smaller the value of q, the less block grants reduce locally financed expenditure, Stern argued: . . . the uncertainty and limited substituta­ bility of block grants, as measured by the esti­ mate of q, could conceivably offset the greater incentive of matching grants for some school d i s ­ tricts. . . . the important implication for policy is that the recipients of aid are sensi­ tive to the way grants are appropriated and administered. Because theoretical models have ignored such institutional complications, they may predict behavior i n c o r r e c t l y . 1 The dy namic mo d e l discussed in the next chapter addresses the issue of uncertainty and the separation of categorical from general block grants as was done by Feldstein and by Ladd addresses the effect of restrictions tied to categorical aid. Thus, we avoid the problem implicit in Stern's discussion, that institutional changes would affect the value of q and require re-estimation of its value before Stern's model could be used for pr e d i c ­ tive purposes. Comparison of the Effect of Block Grants and Pisposable Income Stern's model was based on a school board p r e f e r ­ ence function, not on the preferences of the median voter. Use of such a model has implications for the specification 1S t e r n , p . 9 4. 94 of the aid term in the expenditure equation. Inman also used a leadership preference function approach and had hypothesized that community income and exogenous grants should be combined in one variable. However, he found that an increase in exogenous aid w e n t entirely into expenditure increases whereas the marg i n a l propensity to consume public services out of income was about .04. explanation of this unexpected result, Inman argued: One hypothesis to account for this pattern argues that additional exogenous grants enter the budget constraint with "prior claims" for their a l l o c ation— claims that are distinct from those expressed through the usual budget channels for tax and debt funds. For example, much of the exogenous aid for cities w i t h responsibility for education comes via closed-ended educational matching grants or foundation (per pupil) assist­ ance . It is easy to imagine the educational sys­ tem m aking a strong claim to these outside funds as "supplemental money for education." Given the likely bargaining power of this bureaucracy in the city budgeting process such a claim may be hard to deny. If this is, in fact, the case our previous arguments that service-specific exoge­ nous aid would lead to an equivalent release of tax dollars from that s e r v i c e 's budget for allo­ cation as general revenue will not be observed. The argument here says cities treat exogenous aid as supplemental or transitory to their usual tax and debt r e v e n u e s , and as such there may be quite d ifferent allocative pressures w h i c h come to bear on its disbursement. Patronage (as in the case of sanitation or parks and r e c r e a t i o n ) , charity (as w ith w e l f a r e ) , the constitutional structure of the political process, or perhaps even the name of the aid program may all be possible special d e t e r ­ minants of the [exogenous aid] a l l o c a t i o n . 1 Elsewhere Inman argued: i Inmaii, "Econometric Model," pp. 711-713. In 95 The differences in the impact of [exogenous aid per capita] and private income on [taxes per capita] is a small bit of evidence in favor of the leadership-bureaucracy m o d e l as opposed to the median voter model. Bradford and Oates (1971) have shown that the me d i a n voter m o d e l predicts that a dollar increase in income to the median voter should have the same budgetary impact as a dollar increase in exogenous aid.i In fact, Bradford and Oates did not reach such a conclusion but rather found that . . . for the simple models . . . the gift to a member, which is identical in effect to the gift to the club, is equal to his tax share times the total amount of the gift to the c l u b . 