AGMCULTURE‘S ROLE {N THE EXTERNAL EWCE AND {NTERNAL GROWTH OF THE COSTA RICAN ECONOMY Thesis far the Dem» of M. S. MCHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY Rodalfa E. Quiros 1962 This is to certify that the thesis entitled AGRICULTURE'S ROLE IN THE EXTERNAL BALANCE AND INTERNAL GROWTH OF THE COSTA RICAN ECONOMY presented by Rodolfo E. Quiros has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for m degree in fiififlge— 6AM K €4th Major professor Date April 17. 1962 0-169 LIBRARY Michigan State University I {in w ‘r (1 W4 gym}? My a W33 2"‘7 MAY f i 20m {,JAN :31 33812 ABSTRACT AGRICULTURE'S ROLE IN THE EXTERNAL BALANCE AND INTERNAL GROWTH OF THE COSTA RICAN ECONOMY By Rodolfo E. Quiros One of the striking changes in development patterns and policies in underdeveloped nations in postwar years is the attempt to shift away from export agriculture. In fact, when emerging nations have invested in agriculture, the emphasis has been on self—sufficiency, import substitution, and insulation from world markets. This is a sharp break with the past. The economic history of the United States, Japan, Canada, Russia, Argentina, and Brazil, has been marked by development through world trade. Latin American development patterns reflect this drive for import substitution and the expansion of industry. The ECLA doctrine (also known as the Prebisch—Singer Thesis) has been instrumental in encouraging an increasing number of Latin American countries to concentrate their financial and human resources on import replacing industries at the eXpense of export agriculture. Rodolfo E. Quiros In the late 1950's, Costa Rica enacted three laws which sheltered industries producing for the local market. In essence, Costa Rica is moving along the line advocated by ECLA. Costa Rica is a small agricultural nation of 1.1 mil- lion people and has an annual rate of population growth of 3.87 per cent. Bananas and coffee are the main crops and the main exports. Since agriculture is the major sector in the terms of employment and almost the sole earner of foreign exchange (95%), the purpose of this thesis is to appraise agricul- ture's role in the external balance and internal growth of the Costa Rican economy during the 1950—1959 period. Modern economic statistics for the Costa Rican economy were not available until 1956 when national income accounts were first published starting with 1950. Seven methods of computing growth rates which have been recently examined by Professor Boris P. Pesek were discussed. Six of these were used to compute the growth rates of gross national product, net national product, and net income, and the major sectors of the Costa Rican economy over the 1950-1959 period. Costa Rica's gross national product in constant prices grew at a Rodolfo E. Quiros rate of 8.00 per cent annually during the 1950-1959 period while national income and domestic product grew at 7.53 and 7.06 per cent respectively. The agricultural sector of the gross domestic product grew at 4.55 per cent—-the slowest annual rate of growth of any sector. The cost of living index rose from 100.0 in 1952 to 113.4 in 1959 or a rise of 1.42 per cent per year. The food component of the cost of living index rose from 100.0 in 1952 to 114.9 in 1959 or a rise of 1.47 per cent per year. These figures indicate that, unlike other Latin American countries, Costa Rica has not experienced sharp price increases caused by unsatisfied demand for food products. Rising food imports are sometimes viewed with unwar- ranted alarm. Costa Rica, for example, has a comparative advantage in producing crops such as coffee and bananas and importing certain food such as cereals and cereal products. In order to satisfy the rising incomes and population growth during the 1950‘s, Costa Rica expanded coffee exports and increased food imports. All food imports, however, in— creased by only $7 million over the 1950—1959 period while coffee exports were $23 million higher at the end of the period than in the beginning. Rodolfo E. Quiros In Costa Rica's dualistic economy, productivity gains have been centered in the coffee sector and not in crops produced for the domestic market. Coffee exports increased 138 per cent while coffee acreage increased 49 per cent in the ten—year period. Costa Rica has relied on a moderate rise in food imports and effective stabilization policies of the National Production Council to stabilize food prices over the ten— year period. In general, the 1950-1959 decade was a period of over- all high rates of growth-~8 per cent per annum—-a 3.66 per cent rise in real per capita income per annum, political harmony and a stable general price level including stable food prices. AGRICULTURE'S ROLE IN THE EXTERNAL BALANCE AND INTERNAL GROWTH OF THE COSTA RICAN ECONOMY BY Rodolfo E. Quiros A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE Department of Agricultural Economics 1962 G. a. _ . pa‘fi ‘4’ i/ ‘ .. C" : . r “'2 ,' .- -: .a' 1‘ r ctr AC KN OWLE DG EME NTS The author wishes to express his sincere appreciation to Dr. Carl K. Eicher whose guidance, understanding and patience contributed greatly to the completion of this thesis. The author is further indebted to Professor Boris P. Pesek for his interest and guidance in the statistical aspects of this thesis, and to Professor Lawrence W. Witt for his valuable suggestions and review of the manuscript. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter Page I. PRIMARY PRODUCING COUNTRIES: PROBLEMS AND POLICIES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . l l :\A. General Characteristics of Small Nations ‘NB. Instability of International Markets and Stabilization Policies for Primary 7 Producing Countries C. Relations Between Industrial and Primary Producing Countries: The Prebisch- Singer Thesis for Latin America v D. The Role of Agriculture in External Balance and Internal Growth 52 ‘E. Summary 63 32 II. SCOPE OF THE THESIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 III. GENERAL CHARACTERISTICS OF COSTA RICA . . . . 73 A. Political Organization of Costa Rica 74 B. Major Institutions in the Public Sector 78 C. International Ties 87 D. Demographic Characteristics of Costa Rica 91 E. Social Characteristics of the Population 97 F. Summary 100 IV. THE CONTEMPORARY PERFORMANCE OF THE COSTA RICAN ECONOMY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102 A. The Status of the Costa Rican Economy in 1950: The Stacy May Study 103 B. Economic History of Costa Rica: 1950—1959 104 C. Problems of Measurement of Economic Growth 110 D. Costa Rican National Income Data 120 E. Some Measures of the Rate of Growth in Costa Rica: 1950-1959 125 137 F. Summary iii Chapter V. THE PERFORMANCE OF COSTA RICAN AGRICULTURE: 1950-1959 c o o o o o o o o o o o o o o A. Main Agricultural Regions and Their Characteristics E. Land Tenancy in Costa Rica C. Size and Number of Farms D. Land Use in Costa Rica E. Agricultural Production Data F. Price Stabilization Policies G. Agricultural Credit System H. Summary VI. AGRICULTURE AND INTERNAL GROWTH . . . . . A. Summary VII. AGRICULTURE AND EXTERNAL BALANCE . . . . . A. Summary VIII. SUMMARY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . APPENDIX . . . . . . . . . . . . . BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . iv Page 139 140 143 146 148 154 160 172 176 181 189 194 210 213 230 234 LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1.1 Year to Year and Long-Term Fluctuations in Prices, Volume and Proceeds of Selected . . 11 Primary Commodities, 1901-50 . . . 3.1 Costa Rica: Population and Population Growth, 1920-1959 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91 Economically Active Population 3.2 Costa Rica: 1927 and 1950 . . . . . by Economic Activity, 94 3.3 Costa Rica: Birth, Mortality and Natural Growth Rates of Population per 1000 Inhabitants, 1930—1934 and 1952-1956 . . . . . 96 Government Budget Fiscal Year 4.1 Costa Rica: 1959 (Ordinary and Extraordinary) . . . 109 4.2 Costa Rica: Gross National Income, Gross National Product and Gross Domestic Product at Factor Costs, 1950-1959 . . . . . . . . . . 122 4.3 Costa Rica: Gross Domestic Product by Economic Sectors, 1950-1959 . . . . . . . . . 123 4.4 Percentage Contribution of Major Sectors to the Gross Domestic Product of Costa Rica, 1950-1959 124 4.5 Annual Rates of Growth of the Costa Rican Economy: Gross National Product and Income, Gross Domestic Product by Economic Sectors, Using Six Different Computational Methods, 1950-1959 . . . . . . . . . . 135 5.1 Costa Rica: Size and Number of Farms 144 5.2 Costa Rica: Land Distribution by Percen- tage of Farms and Percentage of Total Farm 149 Area . . . . . . . . . . . Table Page Number of Farms and Farm Land, Costa Rica: . Percentage Distributions 1950 and 1955 . . . 150 Costa Rica: Farm Land Use, 1950 and 1955 151 Costa Rica: Land Utilization 153 Costa Rica: Principal Crops as Percentage of Total Value of Agricultural Production, 1950 and 1955 . . . . . . . . . . . 155 Costa Rica: Indexes of Agricultural . . . . . 157 Production, 1950 and 1955 . Costa Rica: Indexes of Production of Live— stock, Livestock Products, Poultry and Swine, 1950—59 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159 National Production Council: Commodity Purchases Under the Price Stabilization Program, 1950—1959 . . . . . . . . . 166 National Production Council: Purchases of Rice, Beans and Corn as Percentage of Total 167 Production, 1950-1959 . . . . . . . Rural Credit Boards, Number and Volume of . . 176 Loans, 1950—1957 . . . . . . . . . . . . Costa Rica: Percentage Contribution of Agriculture to Gross Domestic Product, 1950-1959 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183 Costa Rica: Food Imports, 1952—1959 . . . . . 187 Costa Rica: General Price Level Indexes, 1950-1959 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190 Costa Rica: Total F.O.B. Exports, 1950—1949 . 196 vi Table 7.2 United Fruit Company, Exports as Percentage of Total Costa Rican Exports, 1955, 1959 . . 7.3 Costa Rica: 1950-1959 7.4 Costa Rica: Exports, 1950, 7.5 Costa Rica: 1950-1959 7.6 Costa Rica: of Payments, Appendix Table I. Costa Rica: Production, II. Costa Rica: 1950-59 . III. Costa Rica: Indexes of International Trade, Geographical Destination of 1959. Total Imports C.I.F., Balance of Trade and Balance 1955, 1950-1959 Volume of Agricultural 1950—59 Volume of Animal Production, Land Planted to Principal Crops, 1950-59 . . vii O O Page 197 202 203 205 208 Page 231 232 233 CHAPTER I PRIMARY PRODUCING COUNTRIES: PROBLEMS AND POLICIES General Characteristics of Small Nations A nation is an important and relevant unit for eco- nomic analysis because it is the basic unit of economic authority and government action.1 Within the bound— aries of a nation, a modern government uses its budge- tary system as an instrument of economic policy; within the national boundaries, a government with the aid of a central bank promotes economic development, attempts to provide a high rate of employment and keep the balance 0f payments under control. Individuals living within national boundaries are affected and influenced by the decisions and actions of economic authorities. The boundaries of a nation, by enclosing a unit of government and economic policies, represent a pOint of 1E. A. G. Robinson (ed.), Economic Consequences of the Size of Nations (New YOrk: Saint Martin's Press, Inc., 1960). XIV. discontinuity. National boundaries not only represent a change in the degree of mobility of the factors of pro- duction and goods, but also represent other discontinui- ties which are inherent to boundaries of nations such as language, education, skills, and community interest and outlook.1 These characteristics and discontinuities are common to all nations in varying degrees. There are, however, other characteristics which seem to be related to the size of nations. Professor Kuznets, for instance, has depicted a number of eConomic traits which are charac- teristic of small nations.2 To Kuznets, a small nation is "a sovereign state with a population of ten million or less."3 Although the correlation between population lIbid., I. Svennilson, "The Nation in Economic Analysis," 1-13. 2Ibid., Simon Kuznets, "Economic Growth of Small Nations," 13-32. 3A number of other economists feel that the 10 million population limit is rather low and suggest that a 15 million population limit is better for economic Purposes when considering small nations. (Ibig,, dis- cussion of KuznetS' paper, 348-350.) and area is not perfect, most of the nations that are small in population are also small in size. Thus, the first characteristic of small nations is a small population. The second characteristic of small na— tions is that their economy is less diversified than that of larger nations, even when the two nations have achieved the same level of economic development. In other words, the proportional distribution of total output and factors of production are concentrated in a few industrial2 sec- tors. This is principally the result of three factors.3 The first is the limiting effect of the size of nations on the supply of natural, non-reproducible resources. In general, larger countries have a greater variety of nat- ural resources (minerals, climates, land, water, etc.) which are available or could be available at any given level of technology. The second factor affecting the relative lack of diversification of small countries is 1 . OE. Clt. I 16. 2 U s o Industrial in an economic sense. 3Ibid., 16-81. the minimum economic scale of some industries and the limited domestic market of small nations.l Some industries (mainly heavy capital producing industries) require a minimum scale of plant which would be very un- economical for the extent of the market of the economic system of a small nation unless it can rely on a sub— stantial foreign market. The third and last reason is, in a sense, complementary of the two named above. On one hand, although small nations may lack many natural re- sources, the supply of a few may provide a comparative advantage to concentrate in their exploitation. Larger countries may have a wider variety of natural resources and a larger absolute supply but a less favorable endow- ment on a per capita basis. On the other hand, although small nations may not afford large-scale industries, they may have a comparative advantage with respect to some production processes. In other words, the existence Of these nuclei of comparative advantage may lead to a concentration of economic activity in small nations. 1This limitation of the market in small nations, is further accentuated in small underdeveloped nations by low levels of income. Professor Kuznetsgeneralizes from empirical data on the concentration of exports and suggests that foreign trade plays a larger role in smaller nations than in larger nations. This generalization forms the second general characteristic of small nations. Patinkin, how— ever, rejects this generalization by referring to a recent study of M. Michaely.l Patinkin concludes that . . . if one took all the large countries togeth- er and all the small countries together, there was not much difference between the concentration of ex- ports in large and in small countries. The classi- fication meant that one was taking underdeveloped and developed countries together in each group, and their characteristics canceled out. In summary, Patinkin points out that the concentration of exports in large or small nations ". . . was only eco— nomically significant if one also distinguishes devel- . ..3 - oped from underdeveloped nations. According to the same author, smaller developed nations have a higher index of dependence on foreign trade than larger lM. Michaely, study carried out at the Hebrew University. 292. cit., Don Patinkin, "Discussion: Economic Growth of Small Nations," 352. 3 Ibid., 353. developed nations. However, there was no significant difference in the index of concentration of foreign trade in small and large underdeveloped nations.l Therefore, qualifying Professor Kuznets' statement, it could be said that foreign trade has important weight both in the economic activity of small developed nations and large and small underdeveloped nations. To summarize, the general characteristics of small nations are: a) concentration of production in a small number of economic activities, and b) high concentration of production for international trade. These two characteristics have economic implica- tions for small countries. In the first place, the limited size of their domestic market compels small na- tions to sell a larger share of their production abroad, therefore making their economies vulnerable to economic fluctuations originating abroad. Secondly, given the limited size of the domestic market small nations may not lIbid. 2Empirical data show that both exports and imports of underdeveloped nations are exchanged for goods in a small number of other nations. This pattern is in market con- trast to the dispersion of international trade of larger developed countries. Ibid., Simon Kuznets, 21. take full advantage of the economies of scale of mass production. Thirdly, by virtue of the geographical size and economic and political power, small nations cannot exercise as much effect on international markets as com- pared to larger nations. This greater dependence on international trade on the part of underdeveloped nations (whether large or small as pointed out earlier), poses two additional problems which have important implications for their economic devel— opment efforts and policies: a) the extent of deteriora- ting terms of trade for underdeveloped countries and b) instability of international markets and export proceeds of underdeveloped countries. These two problems will be explored individually in the remaining parts of this chapter. Instability of International Markets and Stabilization Policies for Primary Producing Countries The purpose of this section is to review the nature, extent and causes of the instability of export prices and proceeds of primary prdducing nations and the common policy prescriptions to reduce price and income instability. The Nature of the Iggtability Instability of export markets for primary commodities is of extreme importance to underdeveloped nations for they are usually the main source of foreign exchange. The relative importance of exports to underdeveloped na- tions is brought out by the fact that exports of these nations to the industrial world accounted for twenty— five per cent of the total trade of the world; in addi- tion, their exports to the industrial world are two and a half times as large as their exports to each other.1 This asymmetry in the trade relations between industrial and underdeveloped nations as compared to the intra— trade among the latter is of great importance since a fluctuation that can be a mere ripple to industrial na- tions, may have the effect of a disastrous fluctuation in underdeveloped nations. lRagnar Nurkse, "Trade Fluctuations and Buffer Pol- icies of Low Income Countries," Kyklos, Vol. XI, 1958, Fasc. 2, 142. The Extent of Instability of Primary Producers Two United Nations studies, published in 1951 and 19521 respectively, explore the relationship between ex- port quantities and export proceeds for a number of se— lected commodities produced by underdeveloped nations. The data presented here provide ample indication of: first, the wide price fluctuations which afflict export prices of the main commodities produced by underdeveloped countries; second, the great variations in export quanti- ties both in terms of world market and export quantities to particular markets; and third, the tendency of price and quantity fluctuations to interact so as to reinforce each other rather than compensating each other's fluc- tuations. The result of this process is violent varia— tions in export proceeds which then represent an unreli— able source of foreign exchange to pay for a steady in- flow of capital goods and other goods required for eco— nomic development. The 1951 study explores year to year variations in prices, quantities and proceeds for thir- teen selected commodities for the period 1901 to 1950. L United Nations, WOrld Economic Situation: Economic Egyelopment of Underdeveloped Countries, 1931:United Nations Instability in Export Markets of Underdeveloped Countries, 1952. l 10 The results of this study show that these thirteen com— modities underwent an average fluctuation per year of eighteen per cent with respect to prices, twenty-five per cent with respect to volume and thirty~five per cent with respect to export proceeds.1 The results of the 1952 study which analyses the same three variables for cyclical, long—term and year to year variations, can be more efficiently summarized in tabular form. 25 commodities considered. 11 TABLE 1.1 YEAR TO YEAR, CYCLICAL AND LONG—TERM FLUCTUATIONS IN PRICES, VOLUME AND PROCEEDS OF SELECTED PRIMARY COMMODITIES,19OL-50 PER CENT AVERAGE ANNUAL FLUCTUATION Year to Cyclical Long—term Year Within Up— Down- Phase: Year swing swing Rising Falling Pricesa 13.7 12.8 -l3.0 4.7 -4.3 26.7 Volumeb 18.7 17.6 —l6.8 4.0 -4.1 Proceedsb 22.6 22.0 -22.l 5.8 —6.1 Source: United Nations, Instability in Export Markets of Underdeveloped Countries, 4-6. New York, 1952, Tables 1—3, a , , . 25 commodities conSidered. 18 commodities considered. Year to year fluctuations in volume were frequently twice as high as fluctuations in price and thus resulted in greater instability of proceeds. even when the fluctua- tions were in the opposite direction. Price and volume fluctuations tended to be in the same direction in the 12 case of industrial raw materials while fluctuation in volume and in prices tended to move in opposite direc- tions in the case of food commodities. A further conclu- sion from the two reports is that no relief from these extreme variations is afforded underdeveloped countries through corresponding variations in the prices of their imports; on the contrary, when proceeds are computed in terms of buying power over imported manufactured goods, yearly variations are, if anything, intensified rather than moderated. It can be noted that the 13 commodi- ties in the 1951 report experienced more violent price fluctuations than the 25 commodities in the 1952 report. It is observed from the preceding table that fluctua- tions in export proceeds, whether measured year to year, cyclical or long-term, were in each case higher than fluctuations in volume or prices alone. The study also points out that this was true even when fluctuations in proceeds were measured and compared in different periods within the time period considered. Furthermore, the reports show that if specific commodities from specific exPorting countries in the U. S. market alone are con- sidered, the average yearly variation in export proceeds 13 is even greater; namely forty—nine per cent according to the 1951 report and thirty-seven per cent according to the 1952 report (seventeen per cent with respect to prices). The above mentioned observations indicate that changes in prices and in quantities had destabilizing effects on each other. Analysis of the years for fall— ing proceeds in which declines averaged twenty-five per cent, show that two—fifths of the decrease was accounted for by a decline in price; the rest by a decline in volume. substantial differences were found in both reports with respect to the relative importance of fluctuations in price and in volume, so far as a particular group of commodities or selected countries were concerned. In general, however, neither price stabilization alone (at the existing level of instability in export volume), nor volume stabilization alone (at the existing level of price instability), was sufficiently great to result in any substantial stability of proceeds. Commodities which were found particularly liable to year to year fluctuations in price were also liable to wide year to year fluctuations in volume and proceeds, and vice versa. l4 gaggggpof Instability There is a general consensus of opinion among economists that demand conditions play a dominant role in the instability of export markets for primary products, and that export fluctuations of primary producers origi- nate in the cyclical swings of investment in fixed capi- tal. Professor Nurkse,for instance, states that the ef- fects of the industrial investment cycle on the demand for primary products is magnified by inventory changes arising from speculative activities or simply by the nor— mal desire to keep stocks adjusted to the volume of trade and production;1 hence the cyclical variability of demand for primary products. Other factors in the demand side that may have an important bearing on the prices of pri- mary commodities are the major irreversible shifts of demand caused by technological advances such as the electrolytic tinning in the 1940's. Let us turn to the supply side. Price induced changes in output may be caused, in the first instance, by changes in the supply, demand schedules remaining unchanged. The 10p. cit., p. 142. 