i... 5555:1555“ 152155 .55? .5» v' V #32}! R11. “’55"?- "‘VVV'F 7’3"; "if“? 196?? (“V-EV ,_ :3“, . . (5V? 5'. .... J"'I 0.54 C ii. I‘Vl ”i VV.T." Qrgx. 3“; UdizlldOQ’ 'rr ix. V 6‘06 '5? I'llgx": :2, Q’E". . V "-5" 1.0-2.5'5-f .“1'3 ,5,(§»~.,-.~1‘~. J‘VLL '33‘3‘O'a‘lr§:}’.0 tl'fi" H. 00" fixvuwii =5- ";aW-H'UMV‘V‘ 35";2’ Vi} 5-352 13;.»33» 5,5595%. "5:51;:1..»“‘- 2"'5'; 312‘ {3.3; . .. f :25»... 55:5" VI ..?5‘.{yq {§x:5‘f ”'1 ”.'Jg-E‘ .y PIE; ff¢.,,’21 ”:11???" £3 i.‘.:1.'.)i ' ").'.-V '.' '1' O . go “‘o ' “15;"... " 0 ’. . ”If”? 51-13%}{V " 3%.!" y: 5.515‘Vr-v' ’-. )V.‘ a; ' ‘ " " ‘-"l_o‘ [La V‘V’LVrz’V ’3 V,“ l. g _!">‘" 1.{1 3. “A I I .V'V'fdl-V '5}: . '5 r-.¢?»" ‘- u . y“ ‘I b o o - a - Q ,MMMfi ‘o O Y ( . cling; V‘E.‘ V' 'l‘6K‘f: r‘: ”3:3;623. '5', .\..-“o :ngJ 2i.“ 'l{=: I' .5 ';>VV V‘ V 5 5.5.5:? 55,... 5'55”. «51w: 5 5'55..5.555.555. ~ -‘5 TI ‘éig'! 5 v 3" 1‘ _ o ‘ 5 :¢‘~I. O ,A_‘ '0 2:; ‘fLKT‘V" . .. 5-5. ’ 25 .: - ‘ O ‘0 V ‘ . 3:13.21: ’95 I"! v. ."1 #bV1‘?V’>V’:C) V 3" VIN. Y?!“ I “ ‘”Po . ‘04] ' z: tat: . if if 3% U Otiji“j‘ if; V a. I. ‘l‘ffiw‘ fi:‘5‘ , Vl::7;‘ . r I I 155‘o555r on“ ‘ ‘ ‘3 5,} " ’V ‘. , 5! .. “at; ”5'. flu]? 9.2“. $55,::-- 'V‘ W0 153-: .‘ 3., .'J .- ‘ 0“ ’ "-"1'35’ rVV$.';?_"m-Fcf- ‘ " ”‘95" EVE“? 35’, 1' I, 54.5 V- 15. 3-,». ,,- Hkbw‘l'? \‘éfid {39 mV—VVV} 7%,} 5&4?- 155V NV‘VVVJVVVNX 55:; 6V? '5. V;Q $2?” "5"“; “‘5‘: : w" .4 , 551553.515 «‘5 55 “5% .1, fiM’ #51? 3. ;.—.r,§ b .5' figfifivufis i; V V; (V. “VJ 55%.;{V1imfiht w- '3: :t7’: 0::r éggffl'lv’ ‘ a . , x 3‘11?“ ’2 ,4: V551. i. *4 {:53 ..,, V 5* {33‘25 {55ng 6‘}, w" O I’ 5 5 “3" 'V-V'i“ "V V 55- : Rd}? A}! {r If); 1’3}.- . 7r 2’ {15‘ #ng' 1. ~ -- '1 ' .0 p 2‘ ‘- '1. V VVVV a V EH 1 VV 5.: 5. $362,} '2‘; ¢~V o" 7:?1} ' ‘5 N - 1}, n V 7"“?13”? i'. ,1 5 'Q’I'V' I I“. '3. : 34V. :5 '2 "3'35. It} I" ' 1:. é; V 'H’ V “V? ' r'. ("-01 s“ f_ 5.0.2", }-",V f“? ' {$35 . :{Vy VVSjV'. 3:55} 1 V,‘: L, '{93 f5}, .rzvgtwgég: '31,}, ,‘ . ,. ,5 *‘M% %&:.'-i f“ I, i, I"! _ ‘5 . o v 5 WWFQK'RQH .’V‘éa a: ‘fofi ‘j‘ngkr’WVEWéX' {3! . ‘, .. v . . 2 s' 5 V W .5'315435135151"; ’3" 55555535.. ""3; . V V f l' I I' 'h V .V '5' . 5 $1155" 5"~’}m= "3.5 55")?“5:51’15'.H5.'»:.1M'-4“‘5 a. m ”555/, H V' ' " ' - ' 'f' ’M'!‘ '5" " , 5o. .VVV ’ ,I."..',‘,‘ ,5, 1 -. -,- «V’:IM.V 'VVJVV‘ W’V'M'VKsL-‘Jfa 4‘55‘21:x¢‘5»5-‘5.93?’V '3 «5.55:5. M125" 4'51V4"*-"5V’»~‘31‘;v- -" '5' ‘-.-5"h',"'5t{"" ‘JZV'LV' V ""1 “ "1%.”.‘55’3‘."5"2.'5'{!~£.55‘ .faé‘f‘l'f . . ".1: :63'53, _- ‘ 1' .,;""".'“V.‘ (f. «’15 “UV; 5 , r’. 5,559."? ,gr't-s “V5 ‘0 ,‘ f ('I . ,' xy'fn‘f'lt'V- , r)" .. F:“,' VV.’1'VVVV.:V {’42. I 'V-V’V‘Vibuflfl VIVV’ V IV. VJ r'qVV..'V’:'Va""V1';Vl IV V5 '1’ WJV"I:,;:, I ‘1' VVVWY: ("ArV‘fi “7‘“: H 'V' I :(V (V “am-VI {VIVJ'V-l' 55' ‘5 WIN?» n f 'JW. '5'.“ ' 5'? J ' . . - V3- "V l ' ”M 9' ul - - to . d] 5:23: :4: ' 15 515'1,,’".VJV h . 5551‘ Tiny? -3 H. ' 5""5 L .- “ ' .- .5 0:0 : 'fl 4_05'V0(>J1/. ""0 ""' "' - ‘ ' ' ' ' ' r ' l . .53: 5.5 1,25'5553 5 ..'. ='.. .. ..*..5"5-5'5“-‘.-( 5.5”;- .5 / -5..'} .- 4 5 :55 1,. .. m1. ”5”» u~~~ 3121:? 1' ”51""? £33.:.r/Ih..."..".5~tn 5 '5" ' '15'353"? ’ '3- ,5 r '51» .'f-- 5524. .‘Vétgaa'fl if} "5553.5” ..f5‘-}*1"'}’m 5 -5.—.-' - V ' ‘(' 5:.-. 5 JV‘ .V V'. l' 5 I 1" Iv. . ‘ . I'V‘o V H1": 6. :VV 1"la(\-/H. V - 0’: .V ’II 'I‘ [VL'V-Vl..1;?'.'.?' 5.". ‘. 'V'V" - V. ”ti. '.'€:."; ‘iszufir‘ ' s " 't~f‘V . ‘ Ii...’ J. ‘V, ;'r‘ "erf ' V ,fif'fiii.'5VII:1.5.,3v},'31-,.-I.q,l5. .5, .5, '."~’. .‘5 "5 " ’”- 5“,: 5”,; :5 ..:v ,5' 5.43.. V " -. m5 "”- 1"»1'”?! 7.: V " ' 5 . . ’51IJ-1- ‘:"V‘ '5“ " ..V~'~"J5 0 ' ‘WV " I." V}. I let? VI o'A - 0- 5 ‘It" . ' .' . .'5 .5 9.’5-: VtiV‘V~"J.: (J .'W '..I3' -’I '??;“ . {:1- 'f. '5'::-.I’%L... . ‘ {.'{f’y‘v :Jzty .?(':':"Jn>’ ‘03:: {‘0 5‘}: P O r - . :.. . ':.,V. . V 5‘ “3"."- .,'5' 5 5- " 51.1.. '5 hjixe'sl- 1: .. 54 55-'.5'?1"r'"" 72'; ‘V'V"V'.»£I5V5.r.".'~ .’V""‘;~.V‘r, .L§?r§.;3w "' V": ,1: '7‘?! WM 15"" [1' 'V'rji' ”5+ -'-V- 'r'z.-.V‘J ’. 7.. ”3V “1' '1'; '73 V ' 3": 'V‘5'5‘73"‘Vt3 ’fi'V’V‘H Vi. .' 1"» :5 ‘5 in, - ”as“ ~51 15/555154»: “ ”rim?" JVWcfir‘p 5‘35: 33' ,v'. .5 "'- '35,?IL'»’!:3‘-’J’»"~°."3‘," ’5“ ”If “"15 "9.1“. ' -nV'/51”}5~.:57~55;... 5:. £12.15. . 2.315“ T.” 5.55; ’5" 5, 95,. 5'5z-y5 . 5’:£19~‘nw?-v§”lifiat 5-353; 1”,,r ' My ' .55?)- 1.; 5 5 .; 3:35: 53355:.7, I ‘ _' .VVJ 4". 3"...’ II. V. V. V V Ff". I-c:v '1' V"." a. r 3.6? ‘ V‘. V, 'V‘ " V ’9. n.u, .ou ' S?" ”'2’. 3'er . "0:5“: 2:23;." 3:40.. ::':‘:’P(VY ' V‘a 5“,! ’tf “.rV I 'IIcV'l‘ VH’V'I" t, {A} .1... ":31?!- Vic/LL.“ 'V 75%.; Vl'brr'p';3:'¢ r‘ I“ f‘; (“lg-'2‘»? “1.3;:61:,’;%1’Jm‘r (It 1;". “I . V. ar" J 5 M 5 .55 . - ,. , $55!: 3:111'1- I' 'V V . \' .. t I ‘ 3'! 5‘ .0 V O, ’ It v0 Vat! " . 'l-.' V. o .'zqvhxflo. I W" ‘5‘ ...f;-'V 41" r... l:°.’.'.':"’.'.'..'38‘, .' 'VVIJV'V: '52,.' o 0/.1 {Gen fla/:’ 1- r:‘ ,I '5, ‘ .1}? '.V' {Q1 "1’57:- -;;:h '; ”i{d.;6j ~41?! 'K)‘ { £7}. (3: '7:,:,.. ’:':.V(; II!" .. ,2’..V:,',:L.::V ff." .'.: 1 :l: '9' f, ‘V' V . ‘f_. -_l f f If: ')V'5':1' ." .’ ."V‘M "NT/3.21.?an J. 3". oli”i‘""'°" ' V's}, "v’f.-,g(il,f' 5"“; 5' 1;”, . fl, an .1. ,7, JV («5' J. o5V 5454-! .5 9’3"?” 1' a"! IJTfintV’I‘ Vvflfi'": :- (I pr» 4:!” 5MP: . f ,. -._,," 4" J V V V ‘ '2;;;{:’ 0:5... :r:.;";’r¢rr' 0" '!';V':'€' . 2%.. (.01‘ ‘fvl 7-. IO . . .. . '. . . - - 5 - - . 5 I" "‘ I?) J 5.». 55:.” v . -/ . '5:_ .. I‘llllI/JOOOID r ”:5fvozt :VTPVV" '- ,V'! ‘3'" H v2.9. ,',‘.',.fl J' - ”Psi? u .141: ‘3'“: , '55. 1074.551 ,’.""0"’f° ”3:; _, ‘ 1:71”, " JyVna-V'p'JJ'r .0", ‘JO'V :J' 'f6.4:..; o"5o will"? [.‘3. ,.l o.l 5" ’ '." '- é-I","'V.J'J J ..;.~9 I 'I" I '. 'V ,'.'-I 1' 'P' ' ° . . I l 5 . ., i, -.. a“ 3..." d’ f .'3'. '3': ”2"", ,(,'.'r -‘ C ..5 . .'m|90 “5, I. W,fl,;'....;.... v 3:,5' ',. M. o "CV/VF";:;;."’11r'!.’;':.‘,'$' V.;"(V.E"‘VV;V;§:V"! gift}? 5%:! {riot}. J};_:;fi LWJ '.'V"'.’, till”! .V. fa V; O . ‘ ~ 0 i I - .5. if: v P" 5 0 E r 5. V ‘ j’-r-',. - 4 ' . 5' V? ' ’ " “11‘" ' V n . . . 5 ' :‘fi...’ ' 065-” f ‘1’," ' . l... L," o l v ‘ ,.undc‘(.-.v 5“..va I" '::I PAW..." .— g. 5“ f r1" 1-!lo '_ .'V’» . . 2 . 0' .j, ‘3 V . .'z'fVflfl', .'. "{ )V 5‘ ‘J ‘I. I. 0.1.! I. ' I "V . p...) .'p‘lbl‘ '30] . “2,0,“.