2 Intuitively, lows: this result can be explained as fol­ A grant-in-aid to the local government is e q u i v a ­ lent to the potential increase in the individual's private disposable income that would be achieved if all of the grant w e r e used to reduce local taxes. If the reduction in tax rates must be uni f o r m over all taxpayers, and non-resident alike, resident the individual's share in such potential tax reduction will not be the amount of per capita aid but the total aid times his tax share. Mathematically, the individual voter's preferred level of educational services per pupil w i l l be determi n e d by m a x i m i zing U(Y-i< io~B 46.5 (169.4) 12.3 (167.2) 560.9** (59.6) t - -.813 559.6** (60.4) 566.3** (60.6) 658** (75) *7 462** (67) c 675** (140) 205 (114) 0 251* (115) 182 (102) C * D 328" (117) 266* (117) 100.5 (117.3) I • D 163* (72) 170* (72) -50.4 (70.1) H 353" (81) 97.2 (64.4) 411.9" (63.2) 27 8 " (721 259" (75) -355" (75) -462.2" (84.5) -109B" (185) -1114** (185) -1106** (187) -1123** (187) -2103" (338) -1758" (337) -1727** (345) -1824** (344) -1704" (351) -2106** (449) -1014* (331) -384 (391) -345 (393) -348 (398) -339 (400) -356 (445) -237 (371) MI -997** (255) 311.4* (12B.3) 411.9** (63.2) MC -1461** (375) -205 (114) -311.4* (126.3) MO -4B2 (386) -1B2 (102) -411.9** (63.2) CMC -583 (421) -266* (117) -100.5 (117.3) EMI -175 (324) -170* (72) 50.4 (70.1) 822** (12B) 801** ' (130) 867" (129) 805** (132) 98 4" (144) 401" (125) 194 1116) 1B9 (116) 203 (118) 188 (119) 154 (127) 107 (130) 265.5** (73.2) 241.7** (75.3) Change in debt retire­ ment revenues, WAm ^ 304" (87) “7 1B2* (69) « T -906** (104) .000330** (.000116) R2 .7850 .7498 .6732 .7670 .7708 .7556 .7609 .7204 R2 .7674 .7355 .6574 .7509 .7520 .7402 .742B .7010 7.0147" 42.7720" P statistic to test restriction described in text 1.417 NOTE: Observations weighted by J ? , F being the number of families in the district. tures per pupil. Standard errors are in parentheses below coefficients. •Significant at .05 level. "Significant at .005 level. tlnstrmental variables estimation with M, HI, MC and HO endogenous. 1.6899 The dependent variable is operating expendi­ H to -4 128 per family enter the utility function, over P e t e r s o n ’s, in w h i c h expenditure per pupil is the argument of the preference function. Equations (1) and (4)-(7) show the results when no restrictions are imposed on the coefficients of the terms in the price variable. Equation (1) includes inter­ action terms with D, a dummy variable for districts in metropolitan areas, multiplied by C, I, MC and MI to allow for Ladd's hypothesis that perceived tax shifting may differ inside and outside metropolitan areas. The results show all terms in the price variable have the correct sign, and Ladd's result that commercial property stimulates expenditure more than industrial is c o n f i r m e d .-1- The interaction terms between D and C and I are p o s itive and significant at the .025 level or better, indicating voters in metropolitan areas perceive less threat of tax shifting through commercial businesses raising prices and industrial firms lowering wages or leaving the community. But the results contradict the theoretical expec­ tation that the coefficients of I and C should be less than or equal to the coefficient of M. The stimulus of non- residential property is apparently greater, less, than the stimulus of matching aid. rather than Furthermore, 1The proportion of commercial property has not been corrected to exclude apartments as Ladd did. the 129 restrictions that the coefficients of block aid m u l t i ­ plied by the terms in the price variable should be of equal m a g n itude and that the coefficients of I and MI, C and CM, O and OM, DI and DMI, and DC and DMC should be of equal m a g n itude and opposite sign is rejected at the .0005 level of significance with an F statistic of 7.0147, as shown in equation (2). However, for any district with much non-residential property the large coefficients of the MI and MC terms so dominate the coefficient of M that the effect of an increase in M is to reduce expenditures. One possible source of downward bias in estimating the coefficient of M is the simultaneous equations p r o b ­ lem w i t h the matching rate, w h i c h was noted in Chapter III. Because of the discontinuous non-linear relationship between the level of expenditures and the matching rate, two-stage least squares is not a theoretically appropriate solution to this problem. Nevertheless, an attempt was made to