rd”9-. . . N firm'ynrug.. r-g‘sz'flj;;.aaumw‘Avw _.III I II .11-:\'1:'- may}; Y’pIIII. I '.Io:;(I'I'', “_..4‘.I"; I 'QII .l‘ I0 A.17(1' 3:,37:,0t'l;‘A‘III-I‘qitgh I;I:.III 1:0; . I",I.'1"" {‘I IJ'F 1‘; I“ . ‘My“? ’I'I'I' .4511, ." . I,'V‘ I-:.~I-II'I"I.‘-' - ‘I‘.IT m»;r’ a]: U Wu}, - l. ‘ “I'tI.I:‘ ,‘1.~, :fl .4..‘ u‘. ..1 0| ": \ H t, .V“I‘ III L?‘ fiI‘I‘II’It IIQI’IIIIIE‘I‘-‘I' I v 2‘ ‘ [4"‘IUU‘fl-1‘Ifi- .‘~:.O|v-";.- ‘ |,,n;',‘,.. .‘;.”._v.. I; ,‘I In. -, '0 IIIIr‘IIIIII ‘3'’va-'.";I'1‘I--m Elf.I'I IIIqIAIII:‘I“37}? .I'I;II': 'I| :ifi-‘g ”I . liIII'IQILI‘IIIUI I' 'I III-SI} , 3553;911‘1 ‘ 73.43» I'I III'III'II III (€11:$311.)" ":5." MI‘I‘IVIIII 3‘,A. ; , % 3 ? * 5 ‘ q ‘ : 7 ' : 5 ‘ " a u.“ I! '2'!- I) U -1 0" "Q“ ., 4" I Luff .v,c,'77'0I1;.'" I; ”‘42:. II"! “ 2 I I'H‘rot n,‘ :04: ,, film-s: , .m‘ ‘1' ' ‘-- - I I I I I I I I I l I I I I I I I I I I I I . . _ I 5 2 ' I 0 _ . _ : . . I I I ' °.'.II A I! . .r . . ‘u' ' " . ‘ ,'_, I. "I 4 z. ( <1 ' § » 1 m' m _I' J, . A I I1 «51 m ‘’ M ‘ i i i v { ' 5 2 I F . I V I A . U - A . - ; . % 3 4 ' ' . A ' - i . : ; 4 5 : 5 ! : 4 1 : 5 1 ( ‘ . ’ l a " u P J : O . . . . _ ” A o ‘ J ' V -‘-. . "i 3., n-l.‘ 3" III . s. ail If ‘ I‘D/I A , 0.1:. 9’17" I! , A‘ _ . . . 9. ,'._‘- ' .1 ‘11 .2; ' II 7 .. II. I I" '. I; s $4 . - If . . A ._ .p, 5 A. . II' L a LI T ‘ II o . ' I . “.F- 2.11.. w 7.M‘» n- . atxdlgt '1' .x u. I ’ I"II“II-II": ‘7'. {flI"!:V}._'.'~‘,:‘;=I”I‘I‘ 5 I Unfit-{I d’t- . I Q .I; 57,-. . _.., , .I 4, . [’1 n- ‘4 _, . 0' I“.- I-.. Y . ,. ’2 . ; ,; _.. I\‘‘III “.I‘I“ -1” ' ..'.l_ \v I. I" ,s' «Iv- 0',“ . v u. " ' I ? ‘ ’ . , f." I... t. 2.“ ,. PA. “4-0“: 1.9.}. ..,~ 1).“;. . A A ~ 0,- I . .. ‘ “‘ ' I” "“ '.- A I ‘ A. 9,.’T’UW"?" :7' ' - I.‘ ‘2‘.""I‘ E1 . II~‘ ~ I v. I I II '0.I',!;‘:‘4,A’5a1‘.:": . ,‘.'‘4 $53“:éuw't’1‘ I. 'I-I. 0.21 I‘ ' .:9I~I;I if. |041:5,A ftp:I." *zIf‘I- I _» . | ‘ t" ‘ ‘F.’ ‘ ' _ "INI‘:If? :3, .er . v“ I I‘" .L' .-. ‘I 0. .— A _A .. -' ~ ~ . ‘1‘.» ‘ . 7 ‘IQ .f’y!" - r ' 'I I _,: Al '0, .' III‘ HH_ SCI" I. MI III‘ I 3.. .I 1 ‘1 .‘I. ‘ -.IosA"AA'A' III'A‘IIII'I' 54",353. I‘iI 1:913 I-I“ I0‘“s5:31“"4.I‘;,‘A:I‘fiI’III-I LiofIII: 'JAJ‘I‘ IALZA‘fi‘Iqw I?“ I". ‘0'!O". ‘5' 8“”.I LT.“’2’".'4’ ““2"” .._‘I4'\-,0,k;!,.,-_I‘A‘UA,°"-$ ‘ '| III - \"Q,~f.: Iii. -.- SI}; .,-—.- I,’ AA ‘3 ‘0' t- , -- Q 3 - «9“;- ~ .I.;:...‘ 31"“;Ifil . 0-; ~. A f '_ - pkg; f!‘ I‘d I . . .P-. .1 _ , . . “.5. \.\h. .1, L, ' "“1210“; I... 3' z, I“; .3 '13.: I|'§.I!I,e“‘l I“. -... .1; "J .I i . t V I“, 1-.9 .. 33-35“ (VP-'1- :j...,..un,I.;‘-’ - "_.rw! A .340- ,. - ~ I: AII'; .: ‘.' .- I;::“I ‘ ;I_l. .Cd‘.. - . .'.'.' 7 .4 .. ,. gt, :7. "'3" "I",i." I‘.I'IIfifi‘Ilf'V‘."I°‘A.‘.+’AI? . .'.' my,“ A 33.4. .‘uv ,., , SI JAR"; I II.“‘A’ Q ”I I," A A6,“. {A 1.? ' .' ,‘ .f ' 'I'o . I 3 f. "; 9it! .‘9'.*",,1'-16°9N.' I .‘_ '1‘.- )0 .I "7’ A.",'It~1A'A..AI"‘ . .' 1- H ' I ‘I‘ E'fl: 4 "It - .,§ 0 J.“ .o."-" If _.‘n'.n' I" ‘- 1 'i‘. . ..!I.A’: . “my: ‘na L‘s-w“. .3 ""f‘I’U ,.-, ‘1, :0 o‘ ; ,0? 3“,}. ".;. ‘7?L“, ,5.III'AT'.505",w. ,,‘: IIII-‘IIIAKII ' f“. 2.1“} .‘A’. IIIIW‘ A f-‘s’l'fl 7' Inf-Vitnt '(-o‘ J “I: 7‘ 'Ib.'Hh-'.' .‘IO.’ ".' ‘ . JI'.'..<_‘r. T.“I',I‘ ‘ ' In Q ., ‘ I - I I ‘ . ' 0 _‘HA . A _ ' - ~1. Q 7 r .-.'-I': , , . ' .»r-. 9 . - _h ‘5 - ..., . . ,5 ’. _, Nu . . ‘ ' -0 [‘R; .'.OI"* ’VI‘.¢,\;¢.’‘ Vtan ;:3:; t‘..4‘l -AIr 1". .: A ' s . H a ~14 . , , , ,L . "“f!"'.' . 1 _w-ooons' :‘o J 7 ' In"-1.. l‘ Icq‘ .I, . ‘ j ‘w '3. .. . 4‘. "f . _ an: 5..) . 1". Eur“; 7 l "’ ' I A :L' ' - . 6“" ‘9 x' - A ~ ,‘5- ‘16 4 ‘ I-’H}VOI.’ I'I rfizm’.§.§ ..I’ I . ’2‘"?—Q"... ‘.~I‘;c-A . 7,1,1}: 03:” fix! flev.;:'4f—.’-. '-’;'II€I‘III I; f #4,},10 It}; '9‘!" 12;? :It‘ta.;lA I03 ‘ I'1'-.'1‘ . O 7 A I .t ' ”N 19‘ II." .I‘u‘ 4 ~1§"~~-'- {'t‘ IAI' - ' O l- .#I. I'f' “ S. '1, IOII- I a .n .. a1 I" ‘A ‘ ‘o I A . O ‘ l ' ‘ . I . .' 2;! .‘é 383,253("I‘I'EJ "I“ I 2., ‘3: ' 1‘ I'- . .~.:A'A.I‘A.::lb ' 2&0 9?‘4;.3:A:‘t"1‘1.’-" 9. 1.2;“. I: *‘ 6:25... 9". ‘5 f..[91 i.4':‘A1.o_:‘,’A.A-I .’ ‘ 7;?" 999‘“: :I‘.'I.1..A«J,'02" .1}: “.I. 'I‘}.'x ' ‘..“ ?"'Io' ”- . .;.a€:l(’.‘1".¢'o‘u".'u ~| ,',7.u1.o4 ’3‘,I'I‘V)8- j,‘ . . .”.I":- 5'17 "fia'figgzéfie'sjlfi‘.cans. IA-‘A‘ ”A II -1343 I 'I-‘I'I‘..?'9I-“.°- ”‘57: '-I- :57 .-' - M '5. 'I’Aa‘é‘fi." :} c‘. ,3” ';?-;".'I'Q.'.AIAIR; IO; fi’IfrI‘I If} "."IA'IJaw.”935,6 '.y_}'A'i-fi. (U 2,}: :31???" ',‘:-': :‘ i ‘i‘I‘I‘Z‘I’Ifl“39:62?” "7 ". .3. "79‘1" ..-.._ f~‘ ‘- "2+4 0" '1-_ :7. I.- (I. {“8"3 1‘: _A .‘Io-fc’." ,e’tn ICC“. ~., ‘ .| ' 3-, J" ..‘4i“-.,O£{I’ -‘ 7. ', I . ’ . '7‘“: - s .' :L' 3"“; .0" ‘fi‘z afi-flm‘éi‘f‘ $II£I Iifla'u' ’JfiLIN“ 0 ~- 6‘51?“ I"): ’1‘" 'I“1I"‘".f°- ‘2‘.- I;—' ' ' "I: I ‘3'! O'.l°f‘v 04'?) 0’1; , 390'". ,§-; ~02;A:.‘,-,:"I‘~"‘,.'I '.‘ I < 3:- (In;.‘SII‘JA 03" '{v'qsp'p' 4‘ "H 3"; . A V.- “IE7“:-I};I:I,".‘v: ‘1 I ”6.9.9, . MIAQ‘O. :- "P.,:.OI‘-,.5'4:“I ‘- 1 I.“ 3.535.}; A—fIQ‘AJ.‘I'..'b:..A., A"|r.’ IIil'AIs‘ri'IsI‘A-V-A . ’th! . . ' .-. 0;}- .A‘ .."..‘Q . I ;v_Il _I-.'_ . .» 1' 1 " 7 «V12 I‘OSI'IAIIf-“I . I. 0'03 ‘I’; JOAI'U ,3 .91..1I‘&".I.§' ‘Iu;--‘A'.‘ ,;‘.‘I .3;‘P‘A3‘.,“ " 3).}: I g - . Q . .."0 ,‘,' 7,“. ':‘-II ' p‘, " '3‘; - - ’. - . - 7‘3‘4: ‘u- I?II. H ‘0 ‘I Inf, I (Eat; goz‘25;,'¢;;l'v§‘.; '3' 0504'“.- "'4'«' 5,2 ‘3' T 3' «3:: «Ix ’IIcI-Sfotv4‘t"- 9:.‘A9?:6 '3! 9 ’5‘ ‘1 0"." =- .0 .1 I'A’A " ‘7‘} I". 070' ' {a 2?. ‘— . smug“- I 99). .A I.” C'I '1": ' 'II 1'0". I ~‘. .AIlI“ , I .42: .. I Hr. " I‘ .' a " - i ‘ ' ‘ - *1?“ ' 1" . :‘fA :t.I:" :‘1‘ .;II I‘:""' mm: {33$}, ,2»; ‘ V? (‘ I‘~7.I‘Ifi:§‘..‘ {— , :23; ;I I’.‘ I .. ‘I ."' . * ‘ . "“».I..t" '.'.. ,1 I}; Ir‘I‘v “I'II‘.':'I.‘.'-I,’~'i.h‘e‘.. I}. ‘1'," ' .‘,~.I_ 7 . . 4". . _~‘ I - 93‘.”-“ 7‘..-.'.5.... ‘34! ‘~I,I_,.°,',.. $§,! J I‘I., ,I-OI'I , . 1"};3‘2fi3 inn-t.” ”IN -\.,- "I *.‘V- " 3‘31 . "'\ “'I‘."’ . ' u' 41‘. 40.3.. - .n.‘r.f- .- Pu'u‘é‘fifiéfi" 9. I’; .‘I'VIIPI 1;“ III.“ II . ~171‘O‘" . " "‘14...“ .\-‘1. . . : -.. Q ' ‘ _ .2, " __, “V. 3-. I5“,.‘.tI; ,r 1"‘'3‘." I);‘‘Qi‘.::'‘;:;:I A 0.\;‘. '.’IIIA'.9I. I4 .4I3 I; A'.‘ ' '7 I . _.~ .A ‘_ “>1..X:r“,. 9.4"'$.‘1Jl .1. ”A swan...” ,. l .0“ -- a PI.;’-I‘_’I‘{I‘:'.: .>.. .4, ,.., .A, ‘5', 3 _ I? '! IAJ 10;; v- . _ _.,_'_ l-I .:.~~: , .. d"); A: ‘,- II‘I‘ , k; I. “‘4', ¢r¢.;u;:.~ 5'“ " ii} I.» 'QI'L‘ 'QI7 it? , ‘1': ._ {A I: ' “2' I} ‘0‘ 'I- I, 'f".'. r. ,r 0’ I Y . ‘ ‘ggcts‘g‘rfo,{p,fi . 3 -.’- I . ' I, ‘. 31,34? {‘1'}? :‘s '2'.” ‘T U . § .‘.!' Qt.’:';§'$"‘t' >4? ’01. “1-": fl '22 - w . . $f‘l‘fi I“. ~ .‘ 4 'n J3.“ 9.‘.‘"‘.f.'l l ' f n " . -. .Ia.,.;_.:.-; 3%?in ~ a: -.«. - r- —"-vI‘. X'.~‘...‘:'..‘ .1 , If; ::$.gfq,4‘p'.4'§.‘i.'- ... ' I. 1 7 v rfha V, _'v'.)t[filqA . ’ ' .,s ' .:I0.; 03,- 11.. J! 1331‘”! 3.34.”, 3‘ ”III""":“'—‘. ‘3. 0 nor.- . - , 1..., b‘.-. - .> ~ ”v : ' I' , no a.” .- + ‘3; '- I- I” 7—." - I‘m H! . q‘, f . w 3 in .- a ‘. ' III ,. .‘ - .u .‘i' ,,.. VI :3. ' ,4 “IR, A ."I' , 4 ,: “£334.43 I‘.’ .e ’5‘ ”‘3', _. ”VIII-,3} ,1 r.‘¢'-L'I9\°o‘I’IL : u,‘~£::‘.‘4‘¢‘II ‘14,}, ‘II'IIIII-II'II‘II'EII'IIIIII'I {‘3‘ I! 1. .’ EIII'I'I‘III fl... 3' I? ‘r‘ ,‘,_:.§"I,.,‘I:‘III;1IJ€‘:'{, '7 (w , 1“ AI." I‘~II'1'-\I‘:;,‘w;‘f‘f7‘?w .‘_I1.-“Q‘ ‘5’}, 1:“ III}. 1,. ‘&.'I"¢’).~;Q‘a< 13‘Q: . ‘-_1:»:‘7‘:9".33:41., . . :{IJgI‘f‘fd Au .0. , 7“.“"‘(.;'IJ~ ‘I"“‘I". 'J‘IIH‘.” 1". 2' .5- 'I Q, . , , .4. . - H“I~'avI- '. " ~.' _ If“; . - ,I.‘-"."‘ J, ‘”‘4'" LII--.:.- -'-. 4- '3‘, .4 ‘. 'a ,. I“ II .' ‘ II‘ -'. _. '- ~. " .‘ ‘I ‘ ‘ . ' ~ ~ ' ' . . - . . I ' ‘ ‘4‘i" If;- 7"1'»! 2'0”}. It} ,7. "I! . 1:?" .‘ g'r . v "I ' o gk'.‘-V¥l;2.3.17‘ " .",‘:I‘$:‘gv_“'.-K'I AI: _.3 31:3" '3’“;'J'JvI”! IIIQIIEEt,~‘I,. ‘ _~ '. f- ' I. I! . I' ‘ ; '9 .‘é , "’3 '5 ‘ 1 .-‘ a...“ ’ 'vm' *7 7w \fiv " I , . y ' 400" 1.. ‘ 7» 7-‘-v3 INSI’DI“O 1-.1‘3 ‘. ‘7 - an e ' I 1 ‘ , - 44‘<-~I« o .x ‘ ‘II ‘ 1"\U lt't‘o“ - ' ' OI» I A I .' "7'5 M 7“ s *3" ‘ ’7}s, “' ' 5‘4 I .I’I,)'if O‘_!I AAII ‘ y" y ‘. 7‘ A- ' ' . ,; 'I' .. . , < ‘ ‘u‘ _ 0 I u, lIIO"'~l .. v , A A ‘-‘IJ‘ 9 X'Ix!‘ ,"A.I'..‘ :.\V . I "I. II;\y 3’5?!" I'I‘:\I' A‘H‘s- - O‘IV." ', 7‘31II7-«I. A" 3 0 .4 .. -, ~;“‘ . .. ‘1‘ .. ‘59.“? <.\ l‘.’ .J‘E' _o ,‘Hfl‘ (:03; ; ~15 H‘- tu- Alr‘. s. ' ‘ “uh-'1 4 'I‘ -‘- .‘u'v- 49-ku- . .-. "i".\ 14 7‘. ”LI I‘Mo- ”tuN'I'ov’uon" . .IIIA.) "A b 0 9, ““1. I 'II" 7' ~I7v'fr" I .. _.3. . 