15 extent to which total supply responds to price changes depends on many factors and varies greatly from com- modity to commodity. Most economists seem to agree that the short-run supply elasticity of most primary com— . I O l modities is low and even zero for some, e.g., most food crops and minerals produced with capital intensive meth— ods. For some other commodities price elasticity of sup- ply is considerably greater than zero, even in the short- run, e.g., palm products and rubber. It is generally agreed that long-run elasticity is greater than the short—run one, but this division of the two elasticities is not as important as the time period required to change fixed—factor inputs. This depends in part on the organi- zation and the physical characteristics of production; for instance, the production of tree crops, obviously will expand more slowly than the production of field crops. Two additional factors also enter in the determination of the long-run supply elasticity; these are, first, the 1However, inelasticity of supply seems to be more pronounced in the event of falling prices than at times of rising prices. Henry wallich, "Stabilization of Export Proceeds," Economic Development for Latin America, HOward S. Ellis (ed.)(New YOrk: Saint Martin's Press, 1961), 346-347. l6 psychological responsiveness of producers to price changes, in particular--peasant producers, and second, the physi- cal possibility and the economic attractiveness of pro— ducing alternative crops. From the preceding comments two conclusions can be drawn. One is that the reduction of price fluctuations would reduce or mitigate the fluctuation in output of pri- mary commodities. The second conclusion is that supply conditions differ so much from commodity to commodity that price stabilization schemes must also vary according to the commodity in question. Some Common Solutions to the Problem Based on previously stated observations, it could be said that industrial countries have tended to impede prog- ress in primary producing countries through the instabil- ity of the trade cycle.l There are, however, three solu- tions to this problem. The first solution is to exercise greater control over the business cycle in industrial nations through appropriate monetary and fiscal policies. Although some progress has been made in this direction, lOp. cit., Nurkse, 143. 17 it is unlikely that upswings and setbacks strong enough to cause serious trouble in international markets can be avoided altogether. The second solution is to make struc- tural changes in primary producing economies which will make them less vulnerable to instabilities in inter- in one word, industrializa- national commodity markets; tion. HOwever, industrialization, though possible, is a long—term process and does not effect an immediate solu— tion to a short—run problem. The third solution is to establish international and national agencies which, through the use of stabilizing measures, try to counter- act wide fluctuations in export prices and proceeds. The Rationale of Price Stabilization As pointed out earlier on page 16, more stable prices will tend to curtail the expansion of’ output at times when prices have fallen from a level at which expan— sion appeared profitable. But this does not mean that given more stable prices, output of primary commodities will not expand. Output is not determined by market price alone, but determined by the market price in relation to cost of production (including opportunity cost). Output 18 may expand, and expand even too much despite stable prices if the costs of production decline through the use of im- proved production techniques. Conversely, output may de- cline despite stable prices if production costs (including opportunity costs) increase. But the extra inducement of temporary high or low prices (or the extra deterrent of temporary low prices) would not add to or subtract from output induced by changes in the price-cost relationship. Thus, price stabilization would contribute a more stable volume of output and fewer and smaller deviations of mar— ket prices from long-term price trends. Nevertheless, the risk and uncertainty of price instability represents in itself a cost which is partially born by consumers (industrial countries) but mostly borne by producers. The stabilization of export prices would therefore, bring a reduction in costs of production (proportional to the risk premium borne by producers) and at any given price, output will ultimately be expanded due to the more —__ Trade Fluctuations lIbid., J. D. Adler, "Government: ' 159. and Buffer Policies in Low Income Countries,’ 19 favorable price-cost relationship. Lower production costs are to the advantage of primary producers because it means an increase in real income, but given demand elasticities of less than one for primary commodities, the export earn— ings will be smaller. This conclusion seems to defeat the case for international stabilization schemes since more stable prices mean lower costs to producers, lower prices and reduced export earning. The answer to this apparent paradox can be divided in two parts. First, this would be the case if on the one hand, the resources set free as a result of cost saving (due to stable prices) become technologically unemployed or if there is no possibility of replacing the loss of foreign exchange earnings by domestic production or increased production of other com- modities. Resources released from the export sector are usually more efficient than other factors in the economy and therefore could be easily transferred. On the other hand, if the cost reduction is gradual, the transfer is likely to be small or even unnecessary if the gradual up— ward movement of the demand schedules, together with the 1Ibid., 160-61. 20 increase in quantities demanded (on account of lower prices), bring about an increase in the volume of com— modity demanded at the market. Second, most proposals for international schemes have been limited to short—run effects in which the impact on cost is minor, and the main objective has been the protection of producers against permanent losses of foreign exchange. It can be concluded then, that price stabilization is advantageous to primary producers even if it means a decline in export earning in the long run. Stabilization schemes also have some benefits to industrial countries. More stable prices bring about cost savings which partially accrue to the industrial countries as consumers and also provide a more stable supply of primary commodities. Furthermore, violent changes in the price of raw materials and foodstuffs make it difficult for industrial countries to maintain inter- nal stability. However, industrial countries may still lose in the aggregate sense through price stabilization. 21 Stabilization Schemes Given the advantage of long—term price stability, the question of the most suitable stabilization scheme arises. Since the supply conditions (including organization of pro- duction) are so different for each primary commodity (p. 16), there is no ideal scheme. However, irrespective of details, whatever scheme may be advocated, it should interfere as little as possible with the dynamic changes in the supply conditions. This will eliminate from con- sideration the allocation of maximum production or export quotas to exporting countries or individual producers, since fixed quotas would prevent those shifts in output which would result from falling (or rising) production costs. However, since quantity fluctuations and price fluctuations are not independent from one another, most practical forms of price stabilization imply some con- trols of quantities. __¥ 1The United Nations report mentioned previously states that if price fluctuations could be eliminated altogether, only 17 per cent of export proceeds fluctuations will be eliminated. Similarly, elimination of quantity fluctua- tions will only eliminate 39 per cent of instability of proceeds. (U. N., op. cit., 57). Wallich has commented however, that past fluctuation in export proceeds of a few 22 Some of the stabilization schemes suggested in the literature are the following: International Measures The export markets of primary products could be stabilized by means of, first, long-term agreements on prices and/or quantities, either bilateral or multi- lateral, and second, buffer stocks schemes. A fundamental principle of all these schemes should be that they do not attempt to make average prices over a period of years higher or lower than they would otherwise have been. Their objectives should be merely to reduce fluctuations around the long—term trend. Long—term agreements on prices and quantities may be bilateral or multilateral. Bilateral agreements may be convenient or even desirable when one country takes a high proportion of the world exports of a commodity and where exporting countries do not feel the need for con— certed negotiation with the importing country to avoid exploitation. Since contracts will be made with suppliers major commodities are analyzed on the basis of quantities absorbed and not quantities traded. Price fluctuations have accounted for well over 50 per cent of total insta- bilities (wallich, op. cit., 345). 23 at different times, it is probable that, at any one time, different prices will be paid to each but as long as one supplier is not consistently favored over another, the agreement need not be considered discriminatory. Multi— lateral long—term agreements, such as the International Wheat Agreement, could also be feasible for a large num— ber of commodities. The margin between minimum and maxi— mum prices, and the provisions for changes from year to year, can insure a measure of stability for both export~ ing and importing countries while avoiding undue rigidity. The International Coffee Agreement is another instance of multilateral agreements based on quantity. Under this agreement, member countries agree to withhold from the market a certain percentage of their annual production. Individual producers can still expand production if it is to their advantage to do so, as long as the percentage quota is maintained. The "Buffer Stock" schemes provide for the selling or buying commodities as soon as the world market price falls to a predetermined level or rises to a certain maximum level. Between these official buying and selling points, prices would be allowed to fluctuate. Both the support and the ceiling prices would 24 be adjusted from time to time in the light of experience, to take account on long-term changes in demand and supply conditions. Difficulties are bound to rise on account of the natural interest of producers to set buying and sell- ing prices at too high a level. However, the main prac- tical objection is that of finance. The costs of storage are manageable but substantial; nevertheless, the more serious problem is that of providing capital finance re— quired given the volume of trade and surpluses at any given time of most commodities. Furthermore, the buffer stock idea can only be started in periods of recession, not in boom periods. Buffer stock schemes can do a great deal to reduce not only price fluctuations but also fluctuations in for— eign exchange receipts due to swings of demand in import- ing countries. On the other hand, it would not stabil— ize either producer's incomes or exporting countries foreign exchange against fluctuations in the supply of the commodity. Furthermore, since it is never possible to distinguish between a temporary fluctuation and a 25 major change of trend, the setting-up of a buffer stock is necessarily a speculation that may fail.1 Both of the international stabilization measures men— tioned here have the disadvantage that if they are ap— plied only to a few exportable products, they would cre— ate privileges for some countries. They would also cre— ate, within any one country, privileges for certain pro— ducers. Thus they would be liable to attract, especially in times of depression, the available entrepreneurs, labor and capital, to the protected branches. Even if the measures were applied to all exportable commodities, there is a risk of the price stability to discourage ex— pansion of the cultivation of food crops for internal markets.2 National Measures National stabilization schemes are in most cases preferable to international arrangements, not only be— cause of the administrative and political difficulties l . Op. cit., P. T. Bauer, F. W. Parish, "Comment: Trade Fluctuations and Buffer Policies in Low Income Countries," 169. Ibid., Maurice Bye, "Comment: Trade Fluctuations and Buffer Policies in Low Income Countries," 180. 26 unavoidable in the latter, but also because of the static character of such arrangements as the allocation of quotas, which are determined based on the bargaining pow— er of the individual country and past performance rather than on dynamic economic considerations. There are, how— ever, instances where some form of international arrange— ment is preferable, or even essential if stabilization is to be successful; and there are advantages to internation— al arrangements which cannot be obtained through national stabilization schemes. Buffer funds as well as buffer stocks national or international are alternative methods of stabilization available to primary producing countries. They are how- ever, substitutes for each other. The existence of buf- fer stocks would make foreign exchange reserves less necessary and vice versa. Buffer stock's main problem is again that of financing; nevertheless, it has to be remembered that buffer funds have to be "financed" through abstinence in boom periods. This could be a real burden in View of the pressing needs for imports of equipment as well as consumer goods. It will be assumed that primary producing countries are willing to carry 27 the burden in operating a buffer fund of foreign exchange, rather than operating a buffer stock. The purpose of the following alternatives using buf- fer funds is not to reduce variations in the world market prices, but to reduce their impact on the domestic econ- omy by stabilizing the disposable income realized by pri- mary producers. This can be done in three ways: 1) The establishment of a central marketing agency which guar— antees a certain price to domestic producers and sells the products in the export markets for whatever price they may fetch. The domestic price paid to producers can be determined in such a way that it amounts to a tax in good years and a subsidy in bad years, 2) A scheme of essentially the same kind which would operate expressly in the form of variable export taxes and subsidies, 3) The establishment of an exchange control agency which takes over the foreign exchange proceeds of exporters at lower or higher rates of exchange. If its selling rates of foreign exchange remain constant, the agency can Operate to make a profit in periods of high export prices and a loss at other times. 28 All the three alternative methods have in common that they do not interfere with the prices paid by importers or consumers. In contrast to buffer stocks of commodi— ties, buffer funds obtained through the schemes mentioned can be best started when the world demand is booming. The argument in favor of stabilization through mar— keting boards is that they are an effective device for serving the interest of producers and that it is much easier in periods of low prices to subsidize producers from the general funds accumulated by the marketing board than to subsidize them from the general tax reven- ues or reserves of the government. HOwever, this sys- tem may be a less satisfactory device than the other two proposed (variable export taxes alone or variable export taxes and fixed prices paid to producers). This is particularly so in the case of countries where there is a great deal of economic interaction between the export sector and the rest of the economy, and where the level of imports (for the entire economy) and the rate of capital formation depend very much on the performance of the producers of export commodities. In this case, the general welfare of the country (guided by the 29 government) and the welfare of producers (guided by the marketing board) is practically undistinguishable. Differential exchange rates and export tax poli- cies are two different methods of achieving the same end. In other words, differential exchange rate arrangements can be used instead of export taxes. The system of taxing primary producers when their products command a high price abroad and to subsidize them when product prices are low is subject to objec— tions. The effects of this scheme will depend on the elasticity and production conditions of the supply of the commodity considered. If the supply of the commod- ity is quite elastic, then by stabilizing prices re- ceived by producers, this policy interferes with the incentive to produce more when prices are high, and serves to keep production up when export prices are low. It is for this reason that is is suggested that prices are allowed to follow world market prices and that general taxation (through excise revenues, income taxes, and import and export duties) be increased in export booms and reduced in export slumps. In this way a budget surplus could be achieved in export boom periods 30 so as to accumulate the essential buffer fund available for expenditure in depression years, without interfer— ing with incentives to shift resources into or away from export production in response to price changes. However, the possibility of conducting this general counter-cy- clical fiscal policy in underdeveloped countries may be extremely limited. It may very well be that the sim- plest counter-cyclical policy for underdeveloped coun- tries is the direct manipulation of export prices for primary commodities. Although national stabilization schemes will mitigate the effects of price-induced changes in the income of producers, the undesirable ef- fects of the different policies (which among other things, depend on supply conditions of the particular commodities) have to be realized. The Economic Role of Price Fluctuations So much has been said about the detrimental effects of price instabilities on export proceeds that one inad- vertently may acquire the impression that price fluctu— ations are not bad per gg, They constitute the essential 31 mechanism for the allocation of resources.1 Price movements are the warning signal to increase or reduce output of a commodity. Doubts concerning this function of price fluctuations arise from the limited reliability of price signals in the short—run. In the first place, there is the possibility of unre— liable price signals due to short-run speculative as well as cyclical nature of many price movements.2 Secondly, short-run price movements are often misleading; producers may be hesitant to react too rapidly or too intensively to price increases which may later prove to be of a more permanent nature. Conversely, failure of producers to contract production in the event of price declines thought to be of a short-run nature (when they are cyclical), to- gether with a lower inelasticity of supply in periods of falling prices, may lead to surpluses (which in turn have further depressing effects on prices). Finally there is the possibility of the cobweb situation: high prices 102. cit., Wallich, 346. 2Ibid., 246-247. 32 cause overproduction which depresses prices and output; lower prices and reduced output will lead to high prices and renewed overproduction, and so on. To summarize: High price instability is a fact. While recognizing the essential dynamic function of price changes in the allocation of resources, there seems to be a well—supported case to try to counteract violent price fluctuations of primary commodities. Policies designed to counteract price fluctuations are beneficial to both producers and consumers as long as the stabilized prices do not interfere with needed long—run price and output shifts. Relations Between Industrial and Primary Producing Countries: The Prebisch-Singer Thesis for Latin America In 1950, Professor Raul Prebisch hypothesized that economic development in Latin American was being inhibi- ted on account of deteriorating terms of trade.2 He lIbid. United Nations, Economic Commission for Latin America, The Economic Development of Latin American and Its Principal Problems (New YOrk, 1950). 33 used United Nations' figures of Britain's terms of trade between 1876 and 1946 to support his hypothesis. The Prebisch thesis states that the economic advan— tage of the division of labor is theoretically sound but is based on unsound assumptions. According to this assumption, the benefits of technical progress tend to be distributed alike to the whole community, either by lowering of prices or by corresponding rise in income. Countries producing raw materials (peripheral countries) obtain their shares of these benefits through inter- national exchange, and therefore have no need to indus— trialize. If they were to do so, their lesser effi- ciency would result in losing the advantages of such exchange. In practice, however, Prebisch believes that the advantages of technical progress have been concen- trated in the industrial countries of the world (the center) and have not been extended to the countries making up the periphery of the world economic system (primary producers). If prices had behaved according to the classical theory, prices of industrial products would have fallen 1Ibid., 8. 34 relative to primary prices, in response to advances in technology and productivity. If this had happened, " . . . the countries of the periphery would have benee fited from the fall in price of finished products to the same extent as the countries of the center and the benefits of technical progress would have been distri— buted alike throughout the world.”1 However, the reverse has been true. In the 1930's, an average of 58.6 per cent more primary products were needed to buy the same amount of finished industrial products as in the 1960's.2 This led Prebisch to believe that the terms of trade of peripheral countries are deteriora- ting. Prebisch believes that the improvement in terms of trade during 1946-47 in favor of primary producers was the result of war and post war boom in supplies but the general unfavorable trend will eventually be resumed. The trend in deteriorating terms of trade seems to have been resumed during the 1950's. 1Ibid., 8. 2Ibid., 8-9. 35 Prebisch explains the deteriorating terms of trade with the following arguments. On the demand side, the explanation is based on the disparity of income elas- ticity of demand for imports at the center and at the periphery.1 On one hand, the low income elasticity of demand for imports at the center,2 combined with higher rates of output at the periphery which are due to increased productivity, exerted a depressing effect on prices of exports produced at the periphery. On the lRaul Prebisch, "Commercial Policies in Under- developed Countries," American Economic Reviewy Papers and Proceedings (May, 1959), 251—54. Prebisch states that for every one per cent rise in per capita income in the U. S. imports of primary goods tend to increase 0.6 per cent. Robert Lekachman, National Policy for Economic welfare at Home and Abroad, comments by Professor Prebisch, 277-80. 2The low income inelasticity, as well as the low price inelasticity of the imports at the center, are due to the nature of exports from the periphery which are food and raw materials. The lag in the growth of demand for these commodities is either due to the effect of Engle's Law and protective measures on the part of center countries with respect to agricultural commod- ities, or to technological innovations which reduce the proportion of raw materials per unit of output or syn- thetic substitutes. werner Baer, "The Economics of Prebisch and ECLA," Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. XI, No. 2 (January, 1962), 170. 