use an instrumental variables procedure. equation But (8 ) shows little change in the relative m a g n i ­ tudes of the coefficients of the price terms w h e n this procedure is used. A second possible reason for the low estimated coefficient of M is that voters are not aware of the m a t c h ­ ing provisions in the recently enacted state aid formula, and thus it does not yet stimulate higher expenditures. The survey of school superintendents inquired as to whether 130 the m a t ching provisions of the aid formula had been pub l i ­ cized in millage campaigns. This was merely a yes or no question and thus has the weakness of not measu r i n g the intensity w i t h which the matc h i n g provision was publicized. To incorporate the possible influence of such publicity on the effect of the matc h i n g rate on expenditures, regressions (not shown) some included an interaction term between the matching rate and a dummy variable having a value of one if the superintendent reported matching p r o v i ­ sions were publicized in the millage campaign and zero otherwise. The correlation between this interaction v a r i ­ able and the matching rate was .82205, indicating that superintendents in m o s t districts favored by the matching formula replied that they did publicize it in the campaign. This high degree of multicollinearity resulted in either the m a t ching rate or the interaction term being insignif i ­ cant in the regressions in w h i c h the latter was included. Thus there is no conclusive evidence that lack of infor­ mation o n the part of voters explains the small coeffi­ cient of M in the regression results. In addition to the restrictions imposed in equa­ tion (2), equation (3) constrains the effect of non- residential property in m e t r opolitan areas to be equal to that of the matching rate. The hypothesis that these restrictions hold is rejected w i t h an F statistic of 44.7720. Imposing the constraint makes the interaction 131 terms w i t h C and I and the m e t r o p o l i t a n area dummy insig­ nificant. Alth o u g h these restrictions are rejected by the P test, because of the implausible implications of the unrestricted regressions the parameter estimates of equation (3) are used in Chapter V to predict the effects of changes in the aid formula. The input price variable, Pi, is a measure of average teacher salary in the district adjusted for ed u c a ­ tion and experience, w i t h the weights of education and experience determined by the statewide average salary increments for these characteristics. Pi is not included in the "price" terms in the regression analysis as it was in the theoretical derivation. theoretical formulation, While deviating from the this allows a separate analysis of the effect of this variable. The positive coefficient on this variable in the expenditure equation indicates a price inelastic demand for educa t i o n inputs. Effects of Non-Matching Aid and Municipal Overburden The categorical aid variable includes all federal aid plus state grants for transportation, vocational ed u ­ cation, special education, pregnancy programs, tory e d u cation and reading programs. compensa­ The estimates of the coefficient equal or are greater than one, agreeing wit h other s t u d i e s ’ findings that categorical aids do not result in a decrease in locally financed expenditure. 132 As theoretically derived in Chapter XX, the income effect of non-categorical lump-sum aid is represented by the variable PB, block grants multip l i e d by the variable. "price" With block grants per family equal to B and the price P = - M) ( 1 R* = - M) ( 1 ( 1 - etc - BI - 5T) (4.1) if perceived shifting of non-residential taxes is to be allowed, then PB = B(l-m) ^ - ctB(l-M)C - 3B(1-M)I ~ - 6B(1-M)T ^ (4.2) Note that the block grant terms should include the facPu tor -p- regardless of whether or not the "price" variable includes this factor because in either case the income effect depends on block grants per family. Thus the regression analysis should include the four variables B(l-M) ^r, B(1 - M ) T B(1-M)C and Dq B( 1 -M)I -=- w i t h no restrictions on the coefficients of £ these four terms. ters a, and 3 B (1-M) T ~ , r 6 If the p e r c e i v e d tax incidence p a r a m e ­ are less than one, B (1-M) C ^ r and B(1-M)I the coefficients of £ should be negative and smaller in magnitude than the coefficient of p„ B(1-M) -~=. These equations are contradicted b y the results shown in equa t i o n (1 ). 