'o ,, , _ . . --,.'|~ .ag 'Iv 0’! l A 2‘..." II'~-I.'~’~ 73.»; I 1M as: ’ .t.I.-:c:I:-.w:-;I. - 7:27»' ' V7}. w~‘- ‘ ‘7. II',‘.““'.‘ ' I“-I .IAI‘J ‘\ - 9.- II .II ‘0 .1 'II‘ .=.v -b~ " _ 5’ I; "ol ‘. | ' f1 . b" I V ~a, I,&,I'~.._J‘ ["O'I‘A'l 7 . .- . A 3 , I‘ "I LI'II'.‘I v, . ‘._ ‘.. {,3171.3 42‘ 453$deI". " ' , ' - 3'. w 7‘ "if e "i; "'.°"’£"I “ 1 'n- $4331.67“. .- A “A" R 'q 9.3.“ “—7"' 'J'I‘I‘w" 13.117: w1-371~f';=..,3,212,,1-1”v; ;a.»wst;"$33 4‘sisIx» m 5‘s 2% ‘1."' W " 9‘ 1;.7‘3fnxq.‘ I" "II: E"; t:"c--' .,,1.3‘1;z; 3%WI?”AL?". H73.1. - I323:31.13:"- ; ' II,',I:","14,' ‘ _""“5;‘9‘? I;'II ‘vo (1 'v- \ .1I‘."7"1,I!J.- t ' ‘I' I‘|-.IIA “A! ‘.. o ‘~ - ‘I‘A fi "' ’0 t In :1 6’9:1*.“ I-I‘Ili’l‘m‘I. I‘ y--' ’f ‘i- I- III. I "II ‘ “'(:.':I' ‘1‘ .1" 3““:gh‘bv-A‘ ... m 9 of“, .1;I;. 3m; --. " ' r I ‘II ‘I ('I:= , ,‘1’ f: 0‘ .' “I. '1’ .. ‘3"I'D‘ .n .i’ . ‘ :1 .' '10 A ‘- .. “I -I' ‘ . J ‘ . - - I ' . 1 . ‘ I - . ' . I :— gum?. I"I :‘I‘I‘I "I" S“'z’é'I‘I'tI'II' (n-I‘v‘ a V:~:3:{v5?: 1..I,{I}: s." ‘ ' 7 . A. ‘4 A. -‘r.I‘..' "'1 1‘. Q A ‘ o h -»72I.Ir~:I.- . ., . ->1I‘.»I.I:-:‘:~~v'c%i~"ivf'Iri I; w wait: 24;: sax-”{2}: : .‘Its'vd-II .;-; -".~I - . I‘m: H411, '35; 5'." an,” A, , AIL-"9., fl," \tvg""‘4 1.: .?~ {fitu \ ‘3'.“ 7" I3 IF"..',‘ U} ‘I' ~40 _. :‘I 1%:d:,.‘n“ ._ ,'.. -' |., _ ‘.' ‘ .' : , ; . . ' .' ’J'.’ I ;“."I:":'I' )2, ‘ ‘r.l‘v‘: rA ' :,<-} I lfl‘n‘qpi 5;} . .. 4. ~Ion .“ _ I’ A h‘t ..‘I'-".'J . . -‘ .L: -, a". 2... . . I}, '; 4'A‘\.A,:,., . “a F‘s, , 0‘”?! I' 11"..:¢4I:9_l'.3..-y‘er ‘wk- 0.!“ i. I, ‘>Ii.,’,.l -‘ ,u,‘ s v 7 .' AI". ‘ 61- I1 I ~‘,' ‘ ‘ a" .“. I“ III. ‘ AI s. I/AII 1: {If . ' III-iv 7.». w"; 75c 1. , . I' V IJIINI '. "I‘I'I- I s' we; ‘'77 :z . 9v .vI r an. .- .9.~‘.'.;.'.'3.-.11\.-.1.r. .c37;, In ‘ A . ' . s I‘V‘III 'I'Iu.n'l '¥I' m:-:I.I~I'~ .s: ~:.~=I.:..~ ~.~*I~.;’r‘.‘£2¢'I‘ La _ - 7%: 'z-s‘s‘a I x . . :~ I If. :0!.. "I- A‘“‘1. s o 3::9. ' ‘I‘IXIiII.OI;z"-:I o‘: ‘ " ’ I‘, “-51. Cc..- . ‘. “A . a'n .°.;r‘-';':w,~* )sa'é .1. 52.333. . : .7._.., ”‘s‘\ m‘.‘.‘,') ‘ ‘H , "‘?'S,‘(:H\‘ ‘, v A A o . . . 3".uwo - 0. v,~‘. .‘0 w. . .fl s...- ' 7 "« au‘th” I 3.0;. _'.\‘I,‘n-1§_, ‘. ., '."" !-'-‘" .AIIlw-n ”IIIAII “I A 4. :W.‘ . I‘ I a .‘4 “a" " A. II I>I‘II-'I ‘5‘"I" '*I‘I' Q" ”III II. ‘II4wa. I_'::I I3" II *IIfI:I .‘I' ' *I“ II M-‘IJH'G ‘r:-‘I‘\"“' . .‘ l1: .°-'\-g ‘¢$' . 4 )1,73‘ " '. ‘g' “9:-IN.. ..,“33.x“ “J‘fi I:I.I24! IA" -‘ . l I II\‘." ‘.-"I SJ l». . III N? I }‘ ‘7.’‘. ' 5 Lo‘o" x \N '. ~"HI If“ "‘ ‘-'.'1".‘«!4t-I‘II:;5'4'1'I;. ‘ . .-.- - 3" -195“ 4' .J II 'II-“ I-.. 1 ' P. v!‘ ‘ 315* 1.. x'b-A.. I I’I‘B‘QIIIIL. 6:?‘4 S’I‘IZI; s" 13"?1Q'qagprv0: I °'91I""I‘_"‘ {‘1‘n~.s"¢- } Aria: .o. - \ {No'A' _u .r 5w.‘--' ' 7 $273713.'45:""' . '«as?»vat-w.-- ‘ .s :! :yy ‘r3 L ,‘“fizzlsily “,3 wig?.MAJ}. " 3i a“: ' ' fl A‘,".'7:~ 55).. ~ ‘5' . ‘ . . 1' 1 ‘A‘,-<’;\x I "!'—‘.‘ , 1 -'I,,‘;’$“":I.I-I‘. 'CS‘K’fl 2"" ‘sf. ”3"" ' k - ff! «fa-“- 4-"; 4‘s» «7:: was '.~, .‘I ‘ ,I.— 1 I . : _ ‘ _ ‘I'O‘I“ ' “" ‘ A". ' .I“,‘3" . As,‘I¢\ 'l‘o . ‘tfi- ' M "1‘ .r~..\': .7 k‘g- "J t . O“ ' .I ._. ' . II I!" ‘ ' I. A ‘ I 1’39. Q‘ 4 "I4'I‘{' I . . c :0 :1 I. ‘- . .‘~‘ - - a("I'MI'UI. I‘I:4.-I‘"-I ' '1'“:Ié'uflfi1,4,, 117:}: Mo‘I’IIiIACF'IIIVIIfIsAx1aE.€. 51.21.; nun. - IIIH’AHI .' ‘\ I‘ '(‘J O. . " ‘ . " a r m I 1 :I'I‘I“ l'glf’ . ”I. .514' '23" .._ a . n ' . _' ‘ I I . ‘ - v ..r I ...-. . - g?7757‘ ,.,...,.....,..s,.,. 2a . I1: '17;'f'kWI“ i , . . -- x . - - . _ Ma.) ~ I I :I_.III.\A‘1(:1.‘-.I~Im‘§l‘a‘f I I‘IAIII:‘II21‘I‘V- “I m .1. Le II- .JOI'I ‘_- r THESIS IVERS Illliill’ilill‘ull Illlui'nlllll 3 1293 01409 6071 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Market Trader Activism in the Context of Global Restructuring Processes: A Ghanaian Case Study presented by Emmanuel Baffuor Awuah has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D . degree in Sociology WXW ' \, Major professor Date ’,%a/VL [Ill/17f MS U i: an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 LlBRARY Michigan State University PLACE ll RETURN BOXto romavothb Mutton your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date duo. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MARKET TRADER ACTIVISM IN THE CONTEXT OF GLOBAL RESTRUCTURING PROCESSES: A GHANAIAN CASE STUDY By Emmanuel Baffuor Awuah A DISSERTATION Submitted to - Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Sociology and Urban Affairs Programs 1995 ABSTRACT MARKET TRADER ACTIVISII IN THE com OF GLOBAL RESTRUCTURING PROCESSES : A GHANAIAN CASE STUDY By Emanuel Baffuor Awuah This study investigated how market traders, as human- social agents, mobilized to articulate their collective interests regarding the policies of state/local government institutions in the Kumasi Metropolis. It was placed within the context of global restructuring and its implications for Ghana. The research questions that guided this investigation were (a) how did global economic restructuring affect central/local state restructuring in Ghana?; (b) what institutional and structural factors engendered conflicts between market traders and the local state?; (c) how did market traders mobilize .to articulate their collective interests? (d) what is the relevance of market trader activism for the democratic processes in Ghana? Data for the study were gathered through fieldwork which was conducted between January and June, 1992. The author utilized. several methods including interviews, survey, archival and documentary sources, and personal observations. sud The framework of the study relates to the argument that central/local state restructuring should.be understooduwithin a broader context of global economic restructuring, which redefines capital-labor relationships, and the role of the state in national development. It was argued that since Ghana implemented a Structural Adjustment Program (SAP) in 1983, state restructuring has led to further dependence of local state institutions on their communities. Consequently, local state institutions have adopted fiscal measures including increased tax revenues, and retrenchment of community services. The study demonstrated that market trader activism in the Kumasi Metropolis following after the implementation of the Structural Adjustment Program, was aimed at influencing the fiscal policies of the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority, while at the same time demanding the provision of new services, and maintenance of existing physical and social infrastructure, to enhance their business activities in the marketplace. The study concluded that the demands market traders made were part of the larger I'demecratization" process that is going on from the ''bottom up" in Ghana. Capyright by EMMANUEL BAFFUOR AWUAH 1995 «a DEDICATION TO MAAME AMA OSAAH, WHO CARED FOR ME, TO MY MOTHER, ELIZABETH BAIDEN: WHO DID NOT LIVE TO SEE THE MIRACLE, AND TO MY DEAR WIFE, AGATHA, AND THE CHILDREN, WHO MADE IT POSSIBLE. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Pursuing graduate studies has been a life-long investment for me. Along the way, I have become indebted to many people, all of whom I cannot mention in this short space. First, I would like to express my heart-felt gratitude to my Lord and Savior Jesus Christ, who provided me the opportunity to pursue graduate studies in the united States. He is the source of my strength, wisdom and protection. The members of my Guidance Committee, Professors Ruth Simmm Hamilton, Christopher Vanderpool, Richard Hill, and John Herrick, were quite helpful throughout my stay at Michigan State university. They challenged me to think critically about social realities. The chairperson of the Guidance Committee, Professor Ruth Hamilton, want an extra mile to guide my research. She helped me to see Ghana in new and refreshing ways. She gave me more than my fair share of her rich academic and research experiencesl. An initial research assistantship from the Urban Affairs Programs (UAP) made it possible for me to accept my admdssion for doctoral studies. The research opportunities HAP provided me, first under Dr. Bill Cross, and later with Professor Ruth Simms Hamilton, the Director of the African Diaspora Research Project, helped.me to acquire more research skills, and enabled.me to apply them to emergent problems in the American society. I am.also grateful to the Department of Sociology for the teaching assistantships, which not only provided financial support for my studies, but also created opportunities for me to work with faculty in the classroom, and taught my own classes. I thank the department for the trust it reposed in me; but I should admit that those rare and challenging opportunities have renewed my interest in teaching. The fieldwork in Ghana would not have been possible without timely research funds from the Mid4West universities Consortium for International Activities (MUCIA). I thank the Center for International Programs for its assistance in securing the MUCIA research funds. Numerous research assistants in Ghana, particularly Mac Obiri-Mainoo, served as "foot soldiers" in the process of collecting data, and I am grateful for their service. Also, the cooperation of market traders, and officers of the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority made my research possible. The family of Professors Jack and Margaret Jones (College of Human Medicine) provided invaluable spiritual, emotional, and financial support for me and my family. Their labor of love enabled my famdly'to endure the pain and hardships of living in a foreign land. Finally, but not the least, my most gratitude goes to my wife Agatha, and my children, Eunice and Yaw. They were always there for me, sharing in my joys and frustrations. I really appreciate their love, patience, and forgiveness. TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter 1. INTRODUCTION ....................................... 1 Statement of the Problem ........................... 9 Significance of the Study............. ...... . ..... 13 Organization of the Study.........................16 m 2. THE SETTING FOR THE STUDY IntrwuctionOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO. OOOOOOOOOOOOOO 00.17 “:0 ..... 0.0... ....... 0.0.0.0....00.00.000.000017 KmsiOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0.0.0....0.0.0.000000000037 Markets and.Marketplaces..........................51 Gender Division of Labor in the Market ........ ....58 The Kumasi Central Market.........................62 Demographic Characteristics of Market Traders.....67 Market Associations.................. .......... ...78 Administration of the Central Market..............86 Su-ary of the Chapter. .. ........... . ............. 92 M 4. PUTTING TEE GHANAIAN -ERIENCE IN A BROADER CONCEPTUAL AND THEORETICAL CONTEXT Introduction......................................93 The Informal Bconomy..............................93 Previous Research on Market Traders Versus the State............................................110 Human Social Agency and Collective Action........115 Market Trader Associational Aotivity.............118 Framework for understanding Market Trader Aotivism.in Ghana‘Mithin the Context of Global Restructuring....................................125 working Propositions ...................... . ...... 134 Chapter 5 . RESUME OF RESEARCH PROCEDURES IntrmctimOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0.0136 Members and Leaders of Market Associations.......137 State/Local Government Officials.................142 Limitations of the Study......... ................ 145 Conclusion........................... ......... ...147 Qantas 6. GLOBAL RESTRUCTURING AND THE STATE AGAINST NATION DILEMMA IN GHANA Introduction.....................................l49 Context of State Restructuring...................149 Fiscal Crisis of the State.......................161 State Policy Responses...........................163 Central-Local Government Relationship............177 Local Government in the Kumasi Metropolis........181 Local Government Restructuring in the Kunasi Metropolis...............................186 Financing of Local Government in the Humasi Metropolis...............................190 Bone of Contention: Central Market Traders versus the Kumasi Metropolitan.Authority........197 Analysis of Major Issues in Traders' Petitions...209 Gleaner 7 . mam TRADER normsx m nmcmnza-rron PROCESSES IN'GHANA Introduction.....................................229 Rehabilitation of the Kumasi Central Market......231 Security in the Kumasi Central Market............238 rment of Indigenous Business Associations..241 Civil Society and Democratic Processes in Ghana..244 Chapter 8. SUMMARI'AMD CGMCLUSIGMS IntrmctimOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO00.00254 8m Of angBOOOOOCIOOOOOOOOOOIOOOOOOOOO0.0255 conc1uaion8000000.000000000000000000.00.000.000.0258 APPENDIX .A: RESEARCH QUESTIONNAIRE..................260 APPENDIX B: PETITIONS OE MARKET TRADERS.............325 WSOOOOOOOOOOOO0.......0.COO-OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO00.335 BIBLIMOCOO0....0000OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0......342 LIST or TABLES The Political and Economic Profile of Ghana, 1957-1993................. ..... ..22 Structure of Ghana Exports.. ............ ... ...... .26 Structure of Ghana Imports ........................ 27 2.4 Balance of Payments of Ghana ...................... 29 2.5 Average Exchange Rates, 1980-1992 ................. 31 2.6 Age and Gender Structure in Ghana ............... ..32 2.7 Enrollments in Ghanaian Schools..... ....... .......34 2.8 Literacy Rates in Ghana...... ............... . ..... 35 2.9 Population Profile of Kumasi.......... ........... .42 2.10 Age and Gender Characteristics in Kumasi. ...... ...43 2.11 Educational Attainments in Kumasi.................45 2.12 Occupations OF Employed Persons in Kumasi.. ..... ..47 3.1 Educational Attainments of Market Traders ........ .68 3.2 Sources of Capital of Market Traders .............. 70 3.3 Marital Status of Central Market Traders .......... 73 3.4 Family Size of Central Market Traders . .......... 74 6.1 Total External Debt of Ghana......... ........... .162 6.2 Total External Debt Ratios of Ghana .............. 164 Central Government Revenue and Grants, Ghana ..... 166 Central Government Expenditure and Net Lending, Ghana.. ....... 167 Profile of Local Government Development in Kummei ............................... . ...... 183 Major Sources of Kumasi Metropolitan Authority's Revenues... ......... ....... ..... ... ......... 191 Kumasi Metropolitan Authority Rents for Central market Stalls/Stores, 1984-1991. e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e a 0193 Sources of Conflict Between Market Traders and the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority ............ . ...... 199 LIST OF FIGURES Map of Ghana ..................................... 18 Map of Kumasi .................................... 40 Distribution of Markets in Ghana....... ........ ..52 Relationship Between Rural and Urban Markets ..... 54 Interchanges Between Sectors of the Ghanaian Economy and the Global Economy....... ........... .56 Organizational Structure of the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority... ................. . ................... 87 Characteristics of the Formal and Informal sectorsOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO......OOOOOOOOOOO ........ 96 A Framework for Understanding Market Trader Activism in Ghana Within the Context of Global Restructuring Processes.................. ..... ..135 People's Defence Committees and worker's Defence conittees' 1983........OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO. ..... 