- 3/" " V: _’v’: : ‘ " Y. . . J" L‘ l;,;‘..">{;6!~ f;"¢:¥_ rd. !:.-:$. ." '1 ;;:;':;‘ :l;:.‘.r::!" v .l-:.::p.‘ {(-- ' 25:, ., {Lid :"; , .. ' ”9 'V; '4 '6 , ' ' “V V V At”). 'V I"; V, V. V o J... .(£".. ’. ’5"{o.¢‘.fo’ 1"". ’VO-rm ‘LI‘fI [/JI'II'; V); V j ‘V': I“ .'t" i; :V“. to". "“7“; f'fl’I’VV’r’ '0’, a.” x 0.0:~:9r'fl.f'01"."-: 0.: ’J‘L ..' l.... " ’ J.» V ,1.“ .1. 1,. . 5 I. V.. ' .4. (!_' 5 ‘ . . ‘ . . o ‘ . 9"»:9‘. 9‘...» 'g-.:.. - "' , -.'¢v( ‘3 O f, A. S w..- "5 5 {52.5551 5 5.5-1 3, 5. ‘.- ' . 1-. 0.91.514 ~ ’. .wm ”-5-.“ as ~’ :» 'é" ' ”."1-3" ' {5'35 .5 :25?» '51,»...- 55:37»; V3" - 1'» 1:19.” 5:»; >1; . .. 5 5 .- ? E ‘0 w ' .\ '. . X. "l , [‘IL'V . . J .'. - v~O.’ o "a 5.. D'I-.t5 ,.'.l- '..'d4 ‘_' :‘fi. .".,' .'Q.'.A(a JV! '"l‘l I 0.10.} . .. I; : . ;)g ‘ :' ”I?! 5;"??? A’Wfl‘VlJ “.é;::t“ ":'V!‘_V‘;' I}; 1" o I'" It. if. ‘ ' ‘V’: \.V' "f' .' , 't'". . . ‘u o 0‘. - - . 1 '2’” '.5"'45.:'.-'5'»-.- 5 - L'. - ~ 3-...“ 5. - '5 - 5 : - ~ :5: -. 7" .- “'1 $51.55,»: 5 .- «5.1.5: 5’1." 9443;55‘1'3759533 £22m .5 {ant/.1525? ,7» 5 ' A“: f‘;'.r.V' :01:ng‘;‘"'};' 'VVVJLVQV .‘ ' VI . | v , o "‘O. ' V.‘ .4... VVVI-o‘l; .'V aid. .VL . O ' 'V, " IV. ' ' (2V. :';'...'!,.V;".. V.“ :':. V? (i: I. OLLV"(VV" [.’V‘g. "tsfr; :VVfir-“L' ';-%3'r.;r‘r ’0’." ' .: V’ 4?;"m 'V: L"... :1 If ‘ ‘.' .- (V’J‘I' m'd'l' L: :.?.V‘-.:.;IV:';'J.¢:' 1‘! 7’1." J V: 0."de 5' _‘|-V rd'V: ‘,".'.'_’_'.:;"' '-.-.',:_.°.‘. O_"":.:' -..,‘V,',V.I. r'c‘d‘r50r! I 0'5 0H5. f’ ‘7'“ ;. ,1. .35 I' f ' 5'- "L ’ .'rfif" .. ' ' ' _ 5| ? 2E V' ’5"; V”: ’5: r2" ”7 ' " '- 1‘5' 3'1" ;.':5.'.~.'.'.-: .3 -~‘=”:=«'--‘ " ME.) ' -‘- 3143’ '5; ' ' 5:, 2:"LirfirA‘E’ES’V'I‘V‘fiV'fI"f‘ (3:. ’5"??? .31.; "» ;,5'5.5 5.‘ I?" ""15"?";'5"'5,’5‘ "- - ‘ .05 ' ..‘. o. .. . c P 9- 55 ' I ' - u o o 4- r. ' ' ' 4 I a. 0' V ' 01o '5 5' 'G 1 » . . V . .‘ ' ..‘w ,qp’w' :1’::(rf"$0~\ ' Jo..5.,.,'-o~..,-.. (ftp JHV‘IJ.‘? 'l'. ‘(I-f' 'VJ.'-o.-' ‘ ._ ‘ V V 'V ’ ,.f V . V ‘0'. 'V. I 0. ’ .‘ I . V 'V V 'Y wZ’z: ’.J V.‘ a .' ' ‘V. . "V'V" " ‘V hi’, . . u r— a v r: ‘ ' ."'.'..’.' 'J I g i. 1V". V '-V5 . o 1"” ' “'1" ' ' 'VVIVIJO.:'VVV,VV!: V. V: J’VVI-VVV.’ .VVVJa'? .35 .'o‘ ‘VYV:.5 1V1". (51.0.- V I); V ‘V‘f-‘V 1:“. V :VVUV'VH V £15”, V." “£4593” ”:JVQVVHIVVVVi‘VthVV‘LfiV'V'VV:"'.VV;'VR; V , -§J¢&"" J'J: VP. 0." . _V"‘[‘"'l' '3'." '4': '1' g ":...‘ I, .OV,'..| 5 VII "V; T. . ("1“ 'l I? ./ -" 7“ \’ .'"V. '1'... V ' . VA. (V.'f! ‘u. I .0/3'5.V -l V 'V‘IC'VlvV‘: '5' 9Y5I4'152/Iiz; i” z .' v.0” . ' V . ‘§:Vr:':: I—m : I‘if’. .-‘ o 6’...\". ‘DQfi' 5'1.”" 1? 77"”! (’3’..- .. j_rr{"'_ . n."..J .:;;”l.' "':. :,V-o O 1' .o.-t ‘l-ylj' .OQ‘VO‘U.F!J'.'J.J : .0 '--V‘.-u 0“. .c'loV.VVV;V JV o'-. V -. - ,1. -'.'- 0 V...‘.‘ I'til'."|"’_",' ."5::f 'V':V"V:I‘:' V ;'L‘V tcrb"'."": ”Vt. ’ fi' . ' 1" _0 ‘ m‘.’ ‘ ' ‘;' 55- '5 C 2 V" V I .1- '3“. V' V', ' ,VV'V'V V“- 2". V.’ "r'PIV'. . V. V 1V V V V .'C ’.'V. I. o 5”. .' ff. er -‘ .. v.f:o: 5-“. In. .'I :1: "‘ ’n‘- 1"!) .5." .VIVV.‘.( . IV‘Vs’pvf‘Vyfr-y V,‘ Din-5"”), 13“:’ 1:.” I) 'V';:“:. "‘ ff, . 2:." ' .4 n. up 'v'. Jr? 5.*."“. f'\_' I V ’5" '-' V; o If. .".V ' V5l V't' ' v 5 O . .'IV/V‘n 9" v V,” V .‘I’5 V. -.'o‘ .'JVVI'J: -’3'l'V :sz'fV' 3.} 'V’I‘IV: ll" “:5, V“. 'J‘: vr‘wflvafl' ”LII-CV47!" "" £53.) "'3::", ' .r'k: . r 5 '93-. ”V... J‘ {""V’. 'V V" V ' {1. 5 .f ‘ A! . (‘0 - 3' ‘r; I“; t. | ‘ .- V/ . 5. {5° 0. 1,5! 5"” ’5' .- . v ' . v. n '..5!lxl.,',..:.7'5 V'VIVV“ a]. ' ”II” "J, 9"?)1‘1!’ .'i‘rfii: .2“, V’.L?.73?:”U:J‘Ju grim-l y ('5'... 'IV;V “A," .2; 5 ‘.':; fill-Ox.- - V -V ' ‘. ‘ VV . V 5” .‘ . . V at ‘ V '0’ "" f 5 ‘5 o 00.0... I. l I I. I 5 —o “ 0 " 'I 5 .,\ I, ., fir. .. -_- . 1.2!” ._ 5 V’dV' . ., -’ 1. ..' :.'-‘. O 5 5" n _ '. 3."! 1?;l'o,a.c;.6.l.v.' . .3”. '. .‘ 5;. I", ll‘If: :"j?’.o.' ($91..." 1",... «5; 2:71 J” , rVVV'V $5,. {3" ' ,.',.1- {I'VVrH 9 V0. " f- - V 0.. ' V ""1“”! V 'V I V V V i .V I ”V. :V J; " V. "I I 5 ”V. ."é'VOV::Vof‘I WOO, .J:V.' “' .’kyl" 45*!” V2" "'12'.v' I.‘V‘f)/V.’I" . g’:;. ’0'! 01.0“ I" —o’,‘ O :VoV' r - c 5 5 5 5 o . - o 5' a 4 *V I I V I ' ‘ . v I 7' . ' I . ‘ 5 5 5.. 5 .._ I!!! .'5 .' : . ., .‘ '5. ,2... 55‘51'8-‘3‘ 1'1". 5'" filial")? "VUVV’VV ', V?’ 27,, r“ “€123": Maggi-rig". i’l'J' ,.r‘¢,__ay‘-f'” é ;; . 'tz'..o’:‘.o 3%; - “we”, ._ , b ' . I F Vl".,'1 vr .. o'-5 -l.’.. p 0. ' ,V . , ‘ _...,,.. -V_‘ Pl ”'1'5' V‘ ‘5»? "‘V .'. ‘_ U.’ .u‘; (I I0.f':”';f“ Jffr_"'.'.:m " . ::'. 1W rm'0" 1"” ‘- V ‘ \. I J’V':O V ‘ a O 1“ >. ' I. ~ .J 0 0:. V " O ' '. ' '1. .':l . ’u ' -| ' 'l I; 5 ' '.'— .LP F '.. r.r:' rJ/E'ZV:'.' f"."o 0 0.4, r'!.. I," V' :.:A‘3 0 O'?‘ 4" /r‘.';": ' '!.'..' P" "r ‘r .‘m . JI 1.: 0:. r‘ :w'ry“ .'Vy' v..- IVV'.'.'I'!. V L".’ Vo"‘1 :V O" u 1V i V05 5 “ , ,5 1" ‘- '5’», ' ’5 5' ‘. '3 ' .'5 I' V' V‘r' 355' 1.; ‘ ' r' '.5 '{o av‘V-Vn" 1"."3: "V'V‘H'I'V‘V'VV 'V‘V V';V_{:'?"VVV:V:'M'I’ VV‘VVVVVV"“'" H "11:53 73:: ”‘6 « 'V'nqzn' 5.7382213}. '29: V, . V‘.I.V ' ‘ c' ' old 0 .V. o Ii. '1’ , . . ' .. . ' ' . . ' .'5. .‘u . ’m "' 0 'VJ I. Jr'r' O:“" . ... ‘.."‘.' ' 'f . 55 g C .'V I -_V .- _o .5 II'5 ' o5 . '0 r " I... ,I , .’ , 15,0 ‘ . :0 n'" "t' 0' 00 ‘ V., ,‘ .p.- ’5‘.“- .— 5 VV|V V'T’V I VI ' 3!: v. if 0 'I "1' . V, 5 '5, v V_..},,...5 , I , .' {'32:} (d. V. . “o... .‘c"'"':'.:"’ .r . V—VV-Z {'0' J ’5" ’:"" ."V’lrb ' .Zr'5WQQ’7'1I“...O:":L’ V. :I'agfilz‘:'d;?fld o 63:35" O 0 “4:. 5". :t";’,,l/":': '?;;V).;.'..:.'o.':5..v'o.'.fit-£3.90]- V . Q l . .‘v"é"' VI’I :‘V '1VI. . I. 'V- V '0‘ VIII. r.".-1..‘.VV'JVVIV ' '_ ,.-.VVV"" JJ.':,VV" '1’. 5:.". "’:‘:.'.5..'“. 5:!00' ‘1’. It, L ‘c.- 2"". "..:".".".:U"' {1" L'::.".":"—” ' .' ”'V l ' V ‘ . V l '."' 5 ' .IV og|5 . 'V,‘ '. . '1 J ‘3"" 5"... , I. . .' - . ' ."”"’VI / " '19.... ML #36”! ‘.{q.;. “I ”I J. .3 '2’," :«Z'fl: o'o.o"";"J ' .1..',’."'..V:VvV V'.‘ V‘p. "' VVVVV'V . -.’. . .V.VV, '. V V'..:.':‘.- V-. . o'c'. '.u VI'J {I (“.9'0' ’ I;"‘."' ’3 .'".“;A ." ‘Hta' r'Vqflii " .J": L';' m"'.'.....’J 'j.'.. up. 4 -.V’V "‘ H" VV'VV' 51"'f-V,' '5'". 'o ' ' " 'I ° '." VI); 'Hl.’ " {WV}, .Vy'uVu'{.'5Vuvd'w'53Vo'aVL1"; 5r- ovvo ; ' “I" 3.33: ooflgp‘l‘aooor' 'IJ:.” :_':i~:"""/:",. "'_"F...,'( V I 1 IV .0. t 5'12.) -V V" -V' V". -.'°.-.Va--a" V. 5..V0| 5-:0. I '19:”. :Vp-n '0'0'0 ‘9‘ IV‘ ‘ g'::';"'?l"":r ;o:. "ffi: .”