36 other hand, the high income elasticity of demand for imports at the periphery1 tends either to keep the price of imports constant if there is a proportional increase in productivity at the center, or to increase the price of the periphery's imports if such propor— tional increase in productivity does not occur or if market imperfections at the center restrict the supply. On the supply side, the reason suggested for the deterioration of the terms of trade against peripheral countries is that money incomes (and hence prices) have risen more rapidly than productivity in the Center, while in peripheral countries, increases in produc- tivity have been distributed in the form of price re- ductions or only in proportional increases in money income.2 This difference in the behavior of prices in 1The reason for the high income elasticity of demand for imports from the center is that these im- ports consist mostly of capital equipment and machinery needed for development and manufactured goods with high demonstration appeal. 2 . . See also the Singer verSion, p. 40. 37 center and peripheral countries is attributed to the difference of primary product prices and industrial prices over successive business cycles, and to the monopolistic industrial market structure. During the upswing of business cycles, prices of primary products rise more rapidly than industrial prices, but subsequently lose this gain during down- swings. Conversely, although industrial prices rise less rapidly during upswings, they do not fall so far in a downswing as they have risen in prosperity. The rea- son for this is; one, the rigidity of industrial wages caused by the organization of labor.1 and two, price inflexibility in a more monopolistic industrial market.2 Therefore, Prebisch asserts that the gap between indus- trial and primary product prices have progressively widened,3 and peripheral countries have suffered an 1In contrast with a monopolistic organization of labor in the center, Prebisch assumes unlimited sup- plies of labor in peripheral countries. Prebisch, op. cit., "Commercial Policies in Underdeveloped Coun- tries," 255. 2United Nations, op. cit., 12—14. 3Ibid., 10. 38 unfavorable movement in their terms of trade. Thus, " . . . while the centers kept the whole benefit of the technical development of their industries, the pe— ripheral countries transferred to them a share of the fruits of their own technical progress."1 As long as these phenomena occur, it follows that productivity of industrial centers exerts a retarding effect on the development of peripheral countries.2 Unless some kind of counteraction is taken, the long—run prognosis is for continued deterioration of the relative trade posi- tion of peripheral areas. Consequently, policies should be enforced to prevent transfers of income (in the form of lower prices) to center countries and to protect the periphery's capacity to import. According to Prebisch, to achieve this purpose, government inter- ference with the import and export trade, in the form of protection, subsidies, export taxes or any other form 1Ibid. 2In fact, Prebisch states: "The high productivity of the great industrial countries is one of the greatest obstacles which the peripheral countries must overcome in order to achieve a similar degree of productivity.” United Nations, Economic Survey of Latin America, 1949 (New Ybrk: 1951), 173. 39 of interference is required. The best way to counter- act the 1ong-run tendencies of deteriorating terms of trade is through a policy of selective protection of import substituting industries.1 The criterion of the feasibility of import substituting industries is not relative efficiencies of industrial production in the usual sense, but the establishment or expansion of local industries which contribute (or would contribute) most to national income. In other words, protection is eco- nomically justified when the possible loss caused by the fall in export prices (due to expansion and increased productivity of traditional exports) is greater than the higher cost of internal production in relation to imports. In Prebisch's words, It is not really a question of comparing industrial costs with import prices but of comparing the incre- ment of income obtained in the expansion of industry with that which could be obtained in export activi— ties had the same productive resources been employed there.2 Raul Prebisch, op. cit., “Commercial Policies . . ." 255. 2Ibid., 255. 40 Although Prebisch warns that protectionistic policies are beneficial as long as they are not exaggerated to shelter inefficiency,1 the application of such poli- cies by some Latin American countries has resulted in the creation of inefficient industries and economic unbalances, as will be pointed out later. The Singer Version writing about the same time, Hans Singer presented a very similar argument to that of Prebisch.2 Singer begins his argument by exploring the role of foreign investment in underdeveloped countries which has been mainly concentrated in primary production. He con- cludes that foreign investment by industrial countries has detrimental effects on primary producers for two reasons: first, because secondary multiplier and back— wash effects of foreign investment have returned to the investing countries, and second, because foreign 1Ibid., 257. Hans Singer, "The Distribution of Gains Between Investing and Borrowing Countries," American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings (May, 1950), 477-85. 41 investments have diverted underdeveloped countries into primary production (which offers less scope for technical progress, internal and external economies), and withheld productive efforts from the "central factor of dynamic radiation," industrialization.l Singer states that the most important factor which has reduced the benefits of foreign trade—cum—investment to underdeveloped countries, has been the deteriora- tion of the terms of trade. He dismisses the possi- bility that the deterioration of the terms of trade reflects the relative changes in real cost of manu- factured exports of industrial countries relative to those of food and raw materials of primary producers, since productivity has increased more rapidly in the former than in the latter. Moreover, The possibility that changing price relations could merely reflect relative trends in produc- tivity may be considered as disposed of by the very fact that the standards of living in indus- trialized countries (largely governed by produc- tivity in manufacturing industries) have risen demonstrably faster than standards of living in underdeveloped countries (generally governed by productivity in agriculture and primary produc- tion) over the last sixty or seventy years. 1Ibid., 477. 2Ibid., 478. 42 Having dismissed changes in productivity as a govern- ing factor in explaining the deterioration of the terms of trade, Singer turns to another explanation. Singer believes that in industrial countries the benefits of technical progress have been distributed to producers primarily through higher incomes rather than to con— sumers in the form of lower prices. However, in under— developed nations, Singer feels that producers have suf- fered and consumers have gained lower prices as a re- sult of technical prOgress. Since both Prebisch and Singer agreed on the deteri- oration of the terms of trade against primary producers, their thesis has come to be known as the Prebisch-Singer thesis. Criticism of the Prebisch—Singer Thesis Criticism of the Prebisch—Singer thesis has been rather extensive. One criticism is based on the statis— tical inadequacy of Britain's terms of trade since the 1870's-—the empirical evidence used by Prebisch and Singer for their arguments. On one hand, the commodity 43 terms of trade are thought to be an inadequate measure because: It is clearly possible that a country's income terms of trade and single-factoral terms of trade may improve at the same time as its commodity terms deteriorate. Also, trade statistics give no weight to the gain in utility from new commodities which have become available during the period considered.2 Moreover, even "where the manufacturers are nominally the same, they are over the years incomparably superior in quality, . . . whereas primary commodities used in price indexes . . . are for the most part . . . not superior in quality and in some cases inferior."3 On the other hand, long-run period terms of trade are misleading since the British terms of trade were based on C.I.F. import prices and 1Gerald M. Meier, "Export Stimulation, Import Sub- stitution and Latin American Development," Social and Economic Studies, Vol. X, No. 1 (March, 1961), 53. 2Jacob Viner, International Trade and Economic Development (Glencoe, Illinois: 1952), 143. See also Gottfried Haberler, "International Trade and Economic Development," in National Bank of Egypt, Fiftieth Anniversapy Commemoration Lectures (Cairo, 1959), 19. 3Ibid. 44 F.0.B. export prices. This means that the import prices included transport costs while export prices did not.1 One of the most vehement critics of this thesis, Professor Haberler questions both the empirical evi- dence and the assumption of the deterioration of terms of trade for primary producers. He states that: This alleged historical trend is supposed to be the consequence of deep-seated factors and hence capable of confident extrapolation into the future. To my mind the alleged historical facts lack proof, their explanation is faulty, the extrapolation reckless and the policy conclusions irresponsible to put it mildly.2 Haberler denies the validity of Prebisch's assertion that prices of industrial products are kept high by monopolistic behavior of labor unions and cartels. It is true that industrial progress in the devel— oped countries rarely takes the form of constant money wages and money incomes associated with falling prices, but rather the form of constant 1 Primary Producing and Industrial Countries, American Economic Affairs, Vol. X, No. 1 (Summer, 1956), 55-57. P. J. Ellsworth, "The Terms of Trade Between ” Inter— 2Gottfried Haberler, "Critical Observations on Some Current thions in the Theory of Economic Devel- Opment," L'industria (No. 2, 1957), 8. 45 (or even rising) prices associated with rising money wages. . . . but there is no evidence that it has changed relative prices as between industry and agriculture or between finished goods and raw materials.1 NOr will Haberler accept the "heavy burden” that this theory places on Engle's Law in explaining the slow growth of demand for food and primary products in indus- trial countries. Although this Law applies to food in general, it does not apply to every kind of food, and it is not clear that rising incomes lead in every case to a proportional decline in the demand for raw mate— rials. Finally Haberler believestflwm even if evidence clearly shows that the terms of trade have deteriorated in the last century, policy conclusions cannot be de- rived from these facts unless it is certain that the deterioration is likely to continue.2 Recent studies have given additional support to the Prebisch—Singer thesis.3 A recent study, based on lIbid., 9. 21bid., 8-9. 3 M. K. Atallah, "The Long-term Movement of the Terms of Trade Between Agricultural and Industrial Countries," (Rotterdam, 1958), summarized in Benjamin Higgins, Economic Development (New YOrk: W.W. Norton & Co., 1960), 375, and C. P. Kindleberger, "The Terms of Trade and Economic Devel- opment," The‘Review of Economics and Statistics, Supplement (February, 1958), 85. ‘— 46 empirical evidence, reaches the following conclu- sions: Even if some of the doubts expressed concerning the validity of the long-run downward tendency of the terms of trade are correct, it seems fairly clear that over long and crucial periods of time in the twentieth century terms of trade have been declin- ing for many peripheral areas. And the few per— iods of primary materials boom were not sufficient to build up enough reserves for adverse periods. This has been especially true for the greater part of the 1950's, when concern for economic develop— ment has become increasingly important. With reference to Prebisch's explanation for the deterioration of the terms of trade and their effects for peripheral countries, Baer concluded that the ". . . low income elasticities of Center countries and high in- come elasticities for peripheral countries has validity 2 for many important areas in the world." Moreover, although it is difficult to prove that the unfavorable terms of trade for peripheral countries are partially due to monopolistic pricing at the center and greater degree of competition at the periphery, this study adds support to the Prebisch-Singer thesis. lW. Baer, op. cit., 179. 47 Thus it can be concluded that productivity condi- tions and changes in international demand have handi- capped or diminished the relative benefits of inter- national trade that can accrue to primary producing countries such as those in Latin America. However, to conclude from that that the concentration of primary production has been one of the principal inhibiting factors of Latin America's long-run economic develop- ment seems to be an over simplification of the complex aspects of Latin American development. Some of the responsibility for the slow rate of economic growth in Latin America obviously can be attributed to fiscal and economic policies pursued by the governments of the various countries as well as to the political, and social organizations of the nations.1 Moreover, Meier points out that market imperfections in primary pro- ducing countries (such as ignorance of market condi- tions, factor immobility, restrictive tendencies both in the factor and goods market, monopolistic and 1B. A. Rogge, ”Economic Development in Latin America: The Prebisch Thesis," Inter—American Economic Affairs, Vol. IX, No. 4 (Spring, 1956), 34. 48 semi-monopolistic practices, restraints on land ten- ure, marketing facilities and capital markets) suggest that in the past, domestically—based impediments to development have been more influential than any obsta- cle attributable to international forces. Moreover, Meier believes that these domestic impediments have not only reduced the "gains from trade" but also the "gains from growth" that can emerge from the former.1 Policy conclusions derived from deteriorating terms of trade argument have not gone unchallenged either. ECLA's doctrine of accelerated industrialization and ‘import substitution has been criticized by Meier; he believes that although there is a place for import substitution, in order to achieve a higher rate of growth, Latin American countries cannot afford to em- phasize replacement of industrial imports at the ex- pense of policies designed to increase productivity, diversification of primary production, and replacement . . 2 . . . . of agricultural imports. Meier's critiCism of ECLA's 1Gerald M. Meier, op. cit., 54. 21bid., 62. 49 economic policy is based both on general principles and on empirical studies of Latin America's replacement of industrial imports and general production conditions in the post-war period. According to Meier, the post—war Latin American economic performance has been rather discouraging. Although aggregate agricultural production has increased over prewar level in absolute terms, the rate of growth has failed to keep up with industrial expansion and popu- lation growth. Agricultural exports have grown on an absolute basis (12 per cent increase in 1955/56 over 1949/50) but have actually decreased on per capita basis. The growth rate of mineral production has fallen substantially behind world rates of mineral production except for iron ore and crude petroleum. The reasons for these slow rates of growth of pro- duction are to be found in economic and monetary poli- cies of the particular governments. In many cases, the increase in the money supply has not increased aggre- gate demand and the use of underemployed resources, but 1Meier, op. cit., 60-62. 50 has led to inflation. Industrialization programs have withdrawn labor from agriculture and without a change in the other factors agricultural output per capital has declined.1 This suggests that disguised unemploy— ment is not wide-spread. Moreover, inflationary trends have tended to maintain investment in agriculture at low levels and actually decreased in per capita abso— lute terms. All these factors plus the lack of an ef- fective program of agricultural development have caused a decline in agricultural output per person. In order to satisfy the rising demand for agricultural products, many Latin American countries have imported food. Moreover, due to foreign exchange shortages, agricul- tural imports have had to be controlled. As a result, prices of agricultural products have risen more rapidly than the general price level. Based on this evidence, Meier concludes that the concentration of limited financial and human resources on industrialization pro- grams, the attraction of productive resources to the industrial sector, and the inflationary consequences Ibid., 60. 51 of industrialization, have handicapped primary pro- duction.1 With respect to industrial import substi- tution policies, Meier observes that: From the general arguments against the replacement of industrial imports and the particular experi- ences of Latin American economies during the post- war period, we may suggest that the development of primary production and the promotion of exports should have higher priority than import replacement. Although under certain conditions there is place for import substitution, its role is limited, it has generally resulted in higher prices, excess capacity in the import competing industries, and a domestic product of inferior quality. Moreover, to the extent that import substitution has been directed to industrial products that have re— quired capital-intensive methods of production, it has failed to absorb as much labor as would more labor-intensive activities. NOr has the expansion of industries producing non-durables allowed the highest possible net saving of imports (that is, the value of imports replaced minus direct and indirect costs of equipment, operating and maintaining the industry).2 lIbid. 2Meier, op. cit., 62. The last point mentioned in the quotation is by no means the one advocated by ECLA with respect to the feasibility of import replacement industries. According to Prebisch, protection is economically justified when the possible fall in export prices is greater than the higher cost of internal production in relation to imports (see page 39). 52 In View of the experience with import replacing industries, and the relatively stagnant agricultural production, Meier concludes that ". . . it would appear more desirable to concentrate the import replacement programmes in the direction of foodstuffs and raw mate- rials."1 Policies helping to achieve this purpose would not only lessen the dependence on imports, but would also improve the balance of payments situation to the same extent as would the replacement of industrial products. In addition, agricultural products and raw material import replacement policies would have the ad- vantage of not adversely affecting exports or contri- bute to the establishment of uneconomic industries. The Role of Agriculture in External Balance and Internal Growth In the preceding sections of the chapter, we have explored some of the problems and disadvantages in- volved in the specialization of production in agricul- tural and raw materials for export. There are, however, Ibid. Ibid. 53 a number of important functions that agriculture per- forms in the process of economic development. The discussion which follows relates agriculture's role in economic development through its contribution to external balance and internal growth of a nation. Agriculture's Role in External Balance The principal role of agriculture in external bal— ance is as a source of foreign exchange for capital This imports required in the process of development. means that as a nation's export agriculture expands, export earnings will likely increase. This will en- able a nation to increase its capital imports in the 4! form of products or equipment which it obtains at a lower cost than they could possibly obtain from in- digenous sources. Some economists contend that mar- ket instabilities and the inelastic world demand for primary products act as an important constraint on the economic development of primary producers. Their policy prescriptions are that these nations should diversify their economies and emphasize industrial production rather than the output of primary products. Morgan, however, points out that: 54 High price instability for primary products is a fact. But are the policy implications valid? Price varia- tion is not an argument for staying out of a given line of production, but rather for a discount on (aver- age) returns--for calculating whether expected net re- turns minus expected net returns in each of the alter- natives. Such calculations will often lead to some diversification, but it will not lead to a flat choos- ing of unremunerative price—stable production. Thus, while in the long run, it may be feasible to em- phasize industrial production, of greater immediate impor- tance is the function of present day exports in providing the foreign exchange required for capital imports which would allow long-run economic development and lessen de— pendence on export proceeds. Furthermore, present day exports not only cmxu to an existing foreign market but also, may face a relatively elastic demand schedule in the short run. The reason being that exports of any given country probably account for only small percentage of the world's trade in the commodity or commodities concerned; therefore, a country can expand its exports without causing any significant decline in prices. _ l . . Theodore Morgan, "Comment: Some Interrelationships Between Agricultural Trade and Economic Development," Boris C. Swerling's paper presented at a Social Science Research Council Meeting at Stanford University (NOvember, 1960), 4. 55 Diversification of exports, while not reducing the dependence on export proceeds, can provide a more stable flow of foreign exchange by spreading the risk of single price declines over wider range of commodities. A prof- itable export crop can frequently be added to an existing cropping system. Some writers believe that the capital requirements for such innovations are often moderate and largely dependent on direct, non—monetary investment by farmers. It must also be remembered that considerable real income to launch development programs can be amassed during periods of high-import prices. Domestic markets of most underdeveloped countries are, in general, too small to justify the establishment of industries pro— ducing capital goods which are essential for the success of any development program. In addition, the possibil- ity of developing a sufficiently large market are lim- ited. Therefore even when considering long~run develop- ment, the maintenance of an ever-growing supply of 1B. F. Johnston and J. W. Mellor, ”The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development,” American Economic Review, Vol. LI (September, 1961), 575. 56 imports is of prime importance. Unless domestic indus— tries achieve a degree of efficiency and productivity sufficient enough to make their products competitive in international markets, agricultural exports will have to pay for capital imports. In summary, the expansion of agricultural export production is sometimes a promising and rational means of augmenting foreign exchange earnings despite unfavorable world supply-demand conditions. Neglect of the export producing sector of an economy, combined with a rising demand for imports, have often resulted in balance of payment problems and external imbalances. Agriculture's Role in Internal Growth Agriculture can play an important role in the inter- nal growth of an economy by: a) providing increased food supplies, b) releasing labor to non-agricultural sectors, c) contributing to capital formation, and d) providing a market for industrial products. 