151 PNDC Ghana(1984): Political Structure...........152 Organizational Structure of the Kumasi Metropolitan Aaamly.OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO0.00.00.00.0000000188 CHAPTER ONE INTRODUCTION 1.1 BACKGROUND My study focused on market trader mobilization and articulation of their collective interests within the context of global/state restructuring processes and their impact on Ghanaians. Ghana has a long history of mobilization among informal economy workers, particularly market traders, in defence of their individual and collective interests vis-a-vis the state. According to Clark (1990), marketplace trade in present-day Ghana has historically had.a highly charged relationship with a range of states: from small chiefships to centralized confederacies, to colonial empires, and nationalist would-be states, to contemporary electoral and military states. Controversies over the acceptable and actual role of traders were prominent among justifications for changes of government. All these types of authority structures generally more than once, intervened energetically in trading relations, at the same time that traders' own actions, individual and collective, shaped important aspects of the economies and political formations of these state systems. Market traders, particularly market women, were quite active in the anti-colonial struggle for Ghana's political independence from the British colonialists. They formed alliances with proto-nationalist movements in putting pressures on the colonial state, until eventually Ghana gained its independence in 1957. Since then, Ghanaian market traders have been among the first social groups to mobilize collectively to protest/challenge/resist seemingly unpopular policies of state/local government authorities, through overt and covert activities. Every state system in Ghana has had to deal with workers in the informal economy, particularly market traders. Market traders relate to state institutions in Ghana at two levels: the central government and local government authority levels. The central government initiates commercial policies which affect the operations of businessmen and women in the country, regarding the allocation of import licenses, and which goods are subject to state price controls. The issue of state price controls of imported goods into Ghana was the bone of contention between market traders and central government officials until it was repealed in 1983. Price control of goods was a regulatory instrument which involved government stipulation of prices for imported commodities into Ghana. According to Clark (1990), price controls were pioneered by colonial governments as a means to guarantee low-cost food supplies for barracks and prisons. In addition, the colonial state had to control food.prices for workers in foreign-owned mines, to cheapen the cost of production, and thereby maximize Their profits from the labor power of the workers. However, traders and farmers effectively refused to sell at the controlled prices. In the First Republic under Kwame Nkrumah (1957-1966)1 the "price control“ system was used as an instrument to regulate business enterprises. The 196; Control of Prices Act was designed with the goal of ‘bringing down the prices of commodities needed by the masses within the reach of everybody, so that it would ensure that the people are not deprived of decent and inexpensive living by any privileged class'. The price list promulgated under the 1962 Control of Prices Act was largely confined to imported consumer goods and locally' manufactured consumer goods ‘with a high. import content. The price control mechanism was used as an instrument of social policy, intended totprotect consumers by preventing importers and local manufacturers from.earning:monopoly rents arising from import restrictions. But as Rillick (1973) points out, the real test of the price control policy was its effectiveness as an egalitarian device. Generally, the price control list was not confined to items mostly purchased by lowbincome consumers. Relatively lowbincome people could hardly afford to purchase imported commodities, and locally manufactured import-substitutes. In fact, as Killick (1973) argues, it was the middle and upper classes in the Ghanaian society (especially the expatriate community and political elites, and their families), who took advantage of the price controls, as they spent a greater -proportion of their incomes/wealth on these goods. Thus, the disparities in real consumption standards increased rather than diminished. Interestingly, the extent of price control evasion was considerably higher in local informal markets than in state and private supermarkets. Generally, while government trading enterprises such as the Ghana National Trading Corporation (GNTC), and multinational commercial enterprises such as the United Trading Company (UTC), and G.B. Ollivant, were too conspicuous to break the price controls with impunity,:market traders were not inhibited in the same way. In fact, market women who served as petty traders within the commodity distribution system were too numerous to regulate as thoroughly as the others. The Abraham.Commission (1968) which was appointed after the fall of the N‘krumah government in 1966 to investigate trade malpractice in the Ghanaian economy, reported that the operations of market women contributed to shortages and escalating prices of locally-manufactured and imported commodities. The Commission's report provided the mass media a weapon against women which they used with relish, calling for steps to rid the markets of recalcitrant and I'unpatriotic" middlewomen. Thus, women traders were castigated for hoarding, profiteering, and smuggling. These attitudes persisted, particularly as prices skyrocketed in urban markets. The dominant view remained that commodity price increases in the internal economy were due mostly to market trader machinations and detenmination to undermine state commercial policies. The 1972-1979 period also witnessed the imposition of price controls, and state repression/regulation, as well as violence against market traders. The mdlitary state under Acheampong introduced several policy'measures to regulate the activities of:market traders. The Price Control Decree of 1972 stipulated that ' any person.who speculates or deals in any of the commodities specified in the decree with the purpose of making excessive or unlawful profit, shall be guilty of an offence, and liable on summary conviction to imprisonment not less than three months, and not exceeding ten years without the option of a fine". In addition, the decree included the forfeiture of market stalls/stores, and ban from trade in a market for a period of up to twelve months, for those who violated the provisions of the decree. These price controls and regulations were extended to locally-produced foods as well. They were enforced by police and.military personnel, students and workers, who were sympathetic to the military junta. These state actions worsened the already precarious shortages of imported.and.locally-manufactured.commodities in the country. In the process, market traders hoarded their comodities, and withdrew them from sight. One newspaper report recounted some of these occurrences: Several market stalls in various markets in Accra remained bare as many traders failed to display their commodities following the insistence by students and workers to buy at controlled prices. Others who owned supermarkets and shops, however, displayed few items of provisions with a view to selling them quickly before the arrival of the "revolutionary“ students and workers (The Ghanaian Times,November, 1977:1). The hoarded commodities were available only to those who could connect to the "underground" network for the sale and distribution of commodities, but at prices about ten times the price controls. For instance, milk was supposed to be sold at 45 pesewas, but was sold at C4.50, that is, ten times the stipulated price in 1976. The withdrawal of commodities, and the creation of the “underground“ market, frustrated the capacity of state officials to control/regulate activities of market traders. In the end, some, state officials joined the market trader “underground" market, and supplied them with commodities, with the sole purpose of also benefitting from their illegal activities. Thus, market traders had the capacity to pull corrupt state officials into their camp, and ‘were successful in sabotaging and.defeating the price control