133 In examining the impact of non-categorical block grants, attention is focused on equations (2) and because the unrestricted estimates in equation lead to the implausible conclusion that, with m u c h non-residential property, grants reduce expenditures. (3) (1 ) in districts increases in block Non-categorical block grants multiplied by the price variable w o u l d have a coefficient equal to the coefficient of income if the political process perfectly represented voter demands and such unrestricted aid were equivalent to increases in personal income. Expressing Y in terms of 1969 nominal income while other money variables are in nominal quantities for 1974 should, if anything, coefficient of Y. in equation of Y. give an upward bias in the pn The coefficient of B{l-M) r (1-T-C-I) (3) is clearly not equal to the coefficient A l though such non-categorical aid apparently results in some reductions in local school taxes, its stimulus to expenditure is greater than that of increases in personal income, indicating that education interests exert a c laim on such aid that results in a greater increase in school expenditures than local voters desire. To measure the effect of municipal overburden it would be desirable to consider only non-school local government expenditures w h i c h provide benefits for or which are imposed by persons outside the local govern­ ment unit. However, this b r e a k d o w n is not available. 134 When non-school local government revenue per family was included in a regression equation similar to equation (not shown) specified (1 ), its coefficient was positive and significant at the .0005 level. This crude test supports other s t u d i e s 1 finding that "municipal o v e r ­ burden" does not reduce education expenditures. Effects of Income and the D istribution of Income M edian family income and state equalized value of residential property nent income) (which is taken to reflect p e r m a ­ have the expected positive coefficients in all equations, both being significant at the in equation (3). .0005 level Evaluated at the sample means the p a r ­ tial elasticity of expenditures is median family income and .2958 with respect to .0650 with respect to residen­ tial p r o perty value per family. Follo w i n g Ladd's assumption that one percent differences in residential w ealth are associated with one percent differences in income^" gives a total expenditure elasticity w i t h respect to income of .3508. B ut do the effects of the d i s t r ibution of income make the use of only the me d i a n income variable inappro­ priate? Equation (4) specifies expenditures per pupil as a quadratic function of median income. Equation tests for bias resulting from omitting other ^Ladd, "Public Expenditures," p. 110. (5) 135 characteristics of the income distribution by including GY, GY 2 , GY 3 and Sk (skewness) as regressors. The F statistic to test for the significance of these addi­ tional regressors is 1.417, w h i c h is insignificant at the 10 percent level. To eliminate any possible effects of the occupation variables on the validity of this test, equations (6 ) and (7) omit Pf and Mg from the regressors. 2 The F statistic to test for the significance of GY, GY , 3 GY and Sk in equation (7) is 1.8899, still insignificant at the 10 percent level. The discrepancy with the Brown and Saks results may be attributed to the fact that this specification is in per pupil rather than per family terms and includes total expenditures rather than only local revenues in the dependent variable. Effects of Other Variables D Public school pupils per family, m is included in the e x penditure equation to capture the price effect and possible per child income effects of the number of public school pupils per family. The negative and sig­ nificant coefficient found in all regressions conforms to theoretical expectations. The fraction of families with children, Fc, intended to represent an interest group favorable to education expenditures, is found to have a