.:£.pv :0" ‘,'V'."V""*. V ’V -0 05 I V . V." .VI .-‘.q.- 0r . '9'“... - a: ‘3‘} "-".‘.l’: “15¢.5.:1‘o::v;;":r;31,03!“.a'...»'5.5o"'~',,.rvoFV/ "V"". 4 'I‘V" o?‘;"( ' f... . g x r. . I... "I ._‘q .1. I .l ' ' I 'l .‘ ._ .1. .3 o I 0 . :'"'I I I A _l' I, . 1.. 0" 0 I ‘l .'I I. I ] .;::'1";L q, I} I . 'J‘ 0| " al I . D f I.‘ y . ‘ V" ' '- .v...: I I . J I O V. . o 5 . $ 5.1 V0 5 - ' ' ‘ " . ' . ‘ ' 5 ' .15. .5,‘*.,5¢((| . 5,01% 'V'.',." ..o. - oo-sr'vn , -, g V .'l ' 5 ' I‘V' . " ’ ;¢ :1: ' ( V. '. f 0 °‘ "' V 'L 4".» ' V ' . ..l f _ . ’V.’ ,.. ' o, I0 I,' ‘ ‘ ‘I r _ .‘. ' v .0 0.4;;0'5, ‘ 1 g r f O to ID. .¢ "" .‘_ t 5": I r. J.\-: V . I .:'|.‘ 5 O :' 5 ':' .3; - ‘ .z I: 0 o .‘.: .lvv':-. I’;.’ ’v ’24.. D[0;"’;. ";5..’ '. ’zf " .l’ O '.V..‘/;. V l . . )‘Oj. 0.3;}3"? ’ ('1; 'Oal'ltgjl :7“ 3;: .:;'_ :v'fiél’.’}lf 'é”? ',;' ._. ”Z... h...’. .' .‘é""‘ ‘ ' V V — 4V . I . '. ’ - ‘ . v 0 ' ' ' "V . .— 00 I. V 5. ‘c V. V VI V ' V V V . V V’VV V V. r. o. o.- u". .'l" l '5 ,_' "l'.‘ . 1. V..; I¢OZOHJ "" . ' ". .-». V... - o oOI'I".O‘.5_ a ' - .0“. O ‘V .V.. V‘ V V V V ' . r ' .VV "' V.' 'V ' ’ " '0.'V ...f., ’. l’V ' '0'; ‘1 p( .‘ J .5..:;r. .'l ’.4’ 8". 3 ': ;;%//' J’;If’l:';:::::; Eé’j’J-};u 'J g' 0 -’::c f£:.-‘ '-;I:' ':.'."L" .V'. .I k 0! O ' ' ._:" 0‘ 5010‘.' .‘ V.’ ‘.0 .‘If' I I. 5" 0 ‘9.00v'-./ . />' IL.“ .7,":’5:/.1"9...;t‘?":‘.‘jl-: ’4'} :P;:' ;' (Or. J.“ .'W. "' - i". V 5VV ‘Y I V '5 . ‘.V'V V'IV o'- 'l 5 V ' Ir ‘, " 0 ' "’.""r":' V‘ V V V‘ I . JV ll". of! 't'l."., ":0. “-0.... "O" "/0 O ."1'7'5. "'O‘V'o.’ I'W'V'J '473. r}$?;':‘;; ”.:{” .3. ."t.:-'.":.:: 39;;::.J ”'3. ‘ _ . , 5 . , . u . , I u 1 . - - - , ‘ o . oo 5 - '-_ 'l. . . p. )'_ . VII. V .'.5 V " . I. . V, IV.‘ I _0‘ V - I .V0 5’ I 0.7—. ." ’5‘»... 0': K!’.fl,‘0 V’;5/'V -.:‘ l.;"/J‘:“:. ‘ f: 1: :V;: ‘I; J" {/'!’;:'. ':J" l.. J.'."-J:.'?;;:".' 0-50.. 0.)! C ‘;1."..':"I;D..dfi”,~‘.""..:'. 'WO..:.°'”.'." V . . 511',‘V} V I v , ‘5 . 5 y - -. , ' ..' 9’ r . , . "‘00'595' I , . “NJ: “’4’...’ "’.’J"' 4' 'r-v-Ov—‘OO- 40" -z . H‘ L ’. -'- V 5 WV _ .5. 5 4 V... p .5' .75. o :M ‘tv-O '5. -I_ {94'9“ '1' V‘"" ’V [,0 ,' Io? v “" ‘ " "' ". - vcnoornn 0‘: _ . V}. 0“. ' 5 '5 '0 . ‘ - o .5 'I. .z 5‘, /Cl' '0'. " V'VV‘ "...I 'VJ: “I ‘01:.ZV’. ’r‘JOIVIVJ’ I. .J‘ k:: .Q.‘ .Q‘oqw ?H ""‘>. !-.‘ l. ‘ 'In J. ‘ . . _ .‘ I .' ' - , -..' .5‘. .. .'.y.r. . . or $"ov. 401:9.odo a- .0 5’, '5',“ o. .'.‘.‘.’ 5. " . .5. ..Q. .5 A" (5 .-. ""10"..."1‘5""V"l.l...."""""";'/ _ {llf‘ 'V‘. 2'. O; ‘ 0”} V’s... I", h&::.. :‘L‘ly'fi‘ :I'Q'V'VU afl'w ‘4”. ’iqfl;.:fl r4. :.?'5:Zib‘u.'5‘ . 5 , 5 - 5 5 5 5 u ' . O . ¢ . 5 . ' 0‘ ' ' . I 0' ’ 1' V .'0’: V. ' 5' 5.. 5.5.5 I.V-’.V- . VI 'O.5V V 6 V VI . "V". IV! ..1 ' I-VV- "0.5. A. " V3, 0 0.10- O 5 O fi:’v V.’ .' “72"“ '. ,,)." .V' "’ ;::):.:3 .1:th 5-:::' “V ... "1” O‘Lf-(krf' ’l/” {(11% 2 fifl’I . J. a! L.‘ daf- Ill 5 .5 5 I5 . 'II II 5“ din-.1AlI'JMInl'IIl‘I'VV" ' """ 54$}. AET EUNIVERSITY LIBRARIES IIIIITITIIIIIIIITTTTTTI TI TITII I T 3 1293 00558 99 LIBRARY ‘ Michigan State University II This is to certify that the dissertation entitled DYNAMIC SUPPLY ESTIMATION: THEORETIC AND EMPIRIC REFINEMENTS APPLIED TO U.S. CASH GRAIN PRODUCTION: 1965-1984 presented by Harold William Rockwell, Jr. has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph .D degree in Agricultural Economics Mv/W & fl 06¢. g“ M“ MMVM E117 Major professor Date Mgggh 22; 1255 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 MSU RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to LJBRARJES remove this checkout from -—. your record. FINES will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. [’3 if “i DYNAMIC SUPPLY ESTIMATION: THEORETIC AND EMPIRIC REFINEMENTS APPLIED TO U.S. CASH GRAIN PRODUCTION: 1965-1984 By Harold William Rockwell. Jr. A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1988 ABSTRACT DYNAMIC SUPPLY ESTIMATION: THEORETIC AND ENPIRIC REFINENENTS APPLIED TO U.S. CASH GRAIN PRODUCTION, 1965—1984 BY Harold William Rockwell, Jr. Agricultural supply relations are commonly characterized as "dynamic" in terms of "lagged adjustment" to price signals and "irre- versible" expansions that occur more readily than contractions. The examination of these relations, however, has been rather §g_ Egg in relation to theory. This study attempts to put such examinations on more secure foundations by introducing lagged adjustment derived from upward-sloping input supply curves and irreversibility derived from input supply constraints. Mathematic development of a model incorporating flexible input prices points to problems of econometric estimation that are generally ignored. Extension to the case of input supply constraints shows even greater difficulties for econometric applications. These problems. however, do not make it impossible to test the standard irreversiblity hypothesis. The fact that input suppliers’ normal capacity utilization rate is well in excess of fifty percent suggests that input supply is more likely to be constrained by input capacity than input disposal is to be constrained by a lack of desired salvage markets. The resulting conclusion that irreversibility is likely to be the opposite of common belief (that supply. in fact, contracts on average more readily than its expands) is still difficult to measure in terms of magnitude. Structurally-ordered instrumental variables econometric measure- ments of dynamic supply relations for acreage planted to feed grains, wheat, and soybeans and for four classes of inputs supplied to agricul- ture in the United States (1965-1984) was attempted in spite of the theoretic implications that such measurement would be of questionable validity. Some evidence of lagged adjustment was found and some weak irreversibility of the type suggested was detected rather inconclusive- ly. This study concludes that eclectic studies of complex supply relations may be more reliable and useful than narrow, formal economet- rics, and that the question of irreversibility could be a major stumbling-block for any examination of supply. A number of other observations regarding cobweb cycles and other phenomena are also offered to make the study’s findings more generally useful. to Ruth, whose help and support made this effort possible and whose presence made it seem worth doing iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Special thanks to Eileen 0. van Ravenswaay for continued support and encouragement and to J. Roy Black for providing an opportunity to work and develop. Thanks also to Hsin Hui-Hsu, for repeated discus- sions of important theoretical considerations and to Wayne N. Nhitman for technical assistance. Thanks to the USDA Economic Research Service for funding the original study on which this dissertation is based. TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter Table of Contents. . . . . . . . . . . . . Table of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . 1. Problem Statement. . . . . . . . . . . Policy Considerations. . . . . . Analytic Considerations. . . . . Overview of the Argument . . . . Outline of the Presentation. . . 8. Dynamic Supply Theory. . . . . . . . . Statics. . . . . . . . . . . . . Multiple outputs . . . . . . . Endogenous prices. . . . . . . Dynamics with Quasi-Fixed Inputs Dynamics with Occasionally-Fixed No available salvage market. . Input capacity constrained . . Salvaging inputs . . . . . . . Summary of the cases . . . . . 3. Characteristics of Agricultural Supply Input Supply in Agriculture. . . Labor. . . . . . . . . . . . . Machinery and buildings. . . . Purchased non-durables . . . . Farm-produced durables . . . . Farm-produced non-durables . . Land . . . . . . . . . . . . Inputs in combination. . . . . Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . Implications for Agricultural Output Long-run supply. . . . . . . . Supply with quasi-fixity . . . Supply with occasional-fixity. Implications for cyclicality . The Supply of Cash Grains. . . . Other Factors Affecting Supply . vi Page ix xi UlOJnJH \l 11 IA 81 82 EB 30 31 33 33 3c. 37 «o «a «a 4.3 43 as A7 4.7 as 49 so 51 57 Chapter Page 4. Econometric Methods. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 Dependent Variables. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 Crop Prices. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 Input Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 Legged Endogenous Variables. . . . . . . . . . . . 71 Credit, Debt, and Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74 Cross-equation Restrictions. . . . . . . . . . . . 75 Coefficient Shifting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 Methodological Note. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 S. Econometric Results. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92 Output . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84 Independent variables used . . . . . . . . . . . BS Regressions reported . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88 Regression results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89 Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93 Farm Machinery and Equipment . . . . . . . . . . . 93 Price. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94 Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98 Fertilizer . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 Price. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102 Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104 Pesticides . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107 Price. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110 Fuel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112 Price. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112 Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114 Cross-Equation Restrictions. . . . . . . . . . . . 116 6. Conclusions and Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 General Conclusions Regarding U.S. Agriculture . . 117 Extensions to Other CBSESm . . . . . . . . . . . . 120 Similarities and differences . . . . . . . . . . 120 Alternate land uses. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 New input capacity, processing, and infrastructure. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122 Other policy changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122 Technological change . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123 Treating the special cases . . . . . . . . 123 Examples for U. S. agricultural history and other industries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 vii Chapter Page a. (continued) Strengths and Weaknesses of the Analysis . . . . . 124 Strengths. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124 weaknesses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125 Policy Implications. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126 Suggestions for Further Work . . . . . . . . . . . 129 Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130 Econometric techniques . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130 Other approachess and improved priors. . . . . . 131 Clarifying goals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131 Appendix A (to Chapter 2, p. 14) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 Models of Depreciation Appendix B (to Chapter 2, pp. 23-29) . . . . . . . . . . . . 134 Derivation of Supply/Demand Functions with Occasional Input Fixity Appendix C (to Chapter 4, p. 70) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138 Coefficient Matrix Symmetry for Imposing Econometric Cross-equation Restrictions Appendix D (to Chapter 5). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140 Variable Definition and Data Sources Appendix E (to Chapter 5, pp. 96ff.) . . . . . . . . . . . . 143 Policy for the Selection of Instrumental Variables Appendix F (to Chapter 5, p. 116, and Appendix E). . . . . . 145 Results of Regressions with Cross-Equations Restrictions Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14S viii LIST OF TABLES Table Page 3.1 Labor used in U.S. farming (millions of hours), 1965-83. . . 35 3.2 Gross investment in farm machinery and equipment, 1965-84, and that industry’s fourth-quarter quarter practical capacity utilization rate, 1974-84, and new capital expenditures, 1972-82. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 3.3 Practical capacity utilization rates for the agricultural chemical industries, fourth quarter, 1974-84 . . . . . . . . 41 3.4 New capital expenditures in the agricultural chemical industries, (millions of 1967 CPI dollars), 1972-82. . . . . 41 3.5 Regression on input use of lagged prices and inputs. . . . . 46 5.1 Dummy variable coefficient shifter forms representing the pos- sibility of acreage-related fixity, and the total and change in planted acreages (in millions) of feed grains, soybeans, and wheat from which the shifters were derived, 1965-84. . . 88 5.2 Results of OLS regressions on total acreage of the six study crops (millions of acres), 1965-84 . . . . . . . . 90 5.3 Results of regressions on the normalized price of farm machinery and equipment (1967=1.00), 1965-84 . . . . 95 5.4 Results of regressions on farm machinery and equipment purchases (billions of 1967 dollars), 1965-84. . . . . . . . 99 5.5 Results of instrumental variables regressions on normalized fertilizer price (1967=1.47), 1965-84 . . . . . . 103 5.6 Results of instrumental variables regressions on fertilizer purchases (expenditures divided by price, 1910-14=100), 1965-84. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105 5.7 Results of regressions on real pesticide price, 1965-84. . . 109 ix Table Page 5.8 Results of regressions on pesticide purchases (expenditures divided by price, 1910-14=100), 1965-84. . . . 110 5.9 Results of regressions on discounted fuel price and fuel purchases (expenditures divided by price, 1910-14'2100)’ 1965-84e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e 115 F.1 Results of tests on one symmetry condition . . . . . . . . . 145 F.2 Results of acres planted regressions using three different estimators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1.1 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.5 2.6 3.2 3.3 3.5 3.6 Conditions affecting dynamic agricultural supply . . . . . Exogenous prices of outputs and inputs . . . . . . . . . . Endogenous prices of outputs and inputs. . . . . . . . . Endogenous price of a durable. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Cases of input supply: quasi-fixity, salvage-constrained fixity, input-capacity-constrained fixity, and salvaging Dynamic adjustment to increased output prices with input quasi-fixity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Dynamic adjustment to decreased output prices With input fixity (1:0). 0 O O O I O O I O I I Dynamic adjustment to increased output prices with capacity-constrained input supply . . . . . . . . . . Salvage and acquisition markets with different price flexibilities. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Agriculture as a net supplier of laborers to other sectors The relative likelihood of two cases of occasional-fixity given the frequency distribution of demand for I . . . . Long-run output supply given endogenous prices of inputs and other outputs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Long-run and short-run output supply with unconstrained input quasi-fixity . . . . . . . . . . . . . Constrained short-run output supply with input occasional-fixity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Limit cycles with input occasional-fixity. . . . . . . xi Page 11 12 18 23 27 28 29 3O 35 38 48 4,9 50 57 Figure 3.7 Land use equilibrium without conversion costs. 3.8 3.9 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.6 5.7 Land use shifts with conversion costs. Land use shift to corn without conversion costs. The effect of durable land improvements on land supply . Acreage planted to studied crops in the U.S., crop years 1965-84 . . . Normalized price of farm machinery and equipment, Farm machinery and equipment purchases and stocks, 1965-84 . . . fitted and actual, Normalized prices of crops (lagged, 1967=2.38) and fertilizer (1967=1.47), Fertilizer purchases (expenditures divided by price, 19lO-14=100), 1965-84. . Normalized prices of crops (lagged, 1967=2.38) 1965-84. and pesticides (1967=2.77), 1965-84. Normalized price of fuel (1967=1.77) and fuel purchases (1910-14=100), Models of depreciation: geometric decay, engineering and their difference . xii 1965-84. data, 54 55 56 57 85 9:, 101 102 108 108 113 132 CHAPTER ONE PROBLEM STATEMENT This chapter discusses the policy concerns motivating this study and the analytic concerns that shaped it. It then turns to an overview of the study’s central arguments and an outline of the remaining chapters. Policy Considerations The high grain prices and related policy decisions of the mid- and late-1970’s stimulated considerable expansion of world grain produc- tion. When prices then fell, many people debated the merits of raising support prices or restricting domestic production to raise market prices (or both) to increase U.S. farm incomes. Because production responses to such measures would affect their costs and effectiveness, the nature of agricultural supply became a major topic for discussion. Specifically, attention focused on the difference between short- run and long-run supply response and on whether agricultural supply expands more readily than it contracts. The first issue is often referred to in terms of "length-of-run", ”lagged-adjustment", or “partial-adjustment". The second issue is often called "reversibility” or "irreversibility". These issues were commonly discussed before the 1970’s, but were generally limited to domestic considerations (e.g., Tweeten and Ouance, 1969, and others cited there.) The expansion of competing foreign productive capacity and export facilities in the 1970’s, however, seemed to call for an extension of these concerns to the analysis of world markets. If foreign supply would contract slowly or very little, U.S. policy effectiveness could be seriously impaired. Analytic Considerations Because much of the early work on these issues preceeded wide knowledge of appropriate analytic techniques, the adequacy and applic- ability