policy. Similarly, Rawlings'. military state (from June to September, 1979, and from December 1981 to April 1983) , reintroduced the price control idea in the Ghanaian marketplace to regulate the activities of market traders. The police, the military and other state agencies stormed public markets, and enforced price controls. In the process, they ”a 7 seized commodities from traders, and sold them.at prices way below their actual official prices. I remember joining a queue to buy a screwbdriver even though I did not need it at that time, because it was being sold by a military personnel for only 25 pesewas, about one-tenth of its official price. Some police and. military personnel also took some of these commodities away as booties, as if they were their prizes for engaging in such exercises. The Pioneer reported: A survey of Kumasi Markets has revealed that some policemen and women and soldiers in Kumasi have turned the markets and shops into GOLDMINES where they extort huge sums of money from frightened traders. The survey also showed that these service personnel go round and buy goods at very ridiculous low prices and later sell them at high prices. Some of the traders interviewed were unanimous that some of the police and military personnel go round with old, pro-budget price-lists, arrest traders, threaten them with the Public Tribunal, and.exhort.monies ranging from.Cl,OOO to C10,1000 from them.before dropping the case (The Pioneer, July 1, 1983:1). Some market traders, mostly women, were caned in public (often naked, which was a grievous traditional insult to African/Ghanaian'women) for selling above the price controls. In fact, in Kumasi, a woman cloth trader was shot for profiteering (her baby was removed from her back before she ‘was killed) [Fraker and. Harrell-Bond, 1979:2182). State repression of market traders also took an ugly turn when the military personnel used dynamite and razed the Makola Number 2 Market. This market was believed to be the center of trade in Ghana, the chief wholesale and retail market in Accra. What made it a target was that it was generally portrayed as the 8 center of trade malpractice, and the hub around which the “underground economy” was organized in Ghana (The Ghanaian Iippp, August 20, 1979:1-2). The space previously occupied.by Makola Number Two was later used for the construction of a parking lot for Accra elite shoppers. However, recent attempts at portraying market traders as victims of state oppression, unorganized, and.powerless, does not fully capture the long history of market traders' mobilization and struggle in dealing with powerful/large structures such as the state and its institutions of control. For example, Robertson (1983) states that as a result of various pressures created by the degree of competition between traders in the market, and build-up of substantial political opposition to their presumed power over prices and supply, market traders/women have not been able to organize to represent their own interests. She states that: In spite of the noise to the contrary, the bulk of the market traders, like the majority of the population, is politically powerless. Their voluntary associations are mainly for mutual help and are politically inactive.... The basic powerlessness of the market women, large and small, is shown by their defenselessness in the face of arbitrary acts of the government (1983:476). As already indicated, what was significant about this period. ‘was :market traders' capacity for collective mobilization, and resistance/sabotage of the price control policy. Withdrawal of commodities from the markets in Ghana was one of the key strategies of traders to register their protest against the price control and state violence against 9 them. Market traders survived through I'underground'I networks, which controlled the supply and distribution of commodities in the marketplace. In fact, it is not unreasonable to argue that the capacity for mobilization among Ghanaian market traders enabled them to sabotage the price control mechanism and regulation of their activities, and eventually contributed immensely to compel Rawlings' military state to embark on a program of economic reforms, including trade liberalization and elimination of price controls in April 1983. The cessation of the price control policy was a testament to the success of market traders' collective struggle to resist state interferences in their economic activities in the marketplace. James C. Scott (1987:421) has aptly argued that "such everyday forms of resistance are effective, widespread, durable, and highly coordinated". 1.2 STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM Given the preceding recent historical context, the point of departure for my study was how market traders mobilized to articulate their collective interests vis-a-vis local government institutions in their communities, within the larger context of global/state restructuring processes. The study sought to investigate how the human-social agency of market traders relate to their external environment, particularly local government institutions. So far, very little documentation on how market traders 10 mobilize to deal with powerful/large structures, such as state/local government institutions exist in Ghana. Past research on market trader associational activities focused on their recruitment strategies, and their socio-economic functions, but failed to examine their mobilization and articulation of their collective interests vis-a-vis their external environment. However, research on the relationship between market traders and state/ local government institutions is quite important since it would provide us information to understand what aspects of the policy environment affect market trader activities, and what strategies they utilize to influence the policy environment, to survive in the marketplace. How market traders empower themselves to deal with powerful bureaucracies, surprisingly has not been the fascination of social scientists who do research on collective action and social movements in Africa, Ghana in particular. The reasons for such an oversight/neglect are not far-fetched: they pose more conceptual/ theoretical and methodological challenges to the researcher than studies of workers in the formal sector, such as labor unions in private and public institutions. Here, there is an apparent ease with data collection from official primary and secondary sources of data. Realizing the gaps in our understanding of market trader activism, I sought to study a market trader collective in the 11 Kumasi Metropolitan Area in Ghana, to examine the sources of conflict between its members and the local government institution, and how it mobilized its members to articulate their collective concerns. Thus, my research was a case study of an exploratory nature, which examined the relationship between traders in the Kumasi Central Market and the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority. The study was approached from a global perspective. The contention of the author is that in order to have a better understanding of market trader activism in the 1983-1992 period, it is necessary to appreciate the changes taking place both within the global political economy, as well as their impact on state and local government institutions. It was contended that crisis within the global capitalist economy in the 1970s initiated restructuring of the global economy itself in terms of capital, role of the state, and markets. Peripheral countries, particularly Ghana, which had been dependent on primary commodities in the global economy, inherited huge balance of payment problems, debts, and debt- service problems. Here, the role of international capitalist institutions such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund have become quite critical in helping peripheral capitalist states to adjust to the crisis in the global system. Subsequently, both organizations have been relatively successful in convincing peripheral states, like Ghana, to embark