57 Providing Increased Food Supplies Apart from autonomous changes in demand, the annual rate of increase in demand for food depends on the rate of population growth, per capita income and the income elasticity of demand. A growing food supply is of major significance in underdeveloped countries. The rapid rate of population growth which many underdeveloped countries are exper— iencing exerts great pressures on the available supplies of food. Furthermore, the improvement in nutritional standards resulting from increased incomes, accentuate this problem. Annual rates of population growth of 3 per cent of higher are not uncommon in underdeveloped countries. In the case of Latin America, which is ex- periencing average annual rates of population growth as high as 2.7 per cent,1 this factor alone accounts for a substantial increase in demand for food. Secondly, not only large proportions of per capita income are spent on food, but also the income elasticity of demand for foodstuffs, is very high in underdeveloped countries. 1"Latin America: A Decade of Decision," Population Bulletin, Vol. XVII, No. 2 (April, 1961), 21. 58 It has been estimated that the income elasticity of demand for food in Latin America is about 0.7 on the average. With per capita income rising in the process of development, high income elasticities of demand for food, high rates of population growth, together with high percentages of total consumption spent on food, increased food supplies are of primary importance. Failure of supply of food to keep up to the growth of demand may have adverse effects on underdeveloped nations. On the one hand, demand pressures on scarce supplies are likely to result in substantial rises in food prices. The inflationary impact of a proportional increase in food prices upon the general price level is more severe in underdeveloped countries than in dev- eloped ones because of the higher proportion of income spent on food and the higher income elasticity of demand in the former than the latter. A rise in food prices may lead to political discontent if there is a l . T. W. Schultz, "Prospects of Primary Products," Economic Development for Latin America, op. cit., 316. 59 lag in increases in wage rates and salaries. Moreover, higher wages may lead to lower industrial profits and to a slower rate of economic growth. On the other hand, if supplies fail to keep in pace with the growth in demand for food, a nation may expand food imports which compete with capital imports for foreign exchange and thereby slow down the rate of growth. Transfer of Manpower from Agricultural to Non—agricul- tural Sectors. The assumption that the marginal productivity of labor in agriculture is zero or even negative, is a factor very frequently cited. If this assumption is valid, it follows that labor can be transferred from agriculture to manufacturing or other expanding sectors, without any appreciable effect on agricultural output. However,the presence of disguised unemployment in agriculture is debatable, at least in some parts of the world. Experiences in Latin America suggest that dis- guised unemployment does not exist,1 or that its presence cannot be substantiated by empirical evidence.2 1See page 50 . 2 Op. cit., 321. 60 Even if disguised unemployment does not exist, the agricultural sector constitutes an important reservoir of labor. Productivity increases in agriculture will make it possible for labor to be transferred to other sectors, without adverse effects on agricultural out- put. In fact, the agricultural sector will benefit from this transfer. As labor is transferred, pres- sures on land are reduced and consolidation of farms is facilitated. Agriculture's Contribution to Capital Formation Underdeveloped nations striving to achieve eco~ nomic progress are faced with large requirements of capital for investment in manufacturing and other productive enterprises, social overhead facilities and human capital investment. Agriculture can make impor- tant contributions to capital formation, particularly in early stages of development when the capital inten- sive sector is relatively small. The sheer size of the agricultural sector, as the major existing indus- try, indicates its importance as a source of capital for general economic development. Agriculture's net 61 contribution to capital formation can be increased by means of rising productivity through the reorgan- ization of resources already committed to agricultural production, or through moderate capital outlays on present patterns of production. Johnston and Mellor feel that the latter prospect has been generally under- emphasized by some economists. If productivity gains are passed to consumers in the form of lower prices, the internal terms of trade will not deteriorate, or even improve in favor of the industrial sector. Con- versely, if productivity gains are retained by pro- ducers in the form of higher incomes, they can be off— set by other means--land or income taxes or both. With respect to the role of agriculture's contri— bution to capital formation, Johnston and Mellor have stated that: The conclusion suggested to strongly by both theo- retical considerations and historical experience is that in underdeveloped countries, where agriculture accounts for some 40 to 60 per cent of the total national income, the transition from a level of savings and investment that spells stagnations to one permitting a tolerable rate of economic growth cannot be achieved unless agriculture makes a 62 significant net contribution to capital formation in the expanding sectors.l Agriculture as a Market for Industrial Products Agriculture provides a substantial market for in— dustrial goods and many industrial projects can direct their production toward the agrarian sector. Agricul— ture provides a potential market for manufactured products; not only goods for human consumption but also capital input goods. The development of this agricultural market will depend to a great extent on the increment in real in- come of the rural population which will tend to shift agriculture's demand for industrial products. If, on one hand, agriculture's purchases of indus— trial products emphasize human consumption goods, agriculture's contribution to capital formation for overall economic development can be substantially reduced. If, on the other hand, increases in real income in the rural sector are used for industrial 1B. F. Johnston, J. W. Mellor, o . cit., 579. 63 capital input purchases, the contribution to capital formation will be reduced at any given time but pro- ductivity increases will make possible a larger con- tribution in succeeding periods. Therefore, although agriculture's contribution to capital formation for overall development and increased purchasing power of the rural population are conflicting issues, they are not mutually exclusive. Moreover, substitution of domestic output for imported manufactured products often provides a significant addition to demand which does not depend on real income increases. Summary Primary producers are often confronted with two main problems in their relations with industrial countries: first, instability of export proceeds on account of price instability of primary products and second, a relative decrease in the capacity to import due to the deterioration of their terms of trade. Industrialization has frequently been suggested as the structural solution to both of these problems affecting the external balance of primary producers. 64 Industrialization, however, is a long—run process which does not offer an immediate solution to the price instability problem. A number of national and international policies and programs are now being used to counteract price instabilities of primary products. Many others have been proposed. It can be concluded that there is no ”best” price stabilization policy since every policy must take into considera— tion the unique supply—demand and production condi- tions of the commodity in question. Whichever poli- cy is advocated, in order for it to be beneficial to both producers and consumers, the stabilized price should not interfere with long-run price shifts. Finally, price instability is not an argument to stay out of a given line of production. On the contrary, price instability merely requires that the discounted average expected returns in primary production be com— pared with alternative production possibilities. When this allowance is taken into consideration, it is often Wise for a nation to continue placing a high priority on producing primary products in order to earn for- eign exchange. 65 Industrialization has often been suggested as the solution to deteriorating terms of trade. In order to maintain the capacity to import, to increase employment and to prevent relative income transfers to industrial countries, it has been advocated that primary producers (especially in Latin America) accelerate industriali- zation. Over the past ten years, an increasing number of Latin American countries have concentrated scarce human and financial resources on import replacing indus- trialization programs at the expense of agricultural and other primary production. According to Meier, indus— trialization policies in Latin America in recent years have led to higher prices, failure to absorb labor sur- pluses, failure to allow the highest possible net sav- ings of imports, excess industrial capacity and in some cases, the establishment of industries with heavy import requirements. Moreover, the neglect of agriculture and other primary production has often resulted in stagnant rates of growth in these activities and food shortages Which, in many instances, have had to be met by agricul— tural imports. To overcome these numerous difficulties, it has been suggested by some economists that Latin 66 American countries should expand their output of food and primary products and place less emphasis on import replacement industries. Agricultural exports can contribute to the external balance and internal growth of a nation by paying for capital imports required for economic development. Agriculture also has two important contributions to the internal growth of a nation. First, agriculture must provide increased food supplies for higher incomes and a growing population. Second, agriculture is an impor- tant source of revenue for capital formation required for general economic development. Moreover, agricul- ture can provide the labor force required by other ex— panding sectors, as well as serving as a major market for industrial products. 67 CHAPTER II SCOPE OF THE THESIS General Considerations In the preceding chapter we have explored the litera- ture and current thought pertaining to four topics in particular; a) economics and economic characteristics of small nations, b) the instability of international mar- kets and stabilization schemes for primary producing countries, c) the problems of deteriorating terms of trade against primary producers and finally, d) the con- tribution of agriculture to economic development through external balance and internal growth. Costa Rica is a small underdeveloped nation of one and one—quarter million people. Moreover, as is char- acteristic of most underdeveloped countries, it relies very heavily on agricultural export proceeds and indus- trial imports for its economic welfare and development. Cost Rica is therefore, subject to and affected by instabilities of international markets. In addition, the terms of trade affect Costa Rica's development possibili- ties. Moreover, being primarily an agricultural country, 68 agriculture plays a very important role in the external balance and internal growth of Costa Rica. Chapter I has provided a theoretical framework of the economic instability of primary production and the terms of trade with special reference to Latin America. My purpose now is to turn to Costa Rica and in remain- ing chapters to present empirical data on each of the four aspects outline above. This analysis will enable us to appraise the performance of the country's agri— culture and its contribution to the growth and develop- ment of Costa Rica. General Literature on Costa Rican Development There is a relative scarcity of literature dealing with Cost Rican development. I have therefore, had to rely considerably on raw data published by the various official agencies of the Government of Costa Rica. To my knowledge, the only literature on Cost Rica's eco- nomic development available at the present, are the following publications: a) a 1952 publication by May, Faaland, Kock, Parsons and Senior on Costa Rica's 69 economic development1 covering the 1940—1950 period with special emphasis on the second half of the 1940's, b) a series of three studies prepared by the Economic Development Project of the University of Costa Rica: one covers the External Sector of the Costa Rican Economy2 during the period 1946—1954, a second one studies the Industrial Sector3 during 1946—1957, and the third one deals with the Agricultural Sector4 during the 1950-1956 period, and c) a United Nations' study pre- pared by Louis Ducoff5 which deals with the human resources lStacy May et a1, Costa Rica: A Study in Economic Dev— elopment (New York: The Twentieth Century Fund, New York, 1952). 2 . . . . UniverSidad de Costa Rica, El Desarrollo Economico de Costa Rica-Sector Externo (Ciudad Universitaria, 1958). 3Ibid., Estudio del Sector Industrial, (1959). 4 Ibid., Estudio del Sector Agropecuario, (1959). 5 . . . . . . United Nations, ComiSion Economica para la America Latina, Los Recursos Humanos de Centroamerica, Panama y Mexico en 1950—1980 (New York: 1960). 70 of Central America, Mexico and Panama and their relations to some aspects of economic development. Statement of the Thesis Problem In view of May's study of Costa Rican economic devel- opment for the 1940-1950 period, the purpose of the thesis is to analyze the role and performance of Costa Rica's agriculture in the external balance and internal growth of the Costa Rican economy during the ten—year period, 1950-1959. Methodology and Procedure The organization of the remainder of the thesis is as follows: Chapter Three depicts the general characteristics of Costa Rica. It deals with geographical and historical aspects, political organization, major public institutions aiding economic development in Cost Rica, international ties and demographic characteristics of the population. Chapter Four presents a brief review of Cost Rica's economic history since the 1930's and explores the per- formance of the Costa Rican economy during the period 71 1950-1959 using national income statistics. These national income data for Costa Rica are analyzed by using seven different statistical methods presently available for the computation of annual growth rates. Chapter Five discusses the social and economic organization of Costa Rica's agriculture, such as agri- cultural regions, land use, land distribution, etc. In addition, it covers trends in production of principal crops and livestock. The contributions of agriculture to the internal growth and balance of Costa Rica's economy are explored in Chapter Six. This chapter presents agriculture's contribution to Gross Domestic Product and its growth during the period considered, as well as the influence of agricultural prices on the general price level. More- over, the principal agencies responsible for Costa Rican agricultural development are examined. The role of Costa Rica's agriculture in external balance is covered in Chapter Seven. This chapter deals with exports, imports and their composition, balance of trade and balance of payments situations, terms of trade, export price stability, etc. 72 Finally, Chapter Eight summarizes the findings of the thesis and their implications for future development. 73 CHAPTER III GENERAL CHARACTERISTICS OF COSTA RICA The purpose of this chapter is to delineate the social, political and historical aspects of Costa Rica in order to understand better the economic problems which are discussed in later chapters. Historical Characteristics Costa Rica is located in the central part of the American Isthmus. This small country of 23,000 square miles borders with Nicaragua in the North, Panama in the South, the Pacific Ocean in the west and the Atlantic Ocean in the East. Costa Rica was discovered by Christopher Columbus in September, 1502. Columbus landed at Cariari (Port Limon) on Costa Rica's Atlantic Coast on his fourth and last trip to the New werld. The Pacific Coast of the country was later explored (1519) by the Spanish Conquerors. The conquest of Costa Rica was terminated in 1564 with the founding of Cartago by the Adelantado Mayor Don Juan Vazquez de Coronado. Cartage was the capital of the Ducado de Veragua (Costa Rica). 74 Costa Rica acquired its independence from Spain on September 15, 1821, and became a member of the Central American Federation. In 1848, Costa Rica was separated from the Federation and became an independent and free nation. Political Organization of Costa Rica Political Division The Costa Rican territory is divided into seven provinces, sixty-five cantones (counties) and 326 dis- tricts. Each province is governed by a Governor ap- pointed by the President of the Republic. Cantones are in turn governed by a board elected by universal suffrage. Government Costa Rica has a centralized government with three distinct and independent powers: Legislative, Executive and Judicial. The Legislative power is in the hands of a Legisla- tive Assembly of forty-five members elected for four year terms. Members of the Assembly cannot be re-elected for successive terms. 75 Bills may originate at the Assembly or at the Execu- tive branches of the government via members of the Cabinet. They ordinarily become laws upon a simple majority vote of the chamber and approval of the President, although certain laws are required by the Constitution to have larger majorities. The Executive Power is vested in the President of the Republic and the Ministers of Government. There are two vice-presidents who along with the President are elected by universal suffrage. The presidential term is for four years beginning May 8th. The Judicial Power is vested in the Supreme Court of Justice which appoints its own personnel and that of other courts. The Judicial branch of the government consists of L sixty-one Alcaldias (Justice of Peace Courts), twenty—two Lower Courts, fourteen Labor Courts, a Court of Cassation (with five Magistrados or member Judges of the Supreme Court. The Plenary Court consists of seventeen Magistrados; five from the Court of Cassation, twelve from the Civil Courts of Appeal and the Penal Courts of Appeal. The fifteen Magistrados constitute the Supreme Court of Justice. Magistrates of the Supreme Court are elected for 76 eight year periods and are regarded as re—elected for a like period unless the Legislative Assembly decides other- wise by a vote of two-thirds of the entire membership of the Chamber. Suffrage and Elections Suffrage is exercised under the supervision of election boards by universal, secret and compulsory vote by citi— zens registered in the Civil Register. The organization, direction and supervision of acts relating to suffrage are exclusively a function of the Supreme Tribunal of Elections, which is an independent agency carrying out this function. This Tribunal is composed of three principal Magistrates and three alternate ones appointed by the Supreme Court of Justice by a vote of not less than two-thirds of its member— ship. They are elected for six terms and enjoy the same immunities and prerogatives as are granted to the three powers into which the government is divided. Decisions of the Supreme Tribunal of Elections cannot be appealed ex- cept on grounds of prevaricato (betrayal of trust). 77 Local Government For the purpose of public administration, the Costa Rican territory is divided into seven provinces, these in turn into sixty-five cantones and the latter in terms of distritos (326). The administration of local interest of each cantén is vested in a Municipal Government consisting of Regidores elected by universal suffrage for a four year term. These positions are compulsory and honorary. An Executive Offi— cial is appointed by the Regidores, who is traditionally the Governor of the Province. Municipal corporations are autonomous. Each district is represented in the Munici— pal Assembly of the Cantén by a Sindico with right of discussion but no vote. Municipalities require authori— zation from the Legislative Assembly to contract loans, to mortgage their property or to alienate real or removable property. 78 Major Institutions in the Public Sector An important role of government is to create and en- courage the development of the proper ”environmental conditions” in which economic activity and economic growth are to occur. The institutional framework is an important element in creating conditions which are pro— pitious to economic growth, especially in the early stages. In some instances, the institutional organiza— tion of governments may inhibit and curtail economic growth; in such cases, institutional changes are re- quired to facilitate progress. Gorwth—promoting insti- tutions, whether in the private or in the public sector, have a very prominent and important function in the process of economic growth. In fact, Wolf has stated that: Institutions--as well as capital and technology—- are protective; or, more accurately, different insti- tutions have differentially productive consequences. Growth-promoting institutions, without themselves adding resources to the economy--or at least by a process that is distinguishable from any resources which they directly add—-may so restructure the en— vironment in which factors of production meet that the rate at which combinations occur is accelerated.1 lCharles Wblf, Jr., "Institutions and Economic Develop- ment,” reprinted in Okun and Richardson, Studies in Economic Development (New Ybrk: Ho1t, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1961), 349. 79 Since the importance of institutions in economic development cannot be underestimated, we intend to ex- plore, in the following pages, some of Costa Rica's major institutions in the public sector. These insti- tutions are the Ministries of Government, their spec- ialized agencies, and the Autonomous Institutions of the State. Ministries of Govepppent and Specialized Agencies All Ministries of Government have a direct or indi- rect role in stimulating economic development. However, only the Ministries of Economics and Revenue, Agriculture and Livestock, Industries, Public werks and Public Edu- cation have a specific commitment to development. These Ministries have specialized agencies which are responsi- ble for research and policy prescription to be followed or pursued; they are, in fact, advisory departments to the pertinent Ministries in policy issues. Ministry of Economics and Revenue The General Direction of Economics is the most important agency within this Ministry. The duties of this agency are, among others, the coordination of all 80 activities leading to the Central American Economic Integration. Furthermore, it makes recommendations in matters pertaining to international treaties and agree— ments and controls ceiling prices of consumption goods in the domestic market. Ministry of Industries The most important agency in the Ministry of Indus— tries is the General Direction of Industries which has direct control over all matters pertaining to the indus- trial development except in those aspects pertaining to credit and the application of industrial laws. Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock The General Direction of Agriculture of this Ministry is responsible for studies and policy pertaining to agri- culture, livestock, forestry and extension services. Ministries of Public werks and Public Education The Ministry of Public werks has the responsibility to construct and maintain the road network as well as other public works. 