of available tools has been unclear. Furthermore, empirical studies of these dynamic characteristics of domestic agricultural supply have been far from conclusive. Claims have not been supported by strong evidence, and the empirical evidence that existed has not been built on strong analytic foundations. Econometric work has been based on two standard models. Partial- adjustment is typically modeled by estimating production as a function of prices, policy variables, and the previous period’s production (e.g., Tweeten and Ouance, 1969). Irreversibility is modeled with different ("shifted") price coefficients in periods of expansion versus periods of contraction (e.g., Tweeten and Ouance; Wolffram, 1971; Houck, 1977). In general, large adjustment lags (the first issue) are not apparent in the findings, but some evidence of expansions occuring more quickly than contractions (the second issue) have been found. The latter conclusion may have been strengthened by the fact that a hypothesis of faster contractions (as opposed to faster expansions) was not considered to be important; statistical results to this effect may well have been considered support for a null hypothesis of no differ- ence in the speed of adjustment. A belief in faster expansions may also have been fostered by a 3 number of studies of perennial and fruit tree supply (Arak, 1969; French and Matthews, 1971; Baritelle and Price, 1974; Saylor, 1974; Gemmill, 1978; French, King, and Minami, 1985). More responsive expansions are easier to demonstrate in these cases, and the technical uniqueness of these crops may have been overlooked. Rather than deducing that the rest of agriculture would be less responsive in its expansion as a result, the findings may have been uncritically extended to other crops and possibly to agriculture as a whole. ngrvigw of thggArqugpp More detailed examinations of the dynamics of agricultural supply have traditionally centered on the analysis of inputs to agriculture (e.g., G. L. Johnson, 1958, and others cited there.) In one approach, agricultural supply elasticity has been explained in terms of the elasticity of the supply of inputs to agriculture (perhaps most notably by D. G. Johnson, 1950). In this view, the more inelastic the supply of inputs, the more inelastic the supply of outputs. A second approach focuses on durable inputs (e.g., G. L. Johnson, 1958). In this view, output supply is more elastic when quantities of durables vary than when they are fixed, so attention shifts to the conditions and time frame that determine fixity. These two approaches to the question of agricultural supply elasticity are not really at odds, but the focus on durables in the second approach is significant. Whereas the first view does not explicitly include time, the second leads directly to the subject of length-of-run in supply adjustment. A focus on durables also suggests the question of irreversibility: because stocks of durables are often 4 seen as variable in expansions but fixed in contractions, agricultural supply is often held to expand more quickly than it contracts. This study integrates these two approaches by examining dynamic agricultural supply in relation to the elasticity of inputs supplied to agriculture. It concentrates on: 1) a less-than-perfectly-elastic supply of durable inputs as a source of the "quasi-fixity" of input use that results in partial adjustment, and 2) conditions of perfectly inelastic input supply that result in irreversibility. These condi- tions are shown in Figure 1.1. U1 IN D:\\\\\\\\\\ Cl ".9 I. \ Figure 1.1. Conditions affecting dynamic agricultural supply. In Figure 1.1, the demand (D) for new purchases (1) of an input is shown as a function of that input’s price (w). When input supply is less-than-perfectly elastic (upward sloping), input price is affected 5 by demand (is endogenous) and thereby affects the quantity purchased. When the input in question is a durable, the demand curve is affected by the Quantity of input stocks held by farmers, resulting in quasi- fixity and lagged adjustment (as discussed in more detail in Chapter Two). 1f demand (0’) falls to a point at which no new purchases are desired but at which no salvage market is available, input use becomes perfectly price-inelastic and fixed. Similarly, if demand (0") rises to use all available input production capacity (C), input use is again perfectly inelastic and fixed. As explained in Chapter Two, it is these conditions of "occasional-fixity" that lead to irreversibility of agricultural supply. The econometric evidence presented in Chapter Five does not suggest that lagged adjustment is a major force in agricultural supply. Furthermore, it is argued below that if either condition of occasional- fixity is more prominent in agriculture, it is likely to be that of the input capacity constraint. This implies that, if a difference exists between the rates of expansion and contraction, it is more likely to be the case that agricultural production contracts more readily than it expands, the opposite of the standard view described in the previous section. This hypothesis is weakly supported by the econometric evidence presented in Chapter Five. Outline of the Presentation The remainder of this study consists of five chapters. Chapter Two presents a formal theoretical treatment of quasi-fixity and the two conditions of occasional fixity, and this treatment is related to other 6 literature on economic dynamics. In Chapter Three, characteristics of agricultural production and its input supply are examined to provide informal support for the idea of a more probable capacity-constrained occasional-fixity. Other observations about production cycles, the supply of cash grains, and other factors affecting supply are also made there. Chapter Four includes a survey of methodological considerations involved in any attempt to examine the ideas of Chapters Two and Three econometrically. This chapter covers both domestic and foreign applications, and concludes with a philosophic note about methods used. Chapter Six draws general conclusions and