upon Structural Adjustment Programs (SAP). The goal is 12 to redress what they call “distortions in the economy". However, SAP has also set into motion state/local government restructuring processes. State restructuring has involved austere measures which have been designed to increase state revenues while at the same time contracting state/public services, as well as emphasizing disciplined state expenditure. These measures, arguably, have become necessary as a result of increasing burden on the part of peripheral states to devote greater proportions of their foreign earnings, if any, to service accumulated debts from international financial institutions, such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund. Local government institutions which used to depend upon the central government have had to shoulder greater responsibilities by providing services to their communities. However, the catch is that they have to rely on their local communities for tax revenues, while at the same time reducing the quantity and quality of services they provide for their communities. Market traders have come to feature quite prominently as a major source of tax revenues for local governments, and hence have become key players in the urban political economy in Ghana. Thus, one of the objectives of the study was to examine the extent to which the global/state/local government restructuring processes had impacted market traders' activities. Second, it investigated the institutional and 13 structural factors which engendered conflict between market traders and state/ local government institutions. Finally, the study analyzed market trader mobilization, and modus pperandi for articulating their collective interest/concerns. 1.3 SIMPICANCE OF THE STUDY The study provides some insights into the capacity of informal economy workers, particularly market traders, to mobilize to influence their external environment. Past social science research on collective action in the workplace focused mainly on organized labor in the formal sector, and to a large extent, overlooked the urban informal economy in Ghana. The present investigation seeks to fill some of these gaps by providing a window into the internal structure, and modus operandi of market trader mobilization and collective action vis-a-vis local government institutions. More importantly, the study seeks to investigate the human-social agency of market traders, especially their capacity for mobilizing to influence powerful/large bureaucratic structures, whose policies affect their survival in the marketplace. The study will also contribute generally to theoretical and policy discussions on the urban informal economy, particularly market traders, in the political economy of developing countries. The relevance of these activities for development in the Third World, and Ghana in particular, has been questioned by some scholars (Ninsin, 1991) . On the other 14 hand, some scholars (Desoto, 1989) have projected them as _s_i_:;e_ qpa non for development in the Third World. However, it is interesting to observe that those who advocate support for the informal economy to enhance their role in Third World economy, often ignore issues regarding their mobilization, especially associations they form to defend and articulate their collective interests in the marketplace. International development agencies and Non-Governmental Organizations (NGOs) stand to benefit from this research. It will demonstrate that while material provisions such as financial assistance and credits, as well as training are essential for improving the activities of workers in the informal economy, especially market traders, it is also important to stress factors (both.internal and.external) which affect the mobilization of these workers to articulate their collective interests in the marketplace. Most importantly, the study also seeks to make a contribution to theoretical discussions on grassroots movements, particularly in the Third World, and their interconnections with the global system. The study illustrates that grassroots mobilization is deeply affected by the international transformations of the global economic base, and its mediation through national/local political contexts, and people's everyday actions and activism. Hence, the search for a comprehensive understanding of grassroots mobilization in the fringes of the periphery of the global system, must 15 incorporate structuralist (macro-level analysis), national/local political processes (mezzo-level analysis), as well as human agency (micro-level analysis), that is, how people resist/challenge domination in society.2 1.4 DEFINITIONS OF KEY CONCEPTS Market Trader: A person who either produces, or distributes, or retails goods and services in a marketplace. Activism; The act of opposing something one is against, or acting in behalf of those things one supports. These involve both overt (open) and/or covert (clandestine and underground) activities. Th2 Statg: The roles, institutions, and individual office occupants having particular drives, compulsions and aims of their own related to decisions binding upon all segments of society in a certain territory.3 Central Government: A political organization with a centralized administration, from which devolves authority to governments in regional and local communities. Local Government: A political organization which has legal and political jurisdiction over a relatively smaller community in a state. 16 1.4 ORGANIZATION OF THE STUDY Chapter Two presents the setting for the study. It provides a background discussion on the history, politics and economy of Ghana, but with special emphasis on the Kumasi Metropolis. Chapter Three discusses markets, and market trader phenomena in Ghana, but Kumasi in particular. Chapter Four puts the Ghanaian experience of market trader-state relationship in a broader conceptual and research context. Chapter Five provides a resume of the research procedures for the collection and analysis of data for the study. Chapter Six examines global restructuring processes and their impact on state versus civil society dilemma in Ghana. It also discusses market traders as social-human agency, and their collective mobilization to resist/challenge domination in society. Chapter Seven assesses market trader activism within the larger context of the l'democratization" processes that are emerging from the 'bottom.up' in Ghana. ‘ Chapter Eight provides the summary and conclusions of the study. CHAPTER TWO THE SETTING FOR THE STUDY: GHANA Introduction This chapter presents background discussion on the history, economy, politics, and demography of Ghana, and the Kumasi Metropolis. Qppgpaphical Backggound Ghana is situated on the West Coast of Africa, north of the Gulf of Guinea. Her neighbors are the Ivory Coast to the West, on the northdwest and north is Burkina Farso, and on the east is the Republic of Togo (see Figure 2.1). From south to north, it extends from about latitude 4o 2' N to about latitude 1f’ 10' SN, a distance of about 420 miles. From west to east, it extends from 3° 15' 3W to 1° 12' 0E. The country has an area of approximately 92,100 square miles which is roughly equal in area to the United Kingdom of Great Britain and about the size of the State of Oregon1 P ati The results of the March 1984 census showed a total population of 12.2 million, giving an average annual growth rate of 2.6 percent since 1970, and an average population density of 50 per square kilometer. The highest densities are in the urban areas, which accounted for 31 percent of the total population in 1984. In 1991, the United Nations 17 Ghana 18 0 km 100 200 w Ffi——w-—-—-H 0 miles 50 too 150 NI OER —— Main toads -+-v-v- Main runways IURKINA -— International boundaries -------- Internal DOUMIHOS Main airport Source: Economic Intelligence, Country Profile, 1994 :1 19 estimated that the population of Ghana had risen to 15.0 million, implying an acceleration in the growth rate to an average of 3.5 percent per year over 1984-1990 period. At the time of the 1984 census, the