81 The Ministry of Public Education controls and super- vises all educational establishments in Costa Rica with the exception of the University of Costa Rica. Tariff Commission The Tariff Commission is an independent official agency designed to study and make recommendations per- taining to tariff and import duty policies. Recommenda- tions made by this organism are enacted and enforced by the General Direction of Economics. Autonomous Institutions As the name implies, autonomous institutions are official institutions independent of the centralized government. They were organized to permit technical and administrative expansion of the State, yet avoiding the hazard of excessive accumulation of political authority and new functions in the hands of the State.1 Autono- mous institutions are relatively new, most having been created after 1949. Together they now form a highly lRodrigo Facio, Planificacién Econémica en Regimen Democratico (San José, Costa Rica: 1959), 54. This docu— ment was published in full in Universidad de Costa Rica, Revigta de Ciencies Sociales, No. 4 (September, 1959). 82 important and significant feature of the economy. These autonomous institutions of the State are controlled by boards of directors of five to seven members, in most cases appointed by the President of the Republic. In case of a change of national political administration, control of the board of directors of the institutes cannot change except when the membership expires. Among the autonomous institutions are the Nationalized Banking System, the National Production~Council, the Costa Rican Institute of Electricity, the National Institute of Housing and Urbanization, the University of Costa Rica, the Pacific Electric Railway, the Social Security Board and the National Insurance Agency. Nationalized Banking System The Costa Rican banking system consists of the Cen- tral Bank, the National Bank of Costa Rica, the Anglo- Costa—Rican Bank, the Bank of Costa Rica, Lyon Bank and the Bank of Agricultural Credit of Cartago. The Central Bank is designed to promote the orderly development of the Cost Rican economy with the purpose of achieving the highest possible utilization of the productive resources of the Nation. For this purpose, 83 the Bank has the complete cooperation and support of the State, its dependences and institutions. In 1957 the Bank created the Section for the Preparation of Specific Investment Projects to encourage the investment in certain priority projects. The National Bank of Costa Rica was established in 1914 under the name of The International Bank of Costa Rica. This Bank, as well as other banks which were pri- vate at one time, has the duty to finance those banking operations related to the development of agriculture, livestock and industrial production; to stimulate savings; to promote agricultural credit and the economic and soc- ial conditions of producers. The National Bank of Costa Rica administers the Costa Rican Agricultural Credit Sys- tem (Juntas Rurales de Crédito Agricola). In addition to the above mentioned duties, these banks are supposed to encourage the creation and expansion of new and exist- ent industrial enterprises; to foster and encourage the cooperative movement and to collaborate in the applica— tion of fiscal policy of the Republic. 84 National Production Council The National Production Council has among its duties encouragement of agricultural and industrial production of the country, and the application of the price stabili— zation for agricultural products. In addition, the C.N.P. cooperates with credit institutions, the agricultural extension service (STICA) and any other institution whose efforts are aimed to the increment of national production. The C.N.P. also administers and operates the national liquor monopoly whose revenues represent over 25 million colones annually. Costa Rican Institute of Electricity This agency was created to channel the use of hydro- electric energy to promote industrial development and economic production. The Institute of Electricity is the owner and operator of 58 per cent of the country's electric power and receives an annual subvention from the government of 10 million colones. National Institute of Housing and Urbanization This autonomous institution is a public housing authority intended to stimulate the development of those 85 industries which contribute directly to the solution of housing and urbanization problems. This autonomous in- stitution is guaranteed a subvention equal to two per cent of the amount of the annual government budget. University of Costa Rica The University is the only autonomous institution directly concerned with education. It is guaranteed a subvention of 10 per cent of the amount of the annual government budget of the Ministry of Education. Pacific Electric Railroad The Pacific Electric Railroad, which began operating in 1925, controls the operation of the railway connecting the Central Plateau and San Jose with the Pacific Coast and the Port of Puntarenas. The railroad receives no direct subvention from the State. Other Autonomous Institutions The Social Security Board and the National Insurance Institute have no direct concern with the material aspects of the economic development of Costa Rica, but they are 86 both very important from the point of view of invest- ment institutions. The organic law of both of these institutions obliges them to invest their monetary re- serves in activities which yield a high rate of profit. The Coffee Office The coffee Office is a semi-autonomous institution connected with the Ministry of Economics. Among the duties of the Office is the regulation of all economic aspects of the coffee industry in Costa Rica, including the enforcement of international quotas. The Coffee Office was reorganized in 1948 to take direct responsi— bility of the Costa Rican Coffee Exchange and the gpppa de Liquidaciones del Café, both established in 1933. The Junta sets the minimum price to be received by pro- ducers from coffee mills buying their coffee. This price is determined at the end of the production year, based on prices received by individual coffee mills from the sale of their coffee in international and domestic markets. The Coffee Office must authorize all pruchases or sales of coffee, including authorization of exports. 87 No coffee transaction can be made without having been registered and approved by the Office. The Coffee Office is ruled by a Board of Directors composed of five members elected for two year periods. Associations of producers, millers, roasters and ex— porters, and the Ministry of Economics, are each repre— sented by one member on the Board. The operations of the Coffee Office are financed by revenues obtained from transactions in the Coffee Exchange, authorization of exports and direct allocation of funds from the Legislative Assembly. International Ties In addition to the normal trade relationships with most countries in the world, Costa Rica maintains com- mercial treaties and bilateral agreements with a number of countries, including Mexico, the United States, Canada, Nerway, Denmark, The Netherlands, the United Kingdom, Italy, France, west Germany, Japan, Uruguay, Guatemala and El Salvador. Moreover, special trade concessions are granted to Central American Countries. As a corollary of Costa Rica's economic development, 88 Costa Rica is an active member in the Organization of Central American States (ODECA), which seeks, among other things, the progressive economic integration of the Central American States. In 1958, along with other Cen- tral American Republics, Costa Rica signed the Agreement for the Central American Economic Integration. The fundamental features in this Agreement are: a) the Multilateral Free Trade Treaty, b) the Agreement for the Integration of Central American Industries, and c) the Central American Agreement for the Equalization of Duties on Imports. The number of items included in the Free Trade Treaty is small in terms of the volume of trade among the five Central American Republics.l It is hoped, however, that the list of items included will be sub- stantially expanded over the initial ten year period of the Agreement. The Agreement for the Integration of Central American Industries envisages the integration and development of industrial plants whose products will enjoy free trade in the Central American market, thus making possible the 1Panama is not included in the overall plans of Central American Economic Integration. Nevertheless, Panama is parti- cipating in some secondary treaties and trade agreements. 89 formation of industrial concerns which would be unprofi— table on the basis of a single country market. The Central American Agreement for the Equalization of Duties on Imports is designed to encourage and stimu— late free trade of Central American products and to lead the way in providing the necessary incentives for the achievement of the integration of Central American industries. Other international ties of Costa Rica are represented by the membership ofcms a Rica in the International Wheat Agreement and the International Coffee Agreement. United Nations technical assistance to Costa Rica has been largely concentrated in education, public health and agriculture. An FAO mission has provided assistance in the eradication of the hoof-and-mouth disease, in nutri— tion, agricultural statistics and land colonization. The World Health Organization has helped train nurses. Tech- nicians of UNESCO have helped improve secondary and uni- versity education. Another United Nations project which has attracted special attention is the establishment of the Central American School of Public Administration in San Jose. 90 The Inter-American Institute of Agricultural Sciences of the Organization of American States was established in Costa Rica in 1942 on land granted by the Costa Rican Government. The research and technical facilities of the Institute are available to all participating member nations. The United States and Costa Rican Governments maintain a bilateral technical assistance program through the Inter- national Cooperation Agency. The largest project is the International Technical Service of Agricultural Coopera- tion (STICA), which is a joint program with the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock and ICA. STICA and the Agricultural Extension Service were separate entities be- fore they were united under the Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock in 1956. Additional technical assistance in the agricultural field is provided by the University Of Florida and the University of Kansas to the University of Costa Rica and the Ministry of Agriculture, respectively. 91 Demographic Characteristics of Costa Rica Costa Rica's population has grown from less than half a million in 1927 to 1.12 million in 1959. The rate of population growth reached an all-time high of 3.87 per cent for the 1950—1959 period, as shown in Table 3.1. This makes Costa Rica one of the fastest growing countries in the world. The rapid rate of population growth can be attributed mainly to natural growth, since immigration has been negligible. The high birth and fertility rates together with rapidly declining mortality rates are the principal factors determining the high rate of population growth. TABLE 3.1 COSTA RICA: POPULATION AND POPULATION GROWTH 1920-1959 Year Population Growth Rate per Annum 1920 421,000 1927 480,326 1940 619,000 1.95 (1927-40) 1950 812,000 2.59 (1940-50) 1959 1,126,000 3.87 (1950-59) Source: United Nations, Economic Commission for Latin America, Los Recursos Humanos de Centroamerica, Panama y México en 1950-1980, 1960, table 1, 4. Data for 1927 and I950 from Direccion General de Estadistica y Censo, Areas Eamoqraficas de Costa Rica (San José, 1959), table 1, 39. 92 Over one-half of the Costa Rican population (52.2 per cent) lives in the central part of the country known as the Intermountainous Valley. There is, however, a net migra- tion from this area to the less densely populated regions along the Atlantic and Pacific Coasts. Population Density The Costa Rican territory is not densely populated. In 1955, the average population density was nineteen inhabitants per square kilometer. Corresponding figures for other Cen- tral American countries for 1955 are: Mexico, fifteen; Guatemala, thirty; and El Salvador, 110.2 By 1957, the population density in Costa Rica had increased to 20.5 inhabitants per square kilometer.3 There are, however, large differences in population density in the different areas of the country. In fact, in 1957, population density in the Intermountainous Valley was 142.3 inhabitants per square kilometer. Conversely, the population density in 1 . . . . Direcc1on General de Estadistica y Censos, Areas Demo- ggaficas de Costa Rica (San José, 1959), 13. 2 , . . . . United Nations, Economic CommiSSion for Latin America, Los Recursos Humanos de Centroamerica, Panama! y México en 1950-1980 (New York, 1960), Table 2, 5. 31bid., 42. 93 other areas in Costa Rica is no higher than 13.2 inhabitants per square kilometer. Rural and Urban Economically Active Population Costa Rica is still a predominantly rural country, with 66.5 per cent of the population living in the rural sector. The 1950 Census of Population shows that 36.7 per cent of the total urban population and 32.5 per cent of total rural population over twelve years of age are economically active. This means that only one-third of the population is econom- ically active and must support the remaining two—thirds of the population.3 A large proportion of Costa Rica's active population is engaged in primary production, namely, agriculture. Table 3.2 shows that 54.7 per cent of economically active popula- tion is engaged in agriculture and forestry, 10.9 per cent in manufacturing, and 14.7 per cent in services. 1 . . . . . Direcc1on General de Estadistica y Censos, o . c1t., 46. 2 . . . , . UniverSidad de Costa Rica, El Desarrollo Economico de stta Rica! Sector Agropecuario (Ciudad Universitaria, 1959) 18. 3Ducoff has pointed out that 49.7 per cent of the popu- lation between 10 and 12 years old is economically active in Costa Rica. United Nations, 0 . cit., 142, table XXV. 94 TABLE 3.2 COSTA RICA, ECONOMICALLY ACTIVE POPULATION BY ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, 1927 AND 1950 . . . 1927 1950 Economic Act1Vity Number Per Cent Number Per Cent Agriculture and forestrya 91,791 61.77 148,837 54.72 Mining and quarrying 398 0.27 754 0.28 Manufacturing 11,701 7.88 29,870 10.98 Construction 5,933 3.99 11,625 4.28 Electricity, water and sanitation service -- ~~ 1,607 0.58 Wholesale and retail trade 8,541 5.75 21,412 7.87 Transportation, storage and communications 3,643 2.45 9,465 3.48 Services 21,223 14.28 40,166 14.77 Other 5,369 3.61 8,248 3.03 Total active population 148,599 100.00 271,984 100.00 aIncludes fishing and hunting. Source: Universidad de Costa Rica, El Desarrollo Egonémico de Costa Rica-—Sector Aqropecuario (Ciudad Uni- versitaria, 1959), 19. 95 This table also shows that there has been a decrease of seven per cent in the proportion of the labor force engaged in agriculture from 1927 to 1950. Determinants of Future Population In a recent study of the human resources in Central America, Panama and Mexico, Ducoff classifies Central Amer- ica as a high potential population growth area. He asserts that the principal determinants of demographic growth for Costa Rica (as well as for Central America) are, and have been in the past, the level of fertility and the level of mortality.1 The net international migration has been negli- gible and can be expected to continue to be negligible although the process of economic integration of Central America will stimulate and facilitate migratory movements between the Central American countries. Disregarding at this stage Ducoff's demographic pro- jections it is still appropriate to mention the demographic characteristics which make Costa Rica a country of high potential population growth. As mentioned before, these —¥ 1 . Ibid., 29. 2Ibid., 29, footnote 3. 96 determinants of future population are mortality, birth and fertility rates. Birth and Mortality Rates These determinants of future population are shown in Table 3.3. The rapid rate of natural growth of population is due to a 50.9 per cent decline in mortality rate and increase in the birth rate of 11.4 per cent in 1952—56 relative to the base period 1930-34.1 The decline in the mortality rate has increased the life expectancy of the population very considerably. TABLE 3.3 COSTA RICA, BIRTH, MORTALITY AND NATURAL GROWTH RATES OF POPULATION PER 1000 INHABITANTS, 1930-1934 AND 1952-1956 r 1930-1934 1952-1956 Per Cent Change Birth rates 45.7 50.9 +11.4 Mortality rate 22.0 10.8 —50.9 Natural growth 23.7 40.1 Source: United Nations, Economic Commission for Latin America, Los Recursos Humanos de Centroamerica, Panama y Mexico en 1950-1980, 1960, 31. Birth rates in the United States for the period 1952— 1956 were 25.1 per cent and death rates 9.4 per cent per 1000 inhabitants. Ibid., 31. 97 Fertility Rates The fertility rate is the number of children under five years of age per thousand women in the population between the ages of fifteen and forty-nine. The fertility rate in Costa Rica was 686 compared to 103 in the United States in 1950. With a high birth rate, high fertility rate and rapidly declining mortality rate, Costa Rica will probably continue to experience a rapid rate of population growth in the 1960's. Social Characteristics of the Population Costa Rica has a homogeneous population. The ethnic composition of the population, according to the 1950 Census of Population, consists of 97.7 per cent Whites, 0.3 per cent Indians, 1.9 per cent Negroes and 0.1 per cent Asians. Furthermore, only 4.2 per cent of the population was born in a foreign country. Spanish is spoken by 97.3 per cent of the population.1 The level of illiteracy in Costa Rica is low relative to Latin America. In 1950, 21 per cent of Costa Rica's 1 Ibid., 18-21, tables 11, 12, 14. 98 population ten years of age or older were illiterate. Illi- teracy rates in the rural population amount to 28 per cent while the corresponding figure for urban areas is only 8 per cent. The reason for these relatively low rates of illiteracy is found in Costa Rican history. In 1886 the Minister of Education, Don Mauro Fernandez ("The Father of Costa Rican Education"), dictated and enacted the Funda- mental Law of Public Education which established primary education to be free, compulsory, laic and under the direct responsibility of the State.2 Congress closed the Univer— sity of Santo Tomas in 1887 in order to bring about a greater expansion in primary education. Hence, in 1886 Costa Rica made the decision to give priority to invest- ment in the human agent through universal education; this investment decision is one of the topics which has attracted a great deal of attention in the recent literature in . 3 . . economic development. The success of the deCiSion to Juan Perez Fajardo, "Caracteristicas Educacionales de Nuestra Poblacién," Atlas Estadistico de Costa Rica, Direc- cion General de Estadistica y Censo (San José, 1953), 55. Ricardo Fernandez Guardia, Cartilla Historica de Costa Rica (33d ed.; San José: Imprenta Lehmann, 1960), 111. 3 . . . T. W. Schultz, The Economic Test for Latin America (New 99 give priority to universal education is indicated by the fact that illiteracy rates dropped from 89 per cent in 1864 to 68.6 per cent in 1892, to 24.0 per cent in 1927, to 21 per cent in 1950.1 The three per cent drop in illiteracy rates from 1927 to 1950 is very significant if one considers that population almost doubled during that period.2 The University of Costa Rica was founded in 1940 by merging a number of independent colleges. The present col- leges of the University and their founding dates are the following: Law (1891), Pharmacy (1897), Fine Arts (1897), PedagOgy (1914), Agriculture (1926), Philosophy (1940), Engineering and Science (1940), Odontology (1941), Economics and Social Science (1943), and Medicine (1959).3 The Uni— versity of Costa Rica is an autonomous institution of the State and receives a subvention of 10 per cent of the amount York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, Bulletin NO. 35 (August 1956), 1-30, and ”Investment in Human Capi- tal," American Economic Review, Vol. LI, No. 1 (March, 1961), 1-17; also, W. Arthur Lewis, "Education and Economic Develop- ment," Social and Economic Studies, Vol. X (June, 1961), 113- 127. l Perez Fajardo, op. cit., 52. 2 . Vide, table 3.1. 3Perez Fajardo, op. cit., p. 55. 100 of the budget of the Ministry of Education. The Ministry of Education controls and supervises all primary and se- condary education in Costa Rica and receives the highest share of the Government budget; in 1959 this share amounted to 71 million colones or 20 per cent. Summary Costa Rica has been a sovereign nation since it attained its independence from Spain 141 years ago. This small coun— try of 23,000 square miles is located in the narrow part of the Central American Isthmus. Costa Rica borders with Nicaragua in the north, Panama in the south, the Pacific Ocean in the west and the Atlantic Ocean in the east. The Costa Rican territory is divided into seven provinces and governed by a centralized democratic government. The govern- ment consists of three distinct and independent powers: Legislative, Executive, and Judicial. National elections take place every four years and are supervised by an inde— pendent body called Supreme Tribunal of Elections. The responsibility of Costa Rica's economic development in the public sector is assumed by the Ministers of Govern- ment and the autonomous institutions of the State. There is, however, no official planning board. These institutions 101 are in charge of Costa Rica's international ties. Aside from normal commercial relations with foreign countries, Costa Rica has bilateral agreements for technical cooper- ation with the United States Government. In addition, treaties leading to the Economic Integration of Central America have been signed with other Central American countries. The population of Costa Rica is slightly over 1.1 million and is growing at a rate of 3.87 per cent per year. This makes Costa Rica one of the fastest growing countries in the world. Costa Rica is largely a rural country with 66.5 per cent of its population and 55 per cent of its labor force in the rural sector. Only one-third of the Costa Rican population is economically active and must support the remaining two-thirds of the population. Of the total economically active population, 54.7 per cent is engaged in agriculture, 10.9 per cent in manufacturing, and 14.7 per cent in services, and the balance in other activities, Costa Rica is spending 20 per cent of its national budget on education. Universal education has been a major aim of . . 1 Costa Rican governments Since 1886. lVide Chapter IV, table 4.1. CHAPTER IV THE CONTEMPORARY PERFORMANCE OF THE COSTA RICAN ECONOMY This chapter presents macroeconomic data for the Costa Rican economy. A cursory review of the economic history of the nation is presented for the late 1940's and for the 1950—1959 period. A note on the measurement problems of economic growth follows. Since national income data for the period 1950 to the present have been published only since 1956, "modern economic computations" have been used in Costa Rica only in recent years. Although there are shortcomings in these aggregate data, an attempt is made in this chapter to calculate and compare the over—all rate of growth with the rates of growth of the major economic sectors over the 1950-1959 period. Rates of growth for the period under consideration are calculated by six different methods which were recently appraised by Professor Boris Pesek.l Boris P. Pesek, "Economic Growth and Its Measurement," Eggnomic Development and Cultural Changg, Vol. IX, No. 3 (April, 1961), 295-315. 102 103 The Status of the Costa Rican Economy in 1950: The Stacy May Study The standard contemporary document on Costa Rican development--The Stacy May Reportl--was an outgrowth of the findings of a Twentieth Century Fund Study Group of five economists who visited Costa Rica for six weeks in 1950. This group was asked to review the status of economic development in the major sectors of the Costa Rican economy. In addition, they were asked to recommend specific development projects that might be undertaken with the aid of technical and financial assistance from inter— national agencies. The contents of the report pertain to the general conditions existing in Costa Rica in 1950. The conclusions and policy recommendations of the study group can be classified as universal statements which would be valid in 1950, 1960 or 1970 in Costa Rica or in many other underdeveloped nations. They recommend for instance, a general development plan for the country, establishment of a better system of economic reporting and statistics as guides for planning and development, expand and improve _‘ l . . . Stacy May et al., Costa Rica, A Study in Economic Development (New YOrk: The Twentieth Century Fund, 1952). 