implications of the study. Six appendices provide details of much of the theoretic and econometric presentations. CHAPTER TWO DYNAMIC SUPPLY THEORY The analysis of dynamic agricultural supply must be based in economic dynamics. That base is developed in this theoretical chapter. A beginning definition of terms and principles in statics is followed by a discussion of quasi-fixed inputs and occasionally-fixed inputs. This will set a foundation for the empirical investigations of the later chapters by showing the role of input fixity in supply elastici- ty. Stgtics In static ("timeless", per Hicks, 1946, p.115) production theory, a firm’s optimum output supply (0) and variable input demand (vector1 L) are determined by prices (P for output and vector W for inputs), given decreasing returns at some level of fixed inputs (K). Assuming profit (R) maximization: max R = P0 - W’L L subject to Q = F(L;K) Optimum factor demand is given by simultaneous solution of the first- order conditions: ‘ All vectors are column vectors unless transposed (Eege’ u’)e RL PQL‘H=0 01': UL W/P = w where RL and UL are first partial derivatives2 of R and Q with respect to L, and w is a vector of input prices ”normalized" by output price. The matrix of second partial derivatives (FLL) must be negative definite as a second-order condition and symmetric by Young’s Theorem (Chiang, 1974, p. 324). (See Varian, 1984, Chapter 1 for a standard treatment.) For exposition and econometric estimation, a convenient second- order approximation of the production function F is the quadratic functional form (Lau, 1978, p. 194): D N c + a’L + 1/2 L’FLLL This approximation is g priori as a good as any second-order approxima- tion, and leads to linear input demand functions as follows: the first-order conditions derived from the quadratic production function become: QL=a+FLLL=W When solved simultaneously for input levels: & Capital subscripts denote first partial derivatives. Double capital subscripts denote second partial derivatives. Small case subscripts are labels, unless noted otherwise. FLLL : W - a 01": L“ = FLL-1(W-a) The resulting set of optimum input demand equations (L*) are linear in normalized input prices and have symmetric cross-price effects (due to symmetric FLL‘I). This symmetry is important because it can provide a basis for more efficient econometric coefficient estimates through cross-equation constraints on parameters. Optimum output supply in this case is expressed as: 0* F(L*;K) C + a’L* + 1/2 L*’FLLL* which is quadratic in normalized input prices: 0* = C + a,FL_L-1(W-a) + 1/2 (W-a)’FLL-1(W-a) C - l/a a,F1_L-la + 1/8 W’FLL—IW Summing the coefficient matrices (FLL'I) across firms yields aggregate input demand and output supply relations. Multiplg_gutputs. Because of the multiple commodities under consideration in the cash grain sector, a single-aggregate-output analysis is not adequate. To develop the static multi-product case, we shall assume that some output (0“) is additively separable from a quadratic function (F) in other outputs (vector 0) and inputs (L and K). (The plausibility of this assumption for agriculture is explained 10 in Chapter 4.) Normalizing prices by the price of On (PH) at the outset and maximizing the resulting normalized profit function (r = R/Pn, i.e., profits expressed as units of On): max r = 0n + p’O - w’L subject to 0n = F(Q,L;K) with Fvv [Y = (O’ L’), the vector of 0’s and L’s] again symmetric negative definite, the first-order conditions: are again solved simultaneously to get optimum non-numeraire outputs and inputs that are linear and symmetric in prices: (O*' L*’)’ = th”‘ (-p-aq’ w-a,’)‘ and 0*" quadratic in prices. Although 0*n can be expressed in terms Of 0* and L*, it is no longer possible to express 0* in terms of L* (except under very restrictive conditions). Once again, aggregate relations result from summing across firms. Hotelling’s Lemma (Diewert, 1982, p. 581; Nadiri, 1982, p. 452; Varian, 1984, p. 52) is demonstrated by taking the first partial derivatives of the resulting indirect profit function in normalized output and input prices, which is: 11 r* = 0*n + (p’ -w’) (0*’ L*’)‘ = C - a,Fvv—1a + 1/2 (‘p’ W,)Fyv-‘(-p’ W’), + (p’ ’W,)Fyv-1('p’ w’)’ - (p’ -w’)Fyy“a in which a = (aq’ a,’)’, and which reduces to: r* = C - a’Fvv-la + a’Fvv-1('p, W,)’ - 1/2 (p’ -w’)Fyy‘1(-p’ w’)’ By Hotelling’s Lemma, the first partial derivatives of r* with respect to p and -w yield 0* and L*: (0*’ L*’)’ = (r*,’ -r*~’)’ = Fyy“ [(-p’ w’)’ - a] as shown above. Endogenous prices. With exogenously determined prices, this competitive supply model is the same for both the firm and the aggre— gate industry. In this case, output and input prices are not influ- enced by output supply or input demand, as in Figure 2.1. (a) (b) Figure 2.1. Exogenous prices for outputs (a) and inputs (b). 12 With downward-sloping output demand and upward-sloping input supply curves, however, the analysis becomes more complex at the level of the industry. (The case of the competitive model with exogenous prices would still apply for the firm.) Fee-1 is now the aggregate derived from the sum of individual functions. Dropping (*) for simplicity’s sake, endogenous prices resulting from less-than-totally- elastic output demand and input supply are represented most simply by: On + qu 13 11 w = w,. + m,L in which intercepts pa and w" are functions of exogenous price shift- ers, and mq and m, are the slopes of output demand and input supply curves, respectively, as shown in Figure 2.2. pm ”It (a) (b) Figure 2.2. Endogenous prices of outputs (a) and inputs (b). Equating these prices with marginal products: (aq’ a,’)’ + Fyy(0’ L’)’ = (-pm’ ww’)’ + ( )(0’ L’)’ 13 or: (Fey-m)(0’ L’)’ = (-pw’-aq’ wM'-a,’)’ where m = ( ) optimum quantities become: (0’ L’)’ = (FYv-m)“(-pK’-aq’ wm’-a,’)’ By endogenizing induced price changes, this relationship expresses output supply and input demand as functions of exogenous price shifters only. With expected signs on the elements of m, 0 and L are less responsive to pa and w, the more p and w respond to 0 and L, demon- strating D.G. Johnson’s (1950) major point about output supply elastic- ity depending on input supply elasticity. (Note that there is no implication of irreversibility.) If m is diagonal, or at least symmetric, cross-price effects are still symmetric, a case which seems likely. Note that if all inputs were variable, even one upward-sloping input supply curve or one downward-sloping output demand curve would serve the same purpose as diminishing returns in making the coefficient matrix non-singular and invertible, i.e., in uniquely determining quantities. The similarity of the effects of endogenous output and input prices is interesting, but it is not essential to this study. Endogenous input prices will be the focus of the remainer of this work, therefore, and the endogeneity of output prices will be ignored. 