most populous region by far was Ashanti with 2.09 million (17 percent of the total), and the least populous Upper West with 438,008 (3.6 per cent). Other important regions were Eastern with 1.68 million (13.8 percent), and Greater Accra with 1.4 million (11.5 percent).2 Historical Backgpound Long before formal colonization by the British at the end of the nineteenth century, the territory called modern Ghana, was inhabited by about one hundred ethnic groups, who were organized under native traditional structures and institutions such as families, clans, tribes, villages, towns, and kingdoms. Some of these ethnic groups had become so powerful that they had established dominance over other ethnic groups. The Ashanti Kingdom, for example, covered almost fifty percent of present-day Ghana. Its boundaries extended far into the northern, western and southern sections of Ghana. Ashanti people, therefore, gained control of the precolonial economy of Ghana, particularly in the hinterland.3 The first contact between Europe and the Gold Coast occurred in the late fifteenth century when a party of Portuguese landed and subsequently established a small 20 trading base on the southern coast. During the next three centuries the English, Danes, Dutch, Germans, and Portuguese established control over various segments of the coastal region. A number of these groups used the small footholds to facilitate their participation in the lucrative West African slave trade. Ultimately, only Great Britain came to exercise control over any major portion of the area. British rule was confined to a few coastal settlements until the middle of the nineteenth century, when Great Britain began to expand its control into the interior. This ambitious venture brought them.into a long series of conflicts with the most powerful of the inland kingdoms, the Ashanti. In 1901, the British succeeded in gaining formal control over the Ashanti and in turning the Northern Territories into a protectorate. Colonial rule ended on March 6, 1957 after the people of the Gold Coast voiced their demands for change, and were successful in gaining political independence from the British. The country's name was changed from the Gold Coast to that of the ancient sub-Saharan empire of Ghana, which flourished during the Middle Ages.‘ Political Backgpound Between 1957 and 1993, Ghana had a turbulent political history. So far, Ghana has experienced nine governments alternating between civilian and military rule. In fact, the military defacto regimes have ruled Ghana longer than 21 civilian regimes [see Table 2.1 showing civilian and military regimes in Ghana from 1957-1993]. The first civilian regime under Kwame Nkrumah was toppled by the military junta, led by senior officers of the army. In explaining why they toppled Nkrumah's government, the principal architects of the coup "emphasized their resentment at Nkrumah's interference with the army, his mismanagement of the Ghanaian economy, his repressive politics, and widespread corruption, intrigue and sycophancy of the Convention People's Party functionaries" (McCaskie, 1986:480). The first military regime, the National Liberation Council (NLC) ruled by decrees and projected itself as a typical guardian regime. It adopted austerity economic measures, culminating in the halting of several projects began under the Nkrumah government, the retirement of a number of workers considered to be redundant or a threat to the smooth running of the military regime. The NLC existed for only three years and ushered in the Second Republic under Dr. Kofi Busia, a distinguished sociologist, and a leader of the Progress Party (PP) and one-time rival of Nkrumah, was installed as the Prime Minister, under a new constitution, with Edward Akuffo as the non-executive (ceremonial) president (Pinkney, 1972). However, the Second Republic was short-lived. On January 13, 1972, another military coup d'etat led by Colonel Kutu Acheampong brought the demise of the Busia 22 Table 2.1 Date: W M: W 1957-1966 Dr. Kwame Nkrumah Civilian State Socialism (Convention Peoples Party) 1966-1969 General Emmanuel Military Market-oriented Kotoka (National Liberation Council) 1969-1972 Dr. K.A. Busia Civilian Market-Oriented; (Progress Party) 1972-1978 Gen. I.K. Acheampong Military Self-Reliant Development I (National Redemption Council, Supreme Military Council I) 1978-1979 Gen. F.W.K. Military Self-Reliant Akuffo (Supreme Military Council II) Development II 1979 June-September Flt. Lt. J.J. Rawlings Military Tightened Economic (Armed Forces Revolutionary Council) Controls 1979-1981 Dr. Hilla Limann Civilian No Real Change (People's National Party) 1981-1992 Flt. Lt. Rawlings II Military Structural Adjustment (PNDC) Program I 1993- Flt. Lt. Structural Adjustment Rawlings (National Democratic Party) Civilian Program II Source: Alan Roe and Hartmut Schneider, 1992 W p-40- 23 government. The following poignant account on Busia's short rule in Ghana illuminates some of the reasons underlying his overthrow by the military: Busia' brief record of twenty-seven months in power was not a happy one: it largely confirmed the view that Kofi Busia was a cleverer academic than he was a politician. By a series of sweeping measures he continually tried to clear his path f obstacles to the kind of liberal democracy he professed, only to find his difficulties increasing and having to fall back on some of the illiberal and undemocratic practice of which he accused ex-President Nkrumah. What made matters worse for Busia was that he presided over notoriously divided team of well-educated Ministers and he was unable either to sack the critics within his Cabinet or to assert his effective authority (Africa Contemporary Rgcord, 1992:552). The National Redemption Council (NRC), following the 1972 coup, was established to rule Ghana. The regime under Acheampong, sought a policy of national self-reliance, and pressed for increased food and agricultural raw'material production in the country. In October 1975, a seven-man Supreme Military Council (SMC) was set up as the highest legislative and administrative organ of Ghana. But an internal or "palace—coup” forced Acheampong to step down in 1978. The SMC was reconstituted under General Fred Akuffo, Acheampong's deputy. On June 4, 1979 a coup d'etat by junior officers of the Ghana Armed Forces, toppled Akuffo's regime. An Armed Forces Revolutionary Council (AFRC) was set up. The main goal of the AFRC was to rid Ghana of corruption before handling over power to the civilian. Flight Lieutenant Jerry Rawlings emerged as the leader of the AFRC military regime. The AFRC 24 “v. ruled Ghana for about four months, and handed power over to the People's National Party (PNP), and Dr. Hilla Limann served as the President in September, 1979. The Third Republic under Limann was short-lived. On December 31, 1981, Rawlings and the military seized power again through a coup d'etat. Rawlings cited corruption and economic maladministration as the reasons for his "second coming" (McCaskie, 1986: 485-488). The Provisional National Defence Council (PNDC) headed by Rawlings was established to run Ghana. Between December 31, 1981 and December 1992, the PNDC survived more than six known counter-coups. The need for a stable political climate was long overdue. However, a combination of political and economic developments in Ghana (discussed in detail in chapters 4 and 6) have led to democratic reforms. Even here, the general and presidential elections that were conducted in November and December, 1992, respectively, were boycotted by political parties opposed to the PNDC, on the grounds of election irregularities and fraud by PNDC-appointed election officials. The PNDC-sponsored party, the New Democratic Congress, won the elections, and Rawlings became the President for the Fourth Republic, beginning January 4, 1993. Thus, the political climate in Ghana since independence has been one characterized by disarray, chaos, and confusion. Hence, abrupt changes in government, and the political turmoil have affected Ghana's