104 scientific research in agriculture, encourage savings and channel them to fields of agricultural improvements, pro- cessing industries, and light manufacturing and assembly industries, maintain a balanced budget and even a surplus as long as inflation is not checked, and revision of the government finances and tax collection systems. With respect to the agricultural sector, the group recommended expanding the production of domestically pro- duced foodstuffs, and to expand and diversify exports. Economic History of Costa Rica: 1950-1959 Let us review the major events in the Costa Rican econ— omy from 1950 to 1959. The Foreign Exchange Law of 1950 established differential foreign exchange surcharges on imports. This law also legalized the free market of foreign exchange and directed the Central Bank to use no less than 20 per cent of its receipts of foreign exchange to pay off accumulated backlog and to increase the available volume of foreign exchange in the free market. The Law of International Payments of 1951 replaces the law mentioned above. By virtue of this law, all surcharges are abolished but both the official and free markets of foreign exchange remain legal. Moreover only "first 105 necessity imports" were to receive foreign exchange at the official rate. By 1951 the free market rate of the colon had dropped to 7.00 colones per U.S. dollar; since 1952 this rate has remained at 6.65 while the official rate of exchange was 5.60 (5.67 selling rate). During this period, the Costa Rican balance of trade as well as the balance of payments has been favorable to Costa Rica although deficits were realized in several years. Government expenditures rose from 140.8 million colones in 1951 to 351.6 million colones in 1959. In spite of this large increase in government expenditures, a surplus of 104.4 million colones was realized from 1951 to 1959. 1958 left a deficit of 0.4 million colones.2 The 1959 govern- ment budget is reproduced in Table 4.1. In 1959, 68 per cent of the total government revenue came from indirect taxes, 15.3 per cent from direct taxes, 8.5 per cent from corporation taxes and 8.2 per cent from other taxes. 1Balance of trade and balance of payments conditions are explored in Chapter 7. 2Banco Central de Costa Rica, Memoria Anual de 1955 (San José: 1953), 102; Memoria Anual de 1959 (San José: 1960),llZ 3Ibid., 1959, computed from data on 106. 106 The Costa Rican public debt decreased from 367.0 mil- lion colones in 1951 to 323.1 million colones in 1954 to reach 457.2 million colones at the end of 1959. During the same period 1951-1959, the internal debt rose from 202.0 to 301.9 million colones, while the external debt decreased from 164.5 to 155.2 million colones at the end of 1959.1 This period was also characterized by the expansion of credit on the part of commercial banks, especially after 1955. The volume of credit rose from 357.2 million colones to 582.3 million in 1959. During this later year 43.3 per cent of the credit was granted to agriculture, 15.4 per cent to livestock, 11.8 per cent to industry, 10.8 per cent to commerce and 18.7 per cent to other activities. The price level during this period rose 7.7 per cent as measured by the wholesale price index3 which suggests effec- tive monetary and fiscal policies were operative. Three important laws were enacted during this period to promote economic development: the Mining Code law of 1953, the Indus lIbid., 1955, 105; 1959, 123. 21bid., 1959, 179. 3 Refer to Chapter 6. 107 trial encouragement law of 1959 and the Economic Develop- ment Law of 1959. Previously, the mining code of Costa Rica discouraged private activities in this sector. Law No. 1551 of May, 1953 adopted a more liberal policy toward private mining exploration. The government now encourages the mining industry by permitting duty-free importation of machinery, tools and other equipment. The second law concerns that development of industries in Costa Rica. The Industrial Encouragement Law of September 1959 pro- vides 99 per cent customs tax exemption on imports of con— struction materials, capital equipment and machinery, fuels and lubricants, raw materials and semi-manufactured products required for the establishment of new industries.1 New industries are exempted from land taxes for five years and enjoy a 100 per cent exemption from any government tax for the first half of the period granted for the enjoyment of the benefits of this law (determined by the Ministry of Industry) and 50 per cent tax exemption during the second 1"Industrial Encouragement Law” published in La Gaceta (official newspaper) September 9, 1959. New industries are considered those which manufacture products not produced in Costa Rica or produced in quantities amounting to less than 10 per cent national consumption (article 16). 108 half of the period. A tax equal to triple the tariff rate is established on the importation of foreign merchandise similar to that produced nationally. Merchandise produced by new industries is exempt of export taxes. ”Established industries" may also enjoy a number of the benefits of this law according to provisions pertaining to this category. More than 150 applications for benefits under the Industrial Encouragement Lawl had been made by 1950. This policy decision of import substitution is an exam— ple of a country following the prescription set forth by Prebisch and Singer. The Prebisch—Singer import substitu- tion policies have been discussed in Chapter I. The third important law enacting policy dealing speci— fically with economic development was the Economic Develop— ment Law of November 1959.2 This law which provides 170.1 million colones for the economic development of Costa Rica was financed by bonds of the Refund of the Internal Debt . 3 and bonds of the National Banking System. Among other 1U.S. Department of Commerce, World Trade Information Service, Economic Developments in Costa Rica, 1960 (Eco— nomic Reports, part 2, No. 61-19, 1961), 3. 2 . cit., Memoria Anual de 1959, 357-382. 3These bonds bear an interest rate of 7 per cent per 109 TABLE 4.1 COSTA RICA, GOVERNMENT BUDGET FISCAL YEAR 1959 (ORDINARY AND EXTRAORDINARY), MILLION OF COLONES J f f Amount Percentage Legislative Power . . . . . . 3,7 .1 Presidencyiof the Republic . . 1,1 0.3 Ministries of Government Agriculture and Industry 6,2 1.8 Economics and Revenue . . . . . 18,2 5.2 Public Education . . . . . . . . . 71,0 20.2 Government, Police, Justice & Grace 18,4 5.2 Public Works . . . . . . . 40.3 11.4 Foreign Relations . . . . . . . 3,7 1.0 Public Health . . . . . . . . . . 8,4 2.4 Public Security . . . . . . . . . 13,3 3.8 Labor and Social Welfare . . . . . 1,7 0.5 Total Executive Power . . . . 182,3 51.8 Judicial Power . . . . . . . . 13,5 3.8 Supreme Tribunal of Elections . 2,0 0.6 Pensions and Retirement . . 14,0 4.0 Subventions . . . . . . . . 77,0 21.9 Internation Organ. Quotas . . 1,7 0.5 Outstanding Payments . . . . . . . 0,0 0.0 "Prestaciones Legales" and other additional payments . . . . . 14,8 4.2 Verdicts and Sentences . . . . 0,2 0.0 Pensions, SubventionsLietc. 107,7 30.6 Service of External debt . . . . 17,5 5.0 Service of Internal debt . . . . . 24,9 7.1 Financial Transactions . . . . . . 0,0 0.0 Total Service of Public Debt . 42,4 12.1 Total Government Budget . . . . . . . 351.6 100 0 Source: Banco Central de Costa Rica, Memoria Anual de lggg, San José, 1960, p. 115. 110 provisions made by this law, 35.0 million colones are to be invested in road construction in agricultural regions; 80.0 million colones were given to the banking system to increase their credit funds (including expansion of the Agricultural Credit System1 and provisions are made to organize separate Industrial Credit Departments in three commercial banks. The National Production Council2 re- ceived 3.7 million colones for the purchase of agricul- tural machinery to be rented to agricultural producers, to expand refrigeration facilities and to stabilize the price of brown sugar for consumption. The University of Costa Rica received 1 1/4 million colones to expand its research programs on the production of basic foodstuffs. Problems of Measurement of Economic Growth The over-all goal of economic development can be said to be the maximization of the rate of expansion of pro- duction over time. In this sense, the process of growth year and like all bonds of these two series, are exempt of any municipal or national taxes, present or future, on the principal or on the interest accrued. 1The Agricultural Credit System is analyzed in Chapter VI. 2 See Chapter VI. 111 is essentially quantitative. Furthermore, economic de— velopment implies certain types of changes covering numerous phases which must be studied in the aggregate as well as for the components of the required structural shifts or changes. It would be an impossible task to attempt to estimate the quantitative aspects of economic growth for the thousands of economic units in a nation. It is for this reason that the reduction of these quanti- tative aspects to some single value measurements is inescapable. Some single value measurements repeatedly used by economists as gauges of economic performance are National Income Accounts. Records of national product (or income) and its components are an indispensable tool for the study of the general characteristics of the development of a country or region. For many underdeveloped countries records of national product are helpful in planning and policy making. The most frequently used measures of economic perform— ance using National Income Accounts are: National Product, National Income and Domestic Product. Each one of these three gauges of output can be estimated in gross terms if 112 they do not include the capital goods consumed in the pro- duction process. The inclusion of capital consumption allowance will yield the net figures in either one of the accounts considered. Gross national product represents the market value of the output of a nation while national income denotes the allocation of income originating from that output. Gross national product refers to the productive contribution of individuals residing in a given country, together with the productive contribution of any property owned by such residents, whether this property is located at home or abroad. In other words, the boundary of gross national product is defined in terms of the nationals of a country and their property rather than in terms of geography. Gross domestic product measures the production occurring within a given geographical area irrespective of whether the productive resources in question are owned by nationals of that area or not. It also excludes any foreign property that is held by nationals of the country in question. Thus, gross domestic product measures the productive activity taking place within a geographical area whereas gross national product refers to the productive activity of a 113 specific group of individuals (nationals) and their pro— perty. Aside from this difference in coverage, gross national product and gross domestic product are equivalent concepts. Both measures have difficulty in handling the problem of defining intermediate goods and services treat— ment of non-market output and treatment of transfer payments. Gross domestic product may be larger than gross national product if one or more of the main sources of productive activity and the resources involved, are owned and operated by nationals of other countries. Conversely, gross domestic product will be smaller than gross national product if the nationals of the country have large foreign investments so that the country's net property income from abroad may be substantial. The three national income estimates mentioned above are usually expressed in terms of market prices. However, an alternative method of valuation production is to value national output in terms of what it costs in terms of fac— tors of production. Any national income aggregate expressed in "factor cost," excludes any indirect tax paid by business to the government since such taxes do not fall on any 114 specific factor of production. For the same reason, busi- nesstransfer payments and current surplus of government enterprises are not included, on grounds that they are not payments to the factors of production. Taxescxiany factor of production, such as corporate profit tax, social insurance contributions, as well as subsidies are part of the factor cost to producers. Fac- tor cost valuation is not really an independent method of valuation showing the cost necessary to obtain the services of factors but rather it is an adjustment of market value to show the proportion thereof that the factors receive. Given the importance of national income estimates in judging economic conditions and their use in economic planning and economic policy, the limitations and short— comings of these estimates should be kept in mind. The use of national income accounts presents two problems: first, conceptual and statistical problems which are in— herent to the actual measurements themselves; second, the failure to reflect non-economic changes. lRichard Ruggles and Nancy D. Ruggles, National Income Accounts and Income Analysis (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., 1956), 117. 115 Conceptual and Statistical Problems The first conceptual problem stems from the definition of intermediate goods and services. In summing the market value of goods and services produced by an economic com— plex, it is necessary to exclude the intermediate goods and services that enter in the production of other goods and services. In other words, any transaction which repre- sents a purchase by a productive unit from other productive units on current account, should be omitted from the total market value of national output. In many instances, it is difficult to distinguish between intermediate and final goods and services. Some items may appear as an expense in the ledger of a firm, in economic terms, may not represent the use of material or other goods used in current output or increase in inventories. In addition to the conceptual problem of separating current expenditures from capital expenditures, a further problem arises from the fact that many outlays that firms can treat as current expense for taxation purposes, are in reality capital formation. Another problem involves distinguishing between inter- mediate and final goods and services provided by the government. Government services can be considered as final 116 goods given to the economy or as intermediate services given to all economic units of a nation. Since most government services are provided free of charge,1 it is debatable whether they should be included in the total output of a nation. They should be included if govern- ment services are considered as services consumed by pro— ducers in their production process or if the market price of goods requiring those services would rise should business be called upon to pay directly for such services. However, government services should not be included in the total value of the output of a nation if one maintains that business does pay for those services indirectly through taxes (i.e., gasoline taxes, corporation taxes, etc.). Again, this is a conceptual problem inherent to national income accounts. In national income accounting, all consumers’ expen- ditures are considered as outlays for final products. This procedure is to some extent arbitrary and not very accurate since it is based on the assumption that individuals do not l . . . . . These serVices may include roads, information serVices, conservation or agricultural extension services, public health and facilities, etc. 117 have expenses that can be classified as purchases of inter— mediate goods and services. Another conceptual problem is presented by the omission of unilateral transfers from the computation of national income accounts. These unilateral transfers or payments are mainly constituted by gifts of one individual to another and government transfer payments such as bonuses, relief payments,pensions, etc. The former are omitted from na- tional income estimates on grounds that they do not refer to any particular production, the latter on grounds that they are means of income redistribution rather than income arising from any particular production. Finally, statistical problems arise from the exclusion of non-market production from national income figures. This non-market production refers to rent "not paid" by home owners residing in their own homes, home-made goods and services for household consumption, domestic servants obtaining free room and board in payment for their services and farm produce consumed at the farm. The omission of non- market production from national product estimates represents a major statistical problem. This is particularly true in underdeveloped countries where the extent of their market or monetary economy is limited. 118 This discussion brings us to the second major limita— tion of national income accounts and their use in under- developed countries. Failure To Reflect Non-economic Changes It has been stated that economic development can be conceived as the maximization of the rate of expansion of production over time. In order to maximize the rate of production in underdeveloped countries, a number of social, political and institutional changes may be required. National income aggregates fail to reflect, to any great extent, such changes. The ultimate goal of economic de— velopment is to improve the standard of living of the population through increased output and productivity. However, the standard of living of a community is as a rule affected by much more than the mere flow of goods and services. Non-economic forces such as political, social, religious and cultural considerations, influence the level of well-being achieved by the members of a society. Not only do there exist significant divergences in the socio— cultural environment of different countries relative to their income levels, but also the actual increment in total output of a country may entail radical changes in the 119 institutional and socio-cultural complex. Changes in national income or output, are almost certain to be accom- panied by changes in the distribution of income. Although any rise in income represents a tacit improvement for a given society, given the change in income distribution which is likely to accompany the increase in income the economic situation may be worse than before. Therefore, to equate differences in the level and/or structure of aggre- gate output with variations in community welfare and levels of economic development, is rather hazardous and arbitrary. National income records are relatively scarce in under- developed nations, and largely unavailable for the study of long period trends. One author contends that the relative scarcity of national income data in underdeveloped countries can be attributed to two factors: first, that the social and economic life does not produce statistics in the course Of everyday life, and second, that poorer countries have no resources to spare for the collection and analysis of data which in the short-run, satisfy less pressing needs than food and other necessities of the population. lSimon Kuznets, "Problems in Comparisons of Economic Trends," Economic Growth, Brazil, India, Japan, Simon Kuznets, Wilbert E. Moore and Joseph J. Spengler (eds.), (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1955), 9. 120 In the preceeding pages, some of the contributions and shortcomings of the use of national income estimates for the measurement of economic growth have been discussed. The following quotation offers a good summary of this discussion. . . . long-term records of national product and its components are indispensable for the study of the general characteristics of economic growth of nations can hardly be gainsaid. Indeed, the major difficulty is not in the defects of the national product measures, but in their scarcity . . . . Provided that we recognize the assump— tions and the difficulties, much can be learned.1 Costa Rica National Income Data National income data for the Costa Rican economy were not available until 1956; the estimates go back as far as 1950.2 These statistics are reproduced in Table 4.2. The gross national product rose from 1,298 million in 1950 to 2,530 million colones in 1959. All three main aggregates, national income, national product or domestic product, showed almost a twofold increase during the period considered. The Ber capita national income in current prices rose from 250 1Simon Kuznets, "Some Conceptual Problems of Measure- ment," Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. IV, NO. 4 (October, 1956), 7. 2Banco Central de Costa Rica, Inqreso y Producto Nacionales de Costa Rica, 1950 (San Jose, 1956). 121 dollars in 1950 to 332 dollars in 1959.1 Table 4.3 shows the gross domestic product by economic sectors for the 1950 to 1959 period. Table 4.4 shows the per cent contribution of the major economic sectors to the gross domestic product in 1950 and 1959. Agriculture, manufacturing and mining and services con- tributed 54.6, 11.4 and 11.8 per cent respectively to the gross domestic product in 1950. These three major sectors employed 54.7, 11.2 and 14.7 per cent respectively of the economically active population in 1950.2 In 1959, agriculture accounted for 35.7 per cent of the domestic product which represented a decrease of 9.85 Per cent from 1950. Government and government services and state enterprises were the two sectors which showed the greatest proportional increases in their contributions to the domestic product. National income figures are useful to show structural economic changes over time. However, for purposes of ——L Banco Central de Costa Rica, Departamento de Estudios Economicos, Ingresopy Producto Nacionales de Costa Rica, @1218 (San José, December, 1959), 7. 2 See Chapter III, Table III, 2, p. 14. 122 .H> Hmummgo sH pmoswoummu pew xcmm Hmuucmv on“ >9 cmusmeoo mesH wofium mammmaoaz map >9 Uwumammp coma m>mfl mueumflumum emote m .Aaoma .mumsuflmm .meb smmv mmmalmmma .muwm muwoo mp mwamcoflomz ouoscoum > OmQHmsH .mooflfioc loom moflpsumm mp oucmEmuHman .moflm mumou mp Hmnucwo OUCMm .wmlmm .Aomma .Hnow 3wzv mmma .mowumflumum mucsooo< Hmsofiumz mo xoonummw .mcoflumz pmuHsD "mousom h.m®om m.mNNN o.mmmm 0.0mmm m.¢mma 0.00HN mmma H.maom m.omHN m.m©NN 0.0mvm m.¢hma o.mNON mmma H.0mma ¢.Hmom 5.0HHN N.hmmm ®.¢¢ha o.mmwa hmma N.vvha N.®mma H.N®ma m.HNHN m.®m®a h.m®ha omma b.00ha m.ommH m.¢mma h.Hmom N.mhma ©.mm©H mmma h.mooa m.®hoa N.m®ha N.®¢ma b.0hva ©.mmmH fimma ¢.m©ma v.m©ma m.mm©H m.mmoa h.mmva h.mN¢H mmma m.hhma @.mmfla ¢.omva o.@HmH 0.0mma O.©mNH Nmma H.0NHH m.¢oma m.OHNH 0.0H¢H o.mm0H 0.0HNH HmmH m.h©oa h.mONH m.m¢HH N.mmNH C.Nmm 0.0NHH omma mmeHHm mmmuahm mmeHHm mmma meHHm mmma mmoflum mmma mOUHHm ucmumcou “COHHSU ucmumcoo DCOHHSU ucmeQOU DCOHHDU How? pospoum Uflumwaon mmouw uospoum HMGOHumZ mmOHU mEOUCH Hmcoflumz mmouw mmooHoo mo mCOHHHHz mmmmauommfl .emoo moeoem em eonsomm oHemmzoo mmomo oze eoooomm q OnonmsH .mooHEocoom mOHpsumm mo ounmEmuHmmwQ .moflm mumou on Hmnucwu oucwm .Nm .Ammma "xnow 302v mmma .moflumflumum DGDOUU¢ Hmcoflumz mo xoonumww .mcoflumz UmuHaD "mousom m.mmmm mdmam «Amom ~6me m.mom._n momma Emoma Emmi“ méOmH fimoma Dosponm Uflumwfiom wmouw ¢.omH ©.mmH m.mma m.mmH v.5HH h.mm m.m> H.Hh m.m® m.H© mmmflumumucm mumum m.mbm H.0mm m.m¢m H.Hmm ¢.oam N.mma o.vma m.0ha 5.0ma o.m¢H mmUH>Hom H.Hmm m.mmm m.mom m.¢ma N.mma o.mma H.hHH o.mm m.mm h.Hm mCOHuouHumcH DGwEGHw>ow w ucmficum>ow m.moa m.Hoa N.mm v.mm o.mm C.Nm 0.5» m.ah m.mm m.¢m mmcflaamza mo QflSmeczo m.mam h.hma o.¢ma ¢.mma N.¢ma H.N¢H m.vma H.mNH N.maa m.ooa GUMHB Hfimumm.wmammmaonz H.0m m.mn N.vh m.m® v.mo ¢.mm m.mm 0.0m m.m¢ H.H¢ :oflumoflcofifiou w wmmuoum .coflumuuommcmue m.mh m.ah H.nm mamm m.hm m.mm 0.0m H.0v H.N¢ m.mm coauosnumcoo v.00m m.vvm m.mmm H.0NN H.Hom m.oma m.mha N.N©H m.mvH m.hma mcflcflz w mcflusuommscmz o.mmb H.Hmm m.mmh H.N0h m.omb m.mmh m.mmm N.N¢® m.mmm m.mvm whsuasofiumfi mmma mmma nmma mmma mmma emaa mmmH_ mmma Hmmai ommH, muouomm Jl mmmdlommd WMOBUmm UHZOZOUH Mm BUDQOMm OHBmmZOQ mmomw umoo Houomm usmnuso um mmcofloo mo maoflaaflz m.v mqm<8 «<0Hm o w oomm m.ou H.0I o.w m.o m.m m.o mmvm I coma 6.0+ o.o e.v N.o H.