significant negative coefficient contrary to theoretical expectations. Perhaps this variable reflects some of the 136 same price and income effects as In Pu The variable (Pu), to reflect the varying political power of edu­ cation interest groups in different size districts, is found to have an insignificant coefficient of varying sign. Contrary to other studies, the coefficient of the fraction of students in high school is insignificant and negative. The fraction of school children in private schools has an insignificant coefficient in all equations but has the expected negative effect except in the con­ strained equation (3) of Table 3. Data on migra t i o n in and out of school districts are not available but a related variable, the fraction of persons living in the same house for five years, has a significant positive coefficient in all equations. The taste for education of persons in professional and technical occupations is reflected by the significant positive coefficient of Pf. The coefficient of the fraction of the labor force in salaried and self-employed managerial positions is insignificant and of varying sign. The fraction of Blacks in the population has a negative effect on school expenditures b u t is statis­ tically significant only w h e n the occupation variables are excluded or when an instrumental variables estima­ tion is u s e d . 137 Estimates of the Distributed Lag Response Equations (1) — (3) in Table 4 incorporate the lag structure developed in Chapter III. All three equations show there may be a significant lag in responding to changes in the aid formula. least squares estimates, Equation and equation (1) shows ordinary (2 ) shows estimates imposing the constraint derived from the theoretical development that the coefficients of B and should be equal. tion is 3.1623, The F statistic for testing this res t r i c ­ indicating that the hypothesis that the restriction holds is rejected at the nificance. (r_2 W)/(l-M) .076 level of sig ­ The estimate of the lag parameter in equation (2) indicates that only 49 per c e n t of the gap between desired and actual mil l a g e rates is eliminated w i t h i n two years. The instrumental variables estimate indicates an even longer lag, but the standard error of the estimated lag parameter is large. The coefficient of —yVL in these regressions shows a significant negative impact of increases in number of pupils on per pupil expenditures. may have this effect because, SEV per pupil, Changes in enrollment in addition to changing they affect pupil-teacher ratios if there is a delay in changing the number of staff in response to enrollment changes. The W - • AMbd term is included to estimate the effect of changes in building and debt retire m e n t millages TABLE 4.— Other Regression Results. Constant Pu Pupils per family, — F tl) (2) <3) + 285* (106) 260* (106) -88.7 -33.2 (30.2) -7.93 (26.70) 11.9 (89.9) (4) (5) (6)++ (7) 520“ (84) 171.4* (74.7) 463.9** (74.8) 364.2“ (75.1) -242.4** (31.8) -494.6** (52.4) -534.0“ (52.1) -406.5** (57.8) Block Grant Terms .140* (.056) .115 (.374) .529** . (.081) .5827** (.0944) .6316** (.0948) .407** (.105) B(1-H)T — F -.159 (.291) -.182 (.292) -.105 (.463) -1.345“ (.255) -1.170** (-235) . -1.252** (.236) -1.146** (.280) Bd-DC a -.906** (.253) -.982** (.250) -1.04 (.69) -1.152** (.236) -1.025“ (.259) -1.022** (.260) -.656* (.302) BI1-HII ^ t -.341* (.134) -.352* (.134) .474 (1.306) -.894** (.135) -1.212“ (.172) -1.250“ (.173) -1.126** (.201) Site of school district, In Pu 11.5 (6.0) 12.7 (6.8) 6.32 (13.00) -22.35“ (5.50) -11.4* (5.6) -8.90 (5.65) -21.04“ (6.35) Fraction in high school. Ks -60.2 (167.0) 26.9 (166.4) 214 (530) 218.4* (99.7) 179 (103) 199 (103) 23.1 (119.6) Adjusted Teacher salary, pi .00815 (.00673) .00612 (.00665) .0102 (.0098) ,0237** (.0064) .0245** (.0066) .0273** (.0066) .0284“ (.0074) Categorical aid, Ca 1.018* (.086) .994** (.085) .869** (.247) 1.445** (.088) 1.437** (.092) 1.360** (.092) 1.411** (.100) Fraction of families with children, Fc -485** (110) -491** (110) -299 (318) 22.4 (71.0) -89.6 (73.4) -91.9 (73.8) -73.3 (82.0) -13 (991 -209“ (51) -172.7** (52.1) -177.6** (52.4) -141.5* (55.9) 459** (81) 458** (81) 407** 199) — ■ Fraction of students in private schools, Pr -13.0 (71.3) -18.1 (71.3) Professional fraction of labor force, Pf 215 (123) 218 (123) -71.7 (491.4) Managerial fraction of labor force, Mg -261 (201) -256 (202) -504 (518) 423** (79) -190 (130) Sales, clerical fraction of labor force, SI 209“ (102) Farm fraction of labor force. Fa Black fraction of population, B1 -2B.9 (72.0) -14.2 (71.8) 138 (301) -329* (135) -395** (1351 -520“ (154) 34.6 (105.9) 151 (106) * -27 (114) 291* (111) 274* till) 136 (115) 138 .256** (.0B6) Bll-K) Fraction in same residence, Rs 114 (65) 126 (663 47.0 (190.4) Metropolitan area, □ i Residential wealth. Hr 20.5* (B.5) 27.1** (8.9) .00937** (.00148) .009997** (.001627) .0101** (.0016) .00716** (.00175) .01429** (.00221) .0143** (.0022) .0199** (.0027) .0202** (.0039) .0207** (.0039) .0118 (.0129) .01717** (.00212) "Price 'Perms," 1 2oa** (49) 224** (48) -209 (666) 616** (561 C 510** (94) 520** (94) 532 (370) 969** (104) T 38 (87) 61 (86) 7.82 (160.94) 763** (100) M 170** (54) 177** (54) 156 (163) -511** (140) -519** (140) HC -1052** (251) KT 304 (290) HI Block grants per pupil, B 611.8** (63.1) 661.2** (63.3) 531.7** (69.8) S Ti 695.6** (94.8) 762.2** (95.2) 552.1** (99.6) PU F 595.3** (78.7) 613** (79) 573.5** (94.8) 532** (83) u zn " F 454.7** (72.3) 493.7** (72.7) 340.7** (75.2) 1456 (2844) -826** (201) Ml f -1037** (252) -1980** (429) -1708** (343) -264 (291) 868 (940) -1300** (280) .356** (.093) .5139** (.0325) .774 (.776) Membership revenues with r_2 W lagged tax rate, --- — .514** (.032) .5139** (.0325) .920 (.706) Change in debt retirement revenues, W A M ^ .000458** (.000080) .000462** (.000080) .000516** (.000168) Rate of growth in number of students, APu/Pu 279** (84) 5.2 (9.8) -285** (64) I 1 F f f MI — F -764** (181) -819** (182) -652** (180) -1302** (304) -1350** (305) -895** (296) -975** (233) -1026** (234) -928** (239) -229 (IB?) R2 .8756 .8745 .6985 .6794 .711B ■6B52 S2 .8659 .8650 .6859 .6655 .6993 -664B 602 602 602 412 F statistic to test restric­ tion described in text Number of observations, H 3.1623 371 371 371 NOTE: Equations (l)-(3) use operating expenditures per pupil in 1974-75 as the dependent variable; equations (4)-{7) use per pupil expenditures for 1972-73 and 1973-74. Standard errors are shewn in parentheses. •Significant at .05 level. ••Significant at .005 level. tlnstrumental variables with M, Ml, HC, MO, (r_;W)/U-K) endogenous. tt(E-Etr), operating expenditures less transportation costs, used as dependent variable. 139 Median income, Y 28.B** (8.9) on operating expenses. Section 27 of the State School Aid A c t provided "equalizing" aid to districts reducing their b u i lding and debt millages in 1974. tion of equations The specific a ­ (1)— {3) in Table 4 does not explicitly model the incentives offered by Section 27. Rather, the equations include the change in per pupil building and debt revenues as a determinant of operating expenditures w i thout regard to whether Section 27 induced these changes or o ther factors were involved. Contrary to the expect a ­ tion that reductions in building and debt millage would allow increases in operating expenses, the estimated coefficient of this variable is positive and statistically significant at the .0005 level in all three equations. Since surveys of districts participating in the Section 27 aid p r o g r a m indicate it has had a positive effect on o perating millage election r e s u l t s , 1 apparently other factors associated w i t h increases in building and debt retirement millages w e r e also associated w i t h increases in operating expenses. Comparison With Estimates Based on Earlier Years Equations (4)-(7) in Table 4 show the results of regressions on pooled cross-section time series data for ^State of Michigan, Governor's Advisory Task Force o n Property Tax Revision, S u m m a r y ; Interim Report to the G o vernor (July 1976), p. 53. 