14 Dynamics with Quasi-Fixed Inputs Time has not been explicitly part of the above static analysis, so no distinction has been drawn between stocks and flows. Simply indexing quantities for time does not alter this approach (Arrow, 1964). When an outcome depends on outcomes in other periods, however, the problem becomes dynamic, and the distinction between stocks and flows becomes important. Such is the case when the problem above includes changing prices and durable inputs with upward-sloping supply curves, known in the literature as "quasi-fixed" inputs. (Good references include: Nerlove, 1972; Treadway, 1970 and 1974; Epstein, 1981; and Nariri, 1982, pp. 477-9). The notion of quasi-fixity is best seen as the analog of quasi-rent: rent is earned by fixed assets, quasi-rent by durable assets which are varied only by affecting their prices (Marshall, 1982(1920), p. 358). The resulting model of dynamic adjustment is the core of the "flexible accelerator” model of macroeco- nomic dynamics (Lucas, 1967a). For present purposes, a durable is defined as an input with less- than-total depreciation in a production period. (In the discrete analysis used below, a period is one year.) Depreciation is defined as the periodic reduction in the value and service-yielding ability of inputs. The common rule that depreciation is a constant proportion (d) of the durable stock will be assumed, although this proportion can vary by type of input. (See, e.g., Jorgensen, 1971, pp. 1112 and 1141; Nickell, 1978, p. 8; Burmeister, 1980, p. 42; Gunjal and Heady, 1984: and Appendix A.) This simplification makes it straight-forward to aggregate an input of different vintages after an uneven history of acquisition. It is also assumed that service flows are constant 15 proportions of durable stocks, another very common assumption, which makes it irrelevant whether production function arguments are denomin- ated in stocks or flows. (See, e.g., Treadway, 1970, p. 331, and 1974, p. 19.) Because the distinction between variable and fixed inputs becomes blurred in this model, the vector L will now be used to represent stocks (after new purchases) of all inputs at the beginning of the production period. (For simplicity, all input purchases are assumed to occur at that time.) Vector 1 represents new purchases, and vector (1- d)L is stocks at the end of the production period (i.e., after depreci- ation). By definition, then: Lo, : 1,, + (l-d)L,,_, For durables: For the special case of non-durable inputs: 50: (For the following analyses, the subscript t will be suppressed in all unambiguous cases.) In the multi-period model needed for dynamic analysis, first-order 16 conditions are derived by maximizing the present value of future profits (J) with respect to current decision variables (00, Lo). That is, in each period, output and input levels are chosen so as to maximize the infinite sum: max J = INFSUM (1/(1+i))“(0n + p0 -wI) Oo,Lo t=0 subject to 0 = F(0,L) L I + (1-d1La-, in which i is the opportunity cost of capital funds, so that 1/(1+i) is a discount factor; and w is the vector of input prices. (Acquisition and salvage prices are assumed to be equal for each input.) This is the discrete version of a standard problem in optimal control theory and the calculus of variations. (See, e.e., Gould, 1968; Nerlove, 1972; Kamien and Schwartz, 1981, pp. 7 and 113; and Kendrick, 1982.) The dynamic analysis does not alter the first-order conditions for outputs (currently assumed to be non-durable): 11 0 39° = F006 ‘1’ P except that p must now be considered to be prices expected to prevail when outputs go to market. With stationary price expectations, the first-order condition for each input becomes: 3L9 = INFSUM (1/(1+i))”FL° - onL0 = 0 => INFSUM (1/(1+i))"F,_L,,O = onLo 17 With FL constant and IOLo=1: [INFSUM (1/(1+i))”LL°] FL = w Replacing L with (1-d)”Lo, and with LoL.=1: [INFSUM (l/(l+i))t(l-d)tLoLol FL = w [INFSUM (l/(l+i))”(l-d)”l FL = w Calling the constant summation term (which reduces to (1+i)/(i+d)) “B": BFL = w This is the dynamic first-order condition for each input. Note that i+d is the sum of the interest and depreciation cost rates of durable use. When d=l, B=1 and the case of non-durable inputs is still analogous to that of the static analysis. When O0 I I*=0 I (a) (b) w 5 w S \\D D I*=C I* dLfi—l ""> L > Lg—j (<) (<) Because input purchase demand (Di) is a decreasing function of input stocks, i.e.: Dice-1 < 0 the resulting rise (fall) in input use and depreciation cause input purchases to fall (rise) until they equal depreciation: I = dL,_, and thereby establish equilibrium, at least in the limit. Graphically (see Figure 2.5), a displacement from equilibrium (0*) could be caused, for example, by a rise in output prices implying a new equilibrium (D**). Adjustment would take place, however, by a larger initial shift in input demand (0’), which would then eventually converge to D**. D’ t=1 D** t=infinite 0* t=0 I Figure 2.5. Dynamic adjustment to increased output prices with input quasi-fixity. 28 With input fixity caused by the constraint of non-negative purchases, however, this adjustment process is altered (see Figure 2.6). with output prices falling, D’ could fall to the point that new purchases of that input cease (I=0). 0* D** \