¢ m.o mmwa I oooa m.o+ o.o m.m m.o h.m m.o mam I oom ©.H+ o.o m.ma N.m m.¢a m.m. 00¢ I mha m.a+ m.o+ v.0H h.¢ H.m ¢.w eha I OOH m.o+ m.ou m.ma e.oa m.aa m.oa mm I om m.o+ o.o e.aa m.om m.oa m.om me I cm m.o+ m.OI ©.m m.va ¢.m N.mH ma I OH H.o+ N.o+ m.H ©.mH m.H m.®a m I m N.o+ m.o+ m.H m.mm H.H m.nm w swap mmmq mfiumm mo HwQESZ mmomno coma mEHmm pawn mEHmm CH wmcmgo DHMW DWMMmHWM powwoumm umwwmuwm powwonmm mmmcmucmz Demo Mom Ge mNHm mmemno mmmauomma mmma omme mzmfim m0 mmmSDZ QZG WNHm .¢UHM fiBmOU H.m mqm¢8 145 agricultural land owned legally by its producers, there is not an egalitarian distribution of land ownership. Table 5.1 shows, for example, that in 1955 a total of 28.8 per cent of the farms were less than five manzanas (8.5 acres) in size. These 13,633 farms comprise only 1.9 per cent of all farm land. On the other hand, 0.1 per cent of the farms were over 3500 manzanas (5950 acres) in size. The fifty farms in this category comprise 21.1 per cent of all farm land. Table 5.2 shows that in 1955, 75.5 per cent of the farms and 81.1 per cent of the farm land was owned by pro— ducers; 1.4 per cent of the farms were rented and 16 per cent were in other forms of ownership. The category "other forms" includes land given free for cultivation, squatters and colonos. Colonos are farmers which have been granted land by the State to form agricultural settlements supported and organized under a National Law. The State assumes the responsibility for the settlement and in some cases may even direct its activities. Although 75.5 per cent of the farms and 81.1 per cent of the farm land is owned by agri— cultural producers, all tOgether, the land on farms exploited by the legal owner covers 88.9 per cent of the 146 total agricultural area of Costa Rica. Comparing the figures in Table 5.2 for 1950 and 1955, it can be seen that there has been a decrease of 5.6 per cent and 8.6 per cent in the number of farms owned by pro— ducers and in the percentage of total farm area respectively over the 1950 Census. "Other forms" of land tenancy showed an increase in 1955 of 10.6 per cent in the number of farms and also an increase of 3.9 per cent in the percentage of farm land. Size and Number of Farms2 Table 5.3 shows that there has been an increase of 4,200 farm units and 56,111 manzanas of land over the 1950 census. This represents an increase of 9.8 per cent and 2.2 per cent in the number of farms and area under cultivation lDireccion General de Estadistica y Censos, Censo Aqro— peeuario de 1955 (San José, 1959), XVII. 2The Census defines a farm as "any extension of land 0f one manzana or more which is dedicated totally or par— tially to agricultural or livestock production and where the production activities are directed or administered di— rectly by one person alone or with the help of others." A farm could consist of one or more tracks of land, owned or rented, as long as they were located within the same county or nearby counties provided that the tracks of land belonged to the same technical or economic unit. Direccion General de Estadistica y Censo, Censo Agropecuario de 1955 (San José, 1959), XII. 147 respectively. One-half of the farms are located in the most heavily populated provinces of San José and Alajuela in the Central Plateau of Costa Rica. Only four provinces of the seven provinces of San José, Puntarenas and Limon showed an increase in the number of farms as well as in the area under cultivation. The other four provinces showed a decrease in both. The province of Guanacaste contains only 18 per cent of the farms while comprising 33.7 per cent of the total area of farm land. This fact indicates a high degree of concentration of farm land and therefore the presence of latifundia type of land tenancy. The opposite phenomenon occurs in the Heredia Province where 5.2 per cent of the farms and only 3.1 per cent of the farm area is found. The presence of latifundio as well as minifundio type of land holding is more clearly shown by Table 5.2. The 1950 Census of Agriculture shows that 0.1 per cent of the farms (49 farms) contained 26.6 per cent of the agricultural land; and in 1955, the same per- centage of the number of farms (50 farms) comprised 21 per cent of the total farm area, showing a decrease of 5.6 per cent over the 1950 Census. On the other hand, Table 5.1 also shows that in 1955, 28.8 per cent of the total number 148 of farms had an extension of less than 4.9 manzanas; they contained 1.3 per cent of the total agricultural land. Farms of less than 10 manzanas (17 acres) accounted for 44 per cent of the farms and 3.8 per cent of the farm land. According to the 1955 Census, 84 per cent of the pro- ducers live on the farm. Of this, 84 per cent are resi- dent producers, 81.6 per cent are owner—operators and 2.4 per cent manager-operators. Of the 16 per cent non—farm residents, 9.9 per cent are owners and 6.1 per cent are managers. Land Use in Costa Rica The 1955 Census of Agriculture reported an area of 2,648,331 manzanas in farms. This figure represents 36.4 per cent of the national territory. Table 5.4 shows that in 1955 the land used for the production of annual crops, fallow land, and other crop land, comprises 401,663 man- zanas which represents 15.2 per cent of the farm land in Costa Rica. Most of the crops for internal consumption are produced on this land. The second major land use group is that made up of land in permanent crops such as coffee, lIbid., XXI. 149 TABLE 5.2 COSTA RICA: LAND DISTRIBUTION BY PERCENTAGE OF FARMS AND PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL FARM AREA T e of Holdin Per Cent Per Cent yp g Total Number Farms Total Farm Land 1950 1955 1950 1955 Owned 81.1 75.5 89.7 81.1 Rented 2.1 1.4 0.7 2.1 Other formsa 5.4 16.0 1.5 5.4 Mixed formsb 11.4 7.1 8.1 11.4 Source: Direccion General de Estadistica y Censo, Censo Aqropecuario de 1950 (San José, 1953), XIII; Censo Agropecuario de 1955 (San José, 1959), XVII. lIncludes land given for cultivation free of charge, squatters and colonos. 2Includes mixed forms such as owned and rented, and squatted or rented and squatted, owned 150 .NNH .Ammma .meb :mmv mmma mo oflumsowmono « Oncmw “m .Ammma .meh Honouao "mousom smmv omma mp oflumsommouo< Oncwo .Omcoo h moflDmHGMDmm mp Hmuocmo so. . omma\mmma am.m mae.m Hee.om oom.e II . . . . moem mumoo o.ooe o.ooe Hmm.meo.m 6mm.ev 0.00H o ooa omm mom N omo me . . GOEHQ e.e e.o mmm.¢om mea.m 0.5 m.m one NmH owe m ~ . @Hm CU e.ee e.NH om¢.eoe eeo.e m.ee e.HH oem emm emm 4 mm: D m ~ ~ flaws e.mm m.ee «mm.mmm one.m o.om H.mH wee wee wow u mummo o a s mHm H.m N.m mmH.mm mee.m N.m m.o 6mm om mom m wee m H.e m.m wea.ema mom.m m.oe o.m omm.wom Hoe.m ommonmo «.me m.mm eme.ome mmo.HH H.ee H.wm «mm.me¢ enm.oa memsflmam m.mH m.mm woo.emm mem.ma m.aa e.mm «Ne.oom mmm.OH wmoe new mmu< mEHmm mmsmusmz mend mEHmm mmcmncmz Demo ucwo owed mEHmm Demo Demo mmud mEumm coflmmm mom mom HmDOB HODESZ Mom mom Hmuoe HOQEDZ mmma omma mmma QZ< omma mZOHBDmHmBmHQ MU 6066506 mo 666605066 66 60mm066X0 066 006666665OM .6606500 6066056066 66606062 066 66 60666650 6666 "006506 FH.PHH mm.mbm.m mm.© m©.©mH ¢O.m¢ mm.Hm h¢.mmb Nm.mm mm.HOm.H 5N.¢m m©.HNm.fiififlOE Hm.ON mm.hh© mm. dm.©m w®.HH hm.m mm.hHH fim.¢ 0?.ONN hm.m ¢O.HmN mmmH mm.h FO.MHm HH.H mm.®m N®.m OH.H hm.¢N Ow.m BH.NmH V®.H MN.O® mmma fiN.m Om.N¢m Oh. hO.®H ©®.m Gm.N ho.mm mm.m m0.mmH woom m¢.h© hmmH 66.6 66.666 66. 66.6 66.6 60.6 06.66 66. 66.6 66.6 66.666 6666 66.66 66.666 06. 66.6 66.06. 66. 66.6 06.6 66.666 66.6 60.606 6666 NH.m O¢.OPN 6N. ©®.m mm.m ¢©.H h¢.mm m¢.H mm.h® om.m HN.mmH fimma 66.6 66.666 66. 66.6 66.6 60.6 66.666 66. 66.66 66.6 66.66 6666 66.06 66.666 66.6 66.66 II 66.6 60.666 66.6 66.066 60.6 66.666 6666 06.66 66.606 66.6 66.66 II 66.6 66.666 66.6 66.666 66.6 66.66 6666 66.6 66.666 66. 66.6 II 66.6 06.66 66. 06.66 66.6 66.66 0666 05H6> 60.606650 056666 .6650 05666,. .6650 05.665 .6650 05a6> 60.606650 056666 66.36650 660% 66609 960660 6006 60m 66606 6600 0066 66666I0666 .2660066 2066666666666 60666 666 MMQZD mmm¢mUMDm NBHQOZEOU “AHUZDOU ZOHeobflomm AdZOHBfiZ m.m mqmdfi 167 TABLE 5.10 NATIONAL PRODUCTION COUNCIL: PURCHASES OF RICE, BEANS AND CORN AS PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL PRODUCTION, 1950-1959 Year Rice Corn Beans 1950 10.2 3.2 23.2 1951 9.5 9.6 56.1 1952 38.9 12.0 59.9 1953 11.8 3.3 44.4 1954 24.0 3.8 10.1 1955 53.6 31.8 2.6 1956 37.8 0.5 17.3 1957 13.1 12.5 24.4 1958 11.3 10.8 9.4 1959 61.0 12.9 57.1 Average 25.3 9.8 29.5 Source: Computed from data in Table 5.9, and Appendix I. It can be observed that there were considerable year to year variations in the percentage of total production repre- sented by the commodities purchased under the price stabili- zation plan. On the average, however, the Consejo controlled 25.3 per cent of total rice production, 9.8 per cent of corn and 29.5 per cent of total bean production during the 1950- 1959 period. 168 In order to maintain price stability and satisfy de— mand conditions, the Consejo found it necessary to import specific commodities. During the 1950-1959 period, it was necessary to import rice from 1956 to 1959 and beans in 1956 and 1959. Total rice imports amounted to 355.2 mil- lion pounds and represented a cost of 13.3 million colones. A total of 104.7 million pounds of beans with a cost of 55.4 million colones were imported in 1958 and 1959.1 The price stabilization program is financed by the Consejo from its own funds as well as from credit from the Central Bank. The Central Bank will lend the Consejo up to eighty per cent of the value of commodities in storage up to a maximum of sixteen million colones. The interest rate on these loans varies from three to four per cent per year. The Consejo can borrow from other commercial banks up to twenty per cent of the value of commodities stored at rates of interest of six per cent. Altogether, the price stabilization program has access to credit funds amounting to over 26 million colones a year. 1From unpublished data supplied by the National Pro- duction Council. 169 Price Stabilization System for Consumer Goods In 1950, a law called "Law of Economic Defense” was enacted to regulate internal prices for some basic commo- dities which are ”indispensable” to the consumers' diet. This law sets up maximum prices for indispensable goods subjected to periodical revisions and limits the gross mar- gin of retail and wholesale establishments dealing with consumer goods. However, the law made no provision to control speculation. Since 1948, the Consejo was given the power to control the price stability of indispensable goods. For this purpose, the Consejo was allowed to sta- bilize prices and counterspeculate as well as to use its storage facilities to regulate the supply of indispensable consumer goods. To meet this end, the Consejo relies on a network of retail and wholesale establishments. In 1959, this network consisted of seven wholesale stores and 59 retail establishments located throughout the country. Plans for fifteen other stores are pending on account of lack of funds. The establishment of the Consejo transacted 106.5 mil- lion colones of business during the 1950-59 period. The volume of sales has been increasing; and it reached an 170 all-time high of 21.4 million colones in 1959.1 Although the Consejo considers normal profits to vary from six to ten per cent of gross sales for wholesale stores and from ten to fifteen per cent in retail stores, total profits amounted to 3.3 per cent of gross sales in 1959.2 The Consejo stores currently sell some 120 different consumption goods. Other Activities and Policies of the Consejo The Consejo has grain elevators with a total capacity of over eighty million pounds.3 Although the construction<1f regional grain elevators is given high priority at the present, the grain elevator in the Pacific Province of Puntarenas (Barranca) still accounts for one-half of the Consejo's total storage capacity. The Consejo also operates feed mixing plants which prepare concentrate for animals and a flour mill. In 1Consejo Nacional de Produccion, Fundamentos y Otros gggLos Expendios y Almancenes de Consejo Nacional de Pro- duccion (San José, 1961), Mimeo, 14, 19. 21bid., 9-10, 16. 3A large proportion of the C.N.P. grain elevator tech- nical staff was trained in the U.S. under the auspices of the ICA. 171 addition, the Consejo built and administers a model slaughter house in Cartago which has a slaughtering capa- city of 105 head a day. A second slaughter house to be built in Alajuela will have a capacity to process 300 animals a day. The Consejo has operated the Nacional Liquor Factory--a government monopoly--since 1949, and receives 42 per cent of the profits of the liquor mono- poly. A portion of these profits are used to build feeder roads in rural areas. In order to contribute to agricultural development the Consejo acts as a guarantor of producers for credit with commercial banks for credit up to 100,000 colones. Under this provision the Institution has made credit available to producers which amounted to 38.3 million colones from 1951—59.1 The Consejo also aids producer cooperatives. This organism is the major shareholder of the Milk Producers Cooperative. Among other activities, this organization processes powdered milk which is stored by the Consejo and distributed to the Ministry of Health's nutrition program. 1Unpublished data supplied by the Consejo Nacional de ProducCion. 172 Agricultural Credit System The agricultural credit system had its origin in 1914 with the founding of the International Bank. The program was to make loans to small producers for amounts not greater than 500 colones out of an original fund of 200,000 colones. The modern agricultural credit system in Costa Rica, however, was started in 1937 by the National Bank which replaced the International Bank. This credit system operates through the use of local boards and committees called Rural Boards of Agricultural Credit. The National Bank's branches administer agencies which in 1957 numbered 48 (see Table 5.1D. These agencies operate exclusively with respect to agricultural credit. Each agency is governed by a local board of five members appointed by the banks for terms of two years with provision for reappoint- ment. Members of the Board are paid an honorarium for each session attended. The necessary office and field staff of each agency are appointed by the Bank and must include an ingeniero agronomo (agronomist) who must reside in the area and acts as an executive officer. The agronomist has a voice but no vote in the local board. His main duty is to Supervise the loans granted to producers. 173 The Central Office of the Rural Credit Boards advises the local boards, supervises their operations, and acts as their intermediary before the Board of Directors and other officers of the National Bank. Loans are granted to pro- ducers without procurement charges and are classified into three major categories: short term loans (one year or less); medium term loans (more than one year but less than ten years) and long term loans (ten years or more). Each major category is subdivided into agriculture, livestock, and industry (especially those utilizing agricultural raw ma- terials). These major subdivisions include loans for work— ing expenses, investment in equipment or other capital goods, transportation storage, and services, loans for purchasing or improvement of property, mortgage cancella- tion, etc.1 The interest rate is six percent per year. Each load is limited to fifteen thousand colones per per- son, however, the maximum credit at any one time is to twenty thousand colones per person. Personal guarantee of the recipient is the usual security accepted by the rural boards 0n short—term loans, however, for medium and long 1Banco Nacional de Costa Rica-Juntas Rurales de Cre- dito Agricola, Classificacion de Creditos, San José, November, 1955, Mimeo, 19-21, 23. 174 term loans, the pledging of chattels (including livestock) or mortgages on real estate are required. In 1956, short term loans amounted to 41.9 per cent of the loans, medium term 51.9 per cent and long term 6.2 per cent.1 During 1947—52, 4,732 loans with a total value of over 10.7 mil— lion colones were granted for the purchases of farms. Over half these were made to tenants. According to one author,3 the Agricultural Credit System in Costa Rica is one of the world's most successful examples of rural credit systems operated using local boards. The agricultural credit system operated four rural agencies in 1943 which made 578 operations amounting to 145,300 colones; by 1949, the number of rural agencies had increased to 33 and granted 15,846 loan applications with a total value of almost 14 million colones.4 From 1937 to 1949 rural boards granted 100,000 loans to small producers which amounted to 61.8 million colones. During this same lOp. cit., Echeverria, 47. 21bid., 38, 41. 3H. Belshaw, "Agricultural Credit in Economically Underdeveloped Countries, F.A.O., Rome, 1959, 140. 4Echeverria, op. cit., 39, 49. 175 period (1937-49) which covers 19 years, the operation of the Rural Credit Boards has represented a 1.9 million colones loss to the National Bank. This operational loss is assumed by the bank as a public service contribution. However, losses on credit amounted only to 2,499 colones which represent the balance on 14 loans.1 Table 5. shows that from 1950 to 1957 the rural boards granted 154,151 loans for a total of 218.7 million colones. The volume of credit in these eight years more than tripled the 1937-49 period. In 1957, the number of loans reached an all—time high of 27,566 which amounted to 51.2 million colones. It is estimated that by 1957, 95 per cent of the farmers were being served by the rural credit boards.2 Although a large proportion of the loans are made with the personal guarantee of the recipient (65 per cent in 1952; 42 per cent in 1956), the total loss on credits granted by the rural boards from 1937 to 1955 amounted to 27,245 colones which represent the balance of 52 loans. These figures are insignificant if one takes into account that during that period, 208,957 loans with a value of 194,420 million colones were made. lIbid., 32. 2Belshaw, op. cit., 142. 3Echeverria, op. cit., 46. RURAL CREDIT BOARDS, NUMBER AND VOLUME 176 TABLE 5.11 OF LOANS, 1950-1957 Year Number of Number of Valuea Average Boards Loans Loana 1950 33 17,752 16,976.6 2.32 1951 37 19,403 21,146.4 2.50 1952 38 19,994 24,623.0 2.99 1953 39 18,006 23,824.7 3.43 1954 40 16,838 24,221.3 1.45 1955 44 16,967 26,186.2 1.56 1956 47 17,625 30,492.5 1.73 1957 48 27,566 51,240.0 1.76 Total 48 154,151 218,701.7 2.22 Source: Luis Echeverria, Resena Cronologica de las Cajas de Credito Agricola del Banco International de Costa ‘Rica 1914-36 y de las Juntas Rurales de Credito Agricola del Banco Nacional de Costa Rica 1937-1957 (San José, 46-50. 36, agriculture were explored in detail in this chapter. 39, 42-43, a Thousands of colones. Summary 1958), The performance and characteristics of Costa Rica‘s The latest Census of Agriculture (1955) indicates that 177 Costa Rica has 47,286 farms covering a total area of 2.65 million manzanas (4.5 million acres). The land in farms (including farm wood lots) represents 36.4 per cent of the Costa Rican territory. A total of 260,736 manzanas were brought into cultivation from 1950—1955. There still remains a large acreage of idle farm land which could be brought into production. It was estimated in the early 1950's that an additional 27 per cent of the land in forests could be utilized for agricultural production. Costa Rica is a country of small agricultural pro- ducers; in 1955, 60.3 per cent of all farms were 19 man- zanas (32.3 acres) or less, and account for 7.4 per cent of the farm land. However, in 1955, 0.1 per cent of all farms or 50 farms comprised 21.0 per cent of all farm land. These figures suggest the presence of minifundia as well as latifundia type of ownership. In 1955, 75.5 per cent of all farms, and 88.9 per cent of the total agricultural land in Costa Rica was being farmed by their legal owners. The agricultural census of 1955 shows that 15.2 per cent of the total farm land is utilized for annual crops (and fallow land), in other words, land used mainly to 178 produce crops for internal consumption. Of the total farm land, 8.5 per cent was in permanent crops grown mainly for exports (i.e., coffee, bananas and cocoa) and 39.0 per cent was in pastures. The remaining 36.5 per cent of the total farm land was in forest. As can be expected in an underdeveloped country, Costa Rican agriculture is characterized by its lack of diver— sification. However, for the size of the country, Costa Rican agriculture has a relatively high degree of diver— sity. In 1955, fourteen commodities (ten principal crops plus livestock, milk, swine and lumber) were responsible for 92 per cent of the total value of agricultural produc- tion. Coffee, bananas and cocoa, which are produced pri- marily for export, accounted for 53.4 per cent of the total value of agricultural production. In 1955, 59.5 per cent of the total volume of agricultural production was exported and 40.5 per cent was domestically consumed. During the 1950—1959 decade, there was considerable increase in the volume of production of principal crops (with exception of bananas) and livestock production. Table 5.7 shows that coffee production more than doubled during the period while banana production declined. Sugar cane, 179 corn and rice production increased during the period while bean output increased moderately. However, these increases in production were accompanied by considerable increases in area planted. Coffee production rose 138.2 per cent from 1950 to 1959 while coffee land increased 49.0 per cent; likewise, sugar cane rose 93.0 per cent in volume while area rose 52.2 per cent. This indicates sharp pro- ductivity increases in these two commodities. Conversely, corn shows a slight increase in output over the area planted while beans and rice output was surpassed by the increase in area. Banana production decreased despite the increase in area planted. This evidence suggests that increases in output of the staple food commodities (corn, beans and rice) have been brought about by increases in area planted rather than by productivity gains. A relatively high absolute increase in output has been experienced by animal and animal products. During the 1950- 1959 period, livestock numbers rose from 100 in 1950 (base period) to 180.1 in 1959, or 80 per cent; milk production increased 43.1 per cent while swine production showed little change. 180 Some of the progress made by Costa Rican agriculture is attributed to the Agricultural Extension Service, the price stabilization policies of the National Production Council and to the Rural Credit System. Although it is difficult to measure the degree of success of price stabil- ization policies, at least some of the general stability of agricultural price levels during the 1950-1959 period can be attributed to the Consejo and its policies. The Rural Credit System has been very successful. Success can be measured not only in terms of the volume of credit granted to small farmers but also in terms of an enviable repayment record. CHAPTER'VI AGRICULTURE AND INTERNAL GROWTH Chapter I pointed out that agriculture can make impor— tant contributions to internal growth by earning foreign exchange through food exports, providing funds for capital formation, serving as a market for industrial products, providing manpower for other expanding sectors and finally, providing increased food supplies for the indigenous popu— lation. This chapter will explore the contributions of agriculture to the growth of the Costa Rican economy in the 1950-1959 period. It has been pointed out in Chapter III that the rural sector in Costa Rica comprised 66.5 per cent of the popula- tion in 1955 and employed 54.7 per cent of the economically active population in 1950.1 Furthermore, agriculture pro— vided an average of 43.7 per cent of the gross domestic product over the 1950-59 period (see Table 6.1). These figures alone show that agriculture is the major existing industry in Costa Rica and hence indicate the importance of _ 1 See Chapter III. 181 182 agriculture as a market for industrial products and as a source of revenue for over-all capital formation. These figures also show the importance of agriculture as a source of labor for expanding non-agricultural sectors. In fact, the economically active population engaged in agriculture decreased seven per cent from 1927 to 1950.1 How well has Costa Rican agriculture provided an in- crease in food supplies? To avoid price increases, food supplies must expand at a rate equal to the rate of growth of population plus the increment of per capita income times the income elasticity of demand.2 For the 1950—1959 period, Costa Rica experienced annual rates of population growth and per capita income of 3.87 and 3.66 per cent respec- . 