141 1972-73, the last year under the foundation aid formula, and 1973-74, the first year under percentage equalizing. Qualitatively, the m o s t notable differences from the results in Table 3 are the larger coefficient of the fraction of timber and utility property in the tax base, T; the significant negative effect of the district size variable, In (Pu) ; the positive coefficient of Hs, the fraction of pupils in high school; negative effect of Pr, and the significant the fraction in private schools. That the last variable has the expected interest group effect in the 1972-74 sample but not in 1974-75 may reflect the fact that it is based on 1970 census data and thus would more accurately describe districts in 1972 than in 1974. Fa, the fraction of the labor force w h o are farmers or farm laborers, is not included in the re g r e s ­ sions for 1974-75 but is shown in Table 4 to have a significant positive effect on expenditures. A comparison of equation (6 ) with equation (5) agrees with Denzau's finding that opera t i n g expenditures less transportation costs as the dependent variable gives a better fit than total operating expenditures per pupil. The higher w i t h expenditures excluding transportation was also found in other regressions not shown here. i The regression shown in equation (7) attempts to avoid the simultaneity problem with the m a t c h i n g rate by excluding "out-of-formula" districts (levying m o r e than 142 22 mills) from the sample. Alth o u g h the m a t c h i n g rate is an exogenous variable for districts in this sample, the estimated coefficient of the m a t c h i n g rate term is still smaller than the coefficients of the non-residential shares of the tax base. C onclusion The regression results presented here lead to the rejection of the hypotheses that match i n g aid has a greater price effect than non-residential property and that the voter's share of block grants has an effect on school spending equivalent to that of private income. Theoretical considerations lead to the choice of equation (3) in Table 3 to predict the consequences of changes in the aid formula. These predicted consequences are d i s c ussed in the next chapter. CHA P T E R V THE DEGREE OF INEQUALITY IN A C T U A L E X P E N D I ­ TURES A N D IN PREDICTED EXPENDITURES U N D E R A L T E RNATIVE A I D FORMULAS This chapter discusses to w h a t degree the change to a percentage equalizing formula has reduced the degree of inequality in per pupil education expenditures in M i c higan and predicts the effects on the distribution of expenditures of modifications in the existing formula. The analysis assumes equality of per pupil expenditures within school districts. Inequality at this level m a y be an important obstacle to equal opportunity but is beyond the scope of this study. The Distributio n of Actual Expenditures Consider first the distribution of actual per pupil expenditures in 1972-73 under the foundation aid plan and in 1974-75 under percentage equalizing. To maintain comparability w i t h later analysis of predicted expenditures under modifications of the aid formula, only the 371 K-12 districts for which all data are a v a i l ­ able are considered. These districts had 81.7 percent of the public school member s h i p and spent 82.9 percent 143 144 of the total public school operating expenditures in the state during 1974-75. Table 5 shows that for these 371 districts the Gini coeff icient for the d i s t r i b u t i o n of operating expenditures was .089989 in 1972-73 and .086988 in 1974- 75, indicating a slight reduction in the degree of inequality of education spending under the "percentage equalizing" formula. TABLE 5.— Actual Expenditures in 1972-73 and 1974-75. Total Operating Expenditures* . . Toiidi . .. HerabershiP Gini Coefficient for the Distribution of Ejtpenditures Sample 371 districts in 1972-73 $1,733,300 1,792,528 .089989 Sample 371 districts in 1974-75 2,112,025 1,745,927 .086988 All 602 districts in 1972-73 2,085,335 2,193,270 All 590 districts in 1974-75 2,548,499 2,135,867 *In thousands of dollars. Measures of the Dist r i b u t i o n of Predicted Spending The first row of Table 6 shows m e a s u r e s of inequality in the distribution of predicted expenditures for the 371 school districts in the sample under the TABLE 6.— Distribution of Predicted Expenditures for 371 Districts. -it U *0 5 & 0H Under Michigan law 0J Atkinson Inequity Measure +) c 0 •H U *H o “H rl P -H PM t G H Q) to 8 & u C -H o ■P c 3 to PM •H f-l G Q *H P ID u tnp« U Pw 3 0) M i PM O A to ■P u tp *H 6 P O +1 U 0) G •H -rl H GQ •P c 0 Oi (tJ 1 G -H 0 -H TJ TJ P 0) 3 OE o