3 . . tively. Thus, the required annual rate of increase of agricultural output, assuming an income elasticity of 0.5, lo . cit., 14. 2Should output fail to rise at the required rate, food prices begin to rise relatively, reducing the real income of the population, especially the wage-salary classes since they spend a higher pr0portion of their income on food. Since rising food prices may lead to political discontent, the alternative is to grant money wage increases (thus reduc- ing profits and investment) or to import more food (which Will compete with capital imports for economic development). 3See Chapter III and Chapter IV. 183 would be 5.7 per cent. If income elasticities of 0.6 and 0.7 are assumed, the corresponding annual rates of growth of agricultural output will be 6.0 and 7.4 per cent. Table 6.1 shows agriculture's contribution to the gross domestic product of Costa Rica in constant prices for the period TABLE 6.1 COSTA RICA: PERCENTAGE CONTRIBUTION OF AGRICULTURE TO GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT 1950-1959 Millions of Colones at Constant Prices Agriculture's Year T2321 Agriggggure's Contribution to GNP Per Cent 1950 1067.9 546.4 51.16 1951 1120.1 564.1 50.36 1952 1377.8 648.9 47.09 1953 1568.4 695.8 44.36 1954 1605.7 646.5 40.26 1955 1706.7 750.0 43.94 1956 1744.2 655.7 37.59 1957 1880.1 727.7 38.70 1958 2019.1 860.8 42.63 1959 2069.7 858.3 41.47 Source: Chapter IV, Table 4.5, p. 135. aAgriculture's GDP was deflated by the combined whole- sale agricultural price reproduced in Table 6.3. 184 1950-1959.1 The growth of agricultural output computed from these aggregates shows that agriculture achieved an annual rate of growth of 4.55 per cent.2 Therefore, in View of the discrepancy between the "required" and the actual rate of agricultural output, Costa Rican agricul— ture has apparently fallen short of meeting the increased demand for food induced by rising incomes and population. To explain this phenomenon the following hypotheses are advanced: first, the apparent inability of agriculture to cope with increased demand for food may be traced to statistical inadequacies of aggregate data. In other words, since national accounts do not measure non-market production of goods and services (i.e., farm produce _ 1This table shows that agriculture contributes over forty per cent to “the total output of the nation. However, the rate of growth of the agricultural sector is the slow- est of all sectors and contributes only 28 per cent to the rate of growth of the Costa Rican economy. This figure was obtained by using a formula proposed by Kuznets to calculate the share of growth of agricultural production in the growth of total product. Simon Kuznets, "Economic Growth and the Contribution of Agriculture: Notes on Measurement," Inter- national Journal of Agrarian Affairs, Vol. III, No. 2 (April, 1961), 59. 2The rate of growth of domesticly consumed agricultural production (agriculture's GDP minus exports, both at con- stant prices) was 4.3 per cent per year. 185 consumed at the farm or subsistance production and labor), agricultural output, and hence the rate of growth, may be underestimated. Second, the distribution of income may be such that the rise in incomes has benefited only a relatively small sector of the population and therefore, higher incomes do not bring forth a proportional increase in the demand for food. In this situation, consumption by the masses may have increased, remained constant or pos— sibly decreased over the 1950-1959 period. The third hypothesis is that the failure of supply to cope with increased demand may have been met by increased food im— ports. The fourth hypothesis is that the income elasticity of demand may be less than 0.5. Finally, a fifth proposi- tion contains elements of the above four hypotheses. It could be expected that estimates of agricultural production in Costa Rica underestimate the actual output stream since the non-market production may be substantial. Lack of data on consumption levels for the 1950-1959 period as well as data on income distribution do not allow us to substantiate to what extent the second hypothesis may explain the phenomenon. Since it is unlikely that the in— come elasticity of demand for food is less than .5, the 186 proposition left for consideration is that the increased demand for food induced by population and income growth has been met, at least partially by increased food imports. Table 6.2 shows the value of food imported by Costa Rica from 1952 to 1959.1 It can be seen that food imports rose from 8.2 million dollars in 1952 to 15.2 million dollars in 1959, and represent a total expenditure of 91.92 million dollars over the period. Cereals represent 43.9 per cent of the total value of imports during the period, followed by milk products, eggs and honey with 13.03 per cent. Although 5.7 per cent of the total imports of Costa Rica during this period are live animals for consumption and meat and meat products, Costa Rica has become a net beef exporter since 1954.3 The bottom line of Table 6.2 shows that food imports as a percentage of total imports have remained at a fairly constant rate——ll to 25 per cent—- over the 1952—1959 period. Likewise, food imports as a 1Data for 1950 and 1951 are not included since import classification for those years does not allow an accurate estimate of food imports. 2This item is very heavily influenced by wheat imports, a commodity which is not produced in Costa Rica. Rice im- ports are shown in Table 6.2, p. 187. 3See Table 7.1. 187 TABLE 6.2 COSTA RICA: FOOD IMPORTS 1952-1959 Thousands of Dollars Classification 1952 1953 1953 1955 Live animals for consumption 240.9 79.3 267.8 250.0 Meat and meat products 147.0 191.7 189.4 119.0 Milk products, eggs and honey 1,032.0 1,428.8 1,304.1 1,385.3 Fish, seafood and seafood products 437.2 517.6 546.7 435.9 Cereals and cereal products 3,749.6 3,905.2 4,375.3 5,882.0 Fruits and vegetables 606.7 718.1 662.7 1,061.8 Sugar and sugar Products 194.6 266.8 224.8 208.4 Tea, cocoa, Spices 136.8 173.3 188.5 136.2 Feedstuffs for animal nutrition 258.9 366.2 303.7 497.6 Other food products 1,401.0 1,424.2 1,980.7 1,830.§_ Total food imports 8,204.7 9,071.2 10,043.7 11.807-0 Food imports as per cent of t1.imports: 12.09 12.31 12.45 13.50 Food imports as per cent of agricul- tural GDPa 7.16 7.58 8.32 8.12. Source: Unpublished data, General de Estadistica y Censo Supplied by the Direccion 188 Year 1956 1957 1958 1959 1952-59 1952‘59 Per Cent 182.1 150.5 177.2 2,785.9 4,133.7 4.50 162.4 121.8 93.7 113.7 1,138.7 1.24 1,522.6 1,822.8 1,917.9 1,561.9 11,975.4 13.03 383.5 365.1 407.8 461.0 3,554.8 3.87 6,054.6 5,102.0 5,262.3 6,030.3 40,361.3 43.91 1,855.6 746.4 642.6 1,017.6 7,311.5 7.95 1,447.7 213.0 232.8 202.2 2,990.3 3,25 140.1 118.1 163.8 146.7 1,203.5 1.31 882.3 926.9 1,236.0 1,470.5 5,942.1 6.46 1,714.1 1,804.0 1,653.8 1,501.6 13,310.2 14.48 14,345.0 11,370.6 11,787.9 15,291.4 91,921.5 100.00 15.72 11.06 11.87 14.89 12.18 8.61 7.57 9.81 a I In constant prices. 189 percentage of agriculture's GDP, have remained relatively stable at levels ranging from 7 to 12 per cent. On the export side of the picture, agricultural exports rose from an index of 80 in 1950 to 109 in 1959 (1953 = 100), and Costa Rica has experienced favorable balance of trade during the 1950-1959 period.1 Table 6.3 presents some general price indexes for the Costa Rican economy. The wholesale price index declined from 112.9 in 1950 to 100.0 in 1953 and rose again to 107.4 in 1959. The retail price index increased steadily from 96.3 in 1950 to 117.5 in 1959. The cost of living index rose from 100.0 in 1952 (base period) to 113.4 in 1959 at a rate of 1.6 per cent per year. The foodstuff index (a component of the cost of living index) rose 14.9 per cent from 1952 to 1959. These price indexes reveal a consider- able degree of price stability especially for an economy which is growing at a rate of eight per cent per year (GNP). Summary The gross domestic product of agriculture has exper- ienced an annual rate of growth of 4.55 per cent over the lIbid., Table 7.6. 190 TABLE 6.3 COSTA RICA: GENERAL PRICE LEVEL INDEXES, 1950—1959 Year Whole— . a COSt Retail AE:::Il‘ salea Retail LiSEn Food—c Price g stuffs Indexd 1950 112.90 96.35 -- -— 100.62 1951 116.45 102.91 -- -- 104.50 1952 104.52 100.04 100.00 100.00 98.96 1953 100.00 100.00 100.48 101.62 100.00 1954 104.41 103.03 103.09 105.84 111.96 1955 107.24 103.63 106.93 109.74 104.04 1956 108.14 104.64 108.00 110.00 107.07 1957 108.05 105.15 110.15 110.86 108.31 1958 108.01 114.46 113.07 115.59 100.03 1959 107.43 117.53 113.39 114.96 92.62 aPrice index computed by the Central Bank of Costa Rica with a base of 1953 = 100, Décima Memoria Anual, Afio 1959 (San José: Mayo 1960), 85-87; price indexes for 1950-52 are the author's extrapolations of previous indexes computed by the Central Bank with a base of 1936 = 100, Sexta Memoria Anual, A60 1955 (San José: Marzo, 1956), 87-88. bIndex computed by the Direccion General de Estadistica y Censo, reproduced in Décima Memoria Anual, A60 1959, 87. CA component of the Cost of Living Index. Price index computed by the author based on livestock, export and agricultural products wholesale price indexes (computed by the Central Bank) using the 1950—1955 weights. 191 1950-1959 period. With per capita income growing at an annual rate of 3.66 per cent and assuming an income elasticity of demand for food of .5, the annual growth of demand for food would be 5.7 per cent. Judging from these growth rates, agriculture has apparently been unable to satisfy the increased demand for food. Two principal propositions may help to explain this phenomenon. First, since national income data do not include non-market agri- cultural output, and this output may be substantial in Costa Rica, gross domestic product may have underestimated agriculture's output. Second, the income distribution in Costa Rica may be such that rising incomes may have benefited only a small sector of the population and therefore, have not induced a proportional increase in demand for food. Thus, in one hand, the actual rate of growth of agricultural supplies in Costa Rica may have been higher than the one shown by agriculture's gross domestic product; on the other hand, the actual rate of increase of demand for food induced by higher incomes may have been lower than the "required" theoretical rate. Moreover, the discrepancy between agricultural supply and demand growth rates was partially filled by food imports. Increased food imports 192 does not necessarily mean a failure of agriculture to cope with demand increases induced by higher incomes and popu- lation growth. The dualism of the agricultural sector in Costa Rica (and other underdeveloped countries), allows agriculture to fail to meet food requirements while agri— cultural exports pay for food imports. Costa Rican agriculture seems to have fallen short of satisfying internal demand for food, as can be deduced from the increase in food imports. However, the relative stability of food imports as a percentage of total imports and of total agricultural output, indicates that agricul- ture's position in coping with internal demand may not have improved but at least it has not deteriorated. Moreover, indexes of agricultural exports and balance of trade con- ditions reveal that agriculture has succeeded not only in paying for the rise in food imports but also for almost all non-agricultural imports during the 1950-1959 period. Wholesale and retail price indexes indicate a consider— able degree of price stability in the Costa Rican economy over the 1950-1959 period. The cost of living index rose 1The performance of Costa Rican agriculture in the production of export commodities will be explored in greater detail in the next chapter. 193 from 100.0 in 1952 to 113.4 in 1959 at a rate of 1.42 per cent per year. The food component of the cost of living index rose from 100.0 in 1952 to 114.9 in 1959 or an annual rate of increase of 1.47 per cent.1 These figures indicate that, unlike other Latin American countries, Costa Rica has not experienced sharp price increases caused by unsatisfied demand for food products. Annual price increases are not only moderate but could also be said to be normal in an economy which is growing at a rate of eight per cent per year (GNP). Some of the price stability may be attributed to the successful price stabilization policies of the CNP. lThe wholesale index of agricultural prices for domes- tic consumption rose from 100.0 in 1953 to 105.4 in 1955 and then declined to 101.7 in 1959. A total weighted wholesale price index of agricultural products is reproduced in Table 6.3. This index, however, is very heavily influen— ced by the large price increases of agricultural exports from 1954 to 1957 and their subsequent decline since 1957. CHAPTER VII AGRICULTURE AND EXTERNAL BALANCE It was pointed out in Chapter I that one of the char- acteristics of small underdeveloped nations is the high concentration of production in primary production for international trade. Small nations, as well as most pri- mary producers, are confronted with two main problems in their relations with industrial countries. First, unstable export proceeds caused by a high degree of price instability of primary products in international markets, and second, a relative decline in their long-run capacity to import caused by the deterioration of their terms of trade. The recommended structural solution for these two main problems is industrialization. However, even if the argument is valid, industrialization is a long-run process and at least, in the short-run, agriculture can plan an important role in external balance by paying for capital imports re- quired for economic development. Moreover, agricultural exports may be called upon to pay for food imports should agriculture fail to satisfy domestic demand. This chapter explores the contribution of Costa Rican agriculture to 194 195 the external balance of the nation's economy over the 1950— 1959 period. It will deal with the situation and principal trends of exports, imports, balance of trade, balance of payments and the price stability of the external sector of Costa Rica from 1950 to 1959. Costa Rica has a high degree of concentration of eco- nomic activity in production for export. In fact, over the 1950-1959 period, exports represented an average of 23.4 per cent of the nation's GNP and 58.3 per cent of the agricultural GDP (see Table 7.1). However, since 1953 agricultural exports have represented a smaller percentage of GNP. Over the 1950—1959 period, coffee, bananas and cocoa accounted for 91.7 per cent of the total value of exports. Table 7.1 shows the relative importance of the main exports during this period. Coffee represented 44.3 per cent of total exports, bananas 41.3 per cent, cocoa 6.1 per cent, jute 2.0 per cent and livestock and beef 1.5 per cent. These five commodities are responsible for 95 per cent of the total exports. During this ten year period, banana exports have declined in importance in absolute terms and in rela- tion to coffee which has become the leading export 196 .6006 u 66660 600666 60666000 066 .06 .60 .60006 .666666060>66D 0606600 6060 66000 00 0606060> I66D .06606xm 606000116060 66000 00 006506000 0660666000 60 8066 6660 0006 6066 .60006 £0662 .0000 6600 0006 000 666664 6660802 66X00 606 .60006 .0000 6600 66660 066Qm0m 0560 10060 .0006 000 6060 66000 00 00060 00 6666660 .6060 66000 00 6666600 00660 "006600 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 06.00 00.60 00.00 06.00 00.00 6020 0.0666 16606606 60 6600 60m 06 066omx0 66609 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.06 06.06 06.00 00.06 06.00 00.00 60.00 00.00 6020 00 6600 60m 06 066omx0 66609 00.006 60.000 00.00 00.60 00.00 06.00 00.00 00.60 66.00 00.00 06.00 00.00 066omx0 66608 00.6 00.00 00.0 00.6 06.0 60.0 60.0 00.0 00.6 06.0 06.0 00.0 06600x0 60:60 066.6 00.66 00.0 00.0 06.0 00.6 00. 066. II ..I ..I II 00090660060066 00.0 00.06 60. 00.6 60. 00.6 00. 00.6 00.0 00.0 60.0 00.6 0660 06.0 06.06 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.6 00.6 60.6 00.6 06060 00.66 60.000 00.06 00.00 00.06 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.60 06.00 00.06 006000 00.66 06.060 00.06 06.00 00.00 00.00 60.00 60.00 00.00 00.00 00.60 00.60 0666660 00I0006 0006 0066 I 0006 0006 0006 0006 0006 6006 0006 0006 6006 0006 00666008500 60060 0006 I 0 0666600 00 06066662 0006:0006 memomxm .m.o.m 60805 "40Hm 09000 6.0 mgmflfi 197 TABLE 7.2 UNITED FRUIT COMPANY EXPORTS AS PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL COSTA RICAN EXPORTS, 1955 - 1959 Commodity 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 Average Bananas 98.82 98.95 99.53 98.79 96.12 98.44 Cacao 36.61 33.79 39.35 31.28 25.50 33.06 Jute 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 Total exports 44.31 41.46 41.82 31.98 27.74 37.46 Source: Banco Central de Costa Rica, Balanza de Pagos de Costa Rica, 1959, Undecimo Reporte Anual (San José, 1960), 18. commodity. Similarly, the relative importance of jute ex— ports declined during the 1950-1959 period while beef and livestock exports have increased both in absolute terms and in relative importance. The United Fruit Company marketed over 98 per cent of banana exports, all jute exports and one-third of the cocoa exports, as shown in Table 7.2. This table also shows that United Fruit marketed 37.5 per cent of the total Costa Rican exports during the 1955-1959 period. 198 The United Fruit Company plantations are located pri- marily in the Southern Pacific Coast of Costa Rica. In 1955, the company had 25,000 acres of bananas, 10,000 acres of African palm oil and 5,000 acres of cocoa. In addition, they had 5,000 acres of jute and 19,000 acres of cocoa in the Atlantic Coast near Port Limon. In total, the United Fruit Company had approximately half a million acres of land in Costa Rica which represents approximately four per cent of the nation's territory. In 1955, about one—fourth of the land possessed by United Fruit was under cultivation}' Unlike bananas, the coffee industry is entirely owned by Costa Ricans. Moreover, a great proportion of coffee output is produced on small farms. In 1955, 42 per cent of the coffee output was produced on farms of less than 84 acres and 24.8 per cent on farms between 84 and 186 acres.2 Farms of these two sizes accounted for 90.8 per cent of 3 the total number of farms in 1955. 1Stacy May and Galo Plaza, La United Fruit Company en America Latina (New York: National Planning Association, 1958), 151-52. Direccion General de Estadistica y Censo, Censo Agro— Egguario de 1955 (San Jose, 1959), XXVII. 3 See Chapter V. 199 This dichotomy in the ownership and organization of production of Costa Rica's two most important exports, cof— fee and bananas, has important economic implications. Price changes of banana exports have less impact on the economy as a whole than price changes in coffee exports. In the first place, since the coffee industry is entirely owned by Costa Ricans, nearly all the foreign exchange generated by coffee exports is absorbed by the nation's economy. Con— versely, since most of Costa Rica's bananas are produced and exported by the United Fruit Company, only a certain percentage of the earnings from banana exports come into the country. The reason for this is that under the pres- ent contract, the United Fruit Company is authorized to subtract profits, capital depreciation allowances, and the cost of its own imports, from its export earnings.l Thus, a relative price change in banana exports has less impact on export earnings than a similar price change in coffee exports. Moreover, since the total value of coffee exports (even at constant prices) is greater than that of bananas, Costa Rica received an average of 44.8 per cent of the total export earnings of the United Fruit Company during 1948 to 1954. Universidad de Costa Rica, El Desarrollo Eco- nomico de Costa Rica-~Sector Externo (Ciudad Universitaria, 1959), 21-22. 200 fluctuations in coffee prices will have a greater impact on the Costa Rican economy than equivalent changes in banana prices. Finally, since a larger proportion of the population is dependent either directly or indirectly on the coffee industry, price changes of coffee exports affect a larger proportion of the population than would export price changes of bananas. Table 7.1 shows the value of Costa Rican exports over the 1950—1959 period. Exports rose from 55.6 million dol— lars in 1950 to 84.7 million in 1954, declined to 67.4 million dollars in 1956 and rose to an all-time high of 91.9 million dollars in 1958 and declined to 76.7 million dollars in 1959. Year to year fluctuations in export earn— ings averaged 10.6 per cent over the period considered. Table 7.3 shows price and volume indexes of total ex- ports and of principal export commodities from 1950 to 1959. The total volume of exports increased 36.2 per cent from 1950 to 1959. However, there were significant year to year variations in volume which averaged 13.2 per cent during the period considered (range 2-27 per cent). Exports prices rose from 84 in 1950 to 109 in 1957 (116 in 1956) and then declined since 1958 to a low of 84 in 1959. Indexes of 201 both volume and price of exports seem to be dominated and behave similarly to corresponding indexes of coffee ex- ports. Coffee exports rose 126.4 per cent from 1950 to 1959, however, year to year volume variations average 20.0 per cent during this period. Coffee prices rose from 78 to 124 by 1956, then declined to 116 in 1957 and finally to 78 in 1959. Year to year variations in price averaged 14.0 per cent during this period. Banana exports have decreased 37.5 per cent from 1950 to 1959 with average yearly variation in volume of 13.1 per cent. Banana prices increased fairly constantly from 1950 to 1957 and declined sharply to 87 and 88 during 1958 and 1959. Banana prices showed a yearly price fluctuation of only 4.33 per cent; the least variation of all export commodities. Table 7.4 shows the geographical destination of Costa Rican exports for 1950, 1955 and 1959. In 1959, 48.9 per cent of all export commodities were exported to the United States, 25.2 per cent to Germany and 11.9 per cent to other European countries. The value of Costa Rican exports to the United States decreased 29.3 per cent while the value of exports to Germany has increased 24.8 per cent over the 1950-1959 period. Germany is the principal market for Costa Rica's coffee. 202 .A066OQX0 mo 05660> >6 0066666665 0560 . . 6 6660055000 0066 . B 60 05608 05006 H6 .66066 66666 6c6 0006 .6600v 0066066660 666066666 6660666660666 .0666 66660602 666066666066 . H "006600 6.00 006 006 60 006 006 606 00 606 00 00 00mm 0.006 006 006 60 006 006 666 00 606 00 00 0006 0.00 006 606 006 00 00 006 066 006 006 00 0006 0.00 006 606 066 00 00 00 606 60 066 00 0006 0.006 006 066 006 00 006 666 066 606 006 00 0006 0.006 00 066 066 60 066 066 006 00 006 006 6006 0.006 006 006 006 006 006 006 006 006 006 006 0006 0.60 006 00 60 00 00 006 00 00 60 666 0006 0.00 606 00 00 00 006 06 00 00 00 00 6006 0.00 00 00 60 00 006 06 00 00 60 00 0006 e e e e W M. . W W W. W W W W W W W 05606 0660656 .68 06606xm .69 60000 006600 0 0666666 006u,0006 0006I0006 madmfi 6¢ZOHB 606 66> 606 0666> 606666666066 0006 660666660000 uom06 0606 mm06 om06 0606600 60 00066662 0006 .0006 .0006 09606Xm 60 ZOHEfiZHEme 6m mom.6mm 6mm.hao.a wom.h¢© mmm.am© mna.mmm.ma mmma mom.ov© oma.omm owh.mvn.a me.¢ao omm.mo¢ VmH.nmm.mH 6mma mmm.vmm www.6hm oma.mm¢.a vm©.¢mm mmm.©m© Hmo.mom.ma mmma mmh.mam 0mm.m©m oao.mmm.a mmm.mmm www.mav www.mam.aa mmma Hmm.¢mm www.mam mom.voo.m omm.©am mmm.vmm mmh.mam.oa Hmma VmN.HHv moo.mmm Hom.©mm.a mom.hm© hmm.mv¢ mm¢.aom.¢a omma maou .mQH OOH .mQH 00H .mQH 00H mcoe wwmmou mwzocom Iflumm moflm mommm GHOU mono ummom m mcmcmm om¢ mmlomma ZOHBUDQOmm qmmDBQDUHm0< m0 HZDAO> uflva