economic 25 development. As McCaskie points out: "the quest for political stability is intimately bound up with the state of the Ghanaian economy. As was the case with previous governments of Ghana, the economy was, and remains, the biggest single problem confronting the ruling PNDC regime" (1986:486). Economic Backgpoundi Essentially, Ghana is an economically dependent country: its economy is dependent on primary agricultural commodities, and imports. Cocoa, the mainstay of the Ghanaian economy, covers about 50 percent of the land under cultivation, and accounts for 60 percent of the export earnings. Food crops and livestock, as well as other important exports of Ghana include timber, gold, diamond, bauxite, and manganese, account for 40 percent of export earnings [see Table 2.2 showing the structure of exports from Ghana]. What is troubling about dependence on primary products is that it makes the economy vulnerable to vicissitudes of commodity prices at the world market, determined largely by the performances of economies of core countries in Europe, North America, and Asia. Ghana is also heavily dependent on commodity imports from core countries of the global system, It imports agricultural raw materials (foods), fuel, machinery and transport equipment, and other manufactured goods [Table 2.3 shows the structure of Ghanaian imports from 1980-1991.]. The irony is that Ghana has no control over the prices of these imports, and pays for them.through its exports whose 26 TABLE 2.2 STRUCTURE OF EXPORTS [percentages] Primary Commodities Manufactures Other 1980 83.9 15.1 1.0 1985 72.4 22.4 5.2 1990 60.6 10.2 29.2 1991 60.6 10.2 . 29.2 Source: United Nations, AfricanfiSocio—oconomic Indicators, 1991, Economic Commission for Africa; p. 55. 27 TIBLB 13 STRUCTURE OF IMPORTS [Percentages] Food Fuel Machinery other other Items and Equip-eat Manufactured Goods 1980 7.8 26.7 29.7 29.9 5.9 1985 4.0 29.2 26.4 33.6 6.8 1990 9.9 35.6 20.8 26.5 . 7.2 1991 9.9 35.6 20.8 26.6 7.1 Source: United Nations. “Waters. 1991, Economic Connission for Africa; p. 60. 28 prices are determined by external forces. Since the 19708, the story of Ghana's economy has been one of stagnation and deterioration. The performance of the economy has been characterized by declining output of key sectors, persistently high rate of inflation (116 percent on the average in the 1970-1983 period), balance of payments difficulties, large government budgeting deficits and excess liquidity. The rising cost of living and depreciation of the value of the Ghanaian currency sharply reduced the standard of living of the average Ghanaian.‘ The overall GDP declined at an average annual rate of 1.3 percent. There was a sharp decline in per capita income--averaging 3.8 percent during the some period. External debt reached $2 billion and debt service ratio amounted to 35.9 percent in 1984. However, the net resource flow rose from -$90.5 mdllion to +$566.3 million in 1984 (can, 1986:118). The poor performance of Ghana's economy during the 1970-1983 period has been attributed to both internal and external factors. The WOrld Bank and the International Monetary Fund, for example, have put the blame on internal factors, particularly the excessive role of the public/state sector of the economy, as well as poor economic planning and management. Others have attributed the poor showing of the economy on adverse weather (droughts), bushfires during 1978-1983) which seriously reduced agricultural output, and created major food shortages. From.my own vantage point, Western analysts often fail to get to the root of the 29 fiNflEILA Balance of Payments 1984 1986 1988 1990 [In Millions of U.S. Dollars] Exports 566.7 749.4 881.0 896.9 Cocoa Beans 381.7 503.3 462.0 360.6 Gold Timber Other 103.3 106.4 168.5 201.7 21.2 60.5 44.1 106.2 118.0 95.6 144.2 216.6 Imports 616.0 733.5 990.9 1,233.7 Oil 161.0 122.6 142.9 199.9 Non-oil 455.0 610.9 848.0 1,033.8 Trade Balance -49.3 15.9 -109.8 -336.8 Source: International Monetary Fund, 1991. Ghana 3 Adjustment and Growth, p.8. 30 problem: that is, the external orientation of the Ghanaian economy, and its dependence on the global system” These circumstances often create a lot of headaches for the Ghanaian economy. For example, the sharp increases in petroleum prices, followed by world recession and declining export prices, usually create a major deterioration in Ghana's terms of trade, and burden it with negative balance of payments [see Table 2.4 showing balance of payments of Ghana for the 1970-1982 period]. Currency The unit of currency is the cedi (C), which is divided into one hundred (100) pesewas. Fifteen months after the PNDC came to power, in April 1983, a system of surcharges on imports and bonuses on exports was introduced. This was effectively a devaluation of the cedi, since surcharges on imports amounted to 750% of the amount being spent, and the discounts on exports amounted to 990%; but the real devaluation was avoided for fear of political repercussions.’ Since October 1983, the exchange rate of the cedi to the US$ has increased at alarming proportions. [Table 2.5 shows the average exchange rate of the Ghanaian cedi from 1980-1992). 31 Table 2.5 Ayera e Exc a Rate Cedis er U.S. 1980 1983 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 2.7 3.4 54.0 89.2 153.7 202.4 270.0 326.3 367.8 437.1 Saute: EbammfioinuelLufimoelhfii, (inma:(kuanarnfile,Sinial. Dgggggaghic Characteristics Age ggd Gender Structure of the Population In 1980, 1985, and 1989, females maintained a steady representation of 50.4 percent of the total population in Ghana. In terms of age groups, the data show that Ghana has a heavy dependent population, with about half of the total population (45.2 percent in 1989) under 15 years of age. Those in the 15-60 age bracket represented 52.4 percent of the total population [see Table 2.6 showing age and gender structure of the population]. Education and Literagz Legels By comparison, Ghana has one of the best and highest levels of educational attainment in Sub-Saharan Africa. However, a closer examination of the data shows that males have more access to formal education than females in the Ghanaian society. Initially, there seems to be parity in the proportion of males and females in primary schools. However, 32 TABLE 2.6 AGE AND GENDER STRUCTURE OF THE POPULATION Females as Percentage of Total Population 1980 1985 1989 50.4 50.4 50.4 Age Groups as Percentage of Total Population [Percentages] 1980 1985 1989 0-14 15-64 65+ 0-14 15-64 65+ 0-14 15-64 65+ 44.9 52.4 2.8 '44.? 52.4 3.0 45.2 51.8 2.9 Source: United Nations, African Socio-economic Indicator; 1990, Economic Commission for Africa, p.315. 33 as one moves up the educational system, females gradually fade from the picture in large proportions. At the secondary (high) school level, males are almost twice as many as females. At the tertiary (post-secondary) level, it is disappointing to realize that in 1990, males outnumbered females by a ratio of 4 to 1 [see Table 2.7 showing enrollment in Ghanaian schools]. In 1990, 60.3 percent of the total population 15 years and over was literate. However, there were differences between males and females. While 70 percent of males were literate, only 51 percent of females were literate [see Table 2.8 showing the literacy rates in Ghana]. The differential educational attainment and literacy levels for men and women in Ghana, have consequences for their participation in the occupational structure of Ghana. Qgggpgtional Structurg About 70 percent of the population in Ghana live in rural areas, and engage in agricultural activities such as farming, fishing, and hunting, to mention but a few; These farmers and their families produce the cocoa for export, and also food for local consumption. It is within the urban areas that one could see diversity of occupations in the formal and informal sectors of the Ghanaian economy. Overall, about 48 percent of females work in the agricultural sector. About 18 percent of the females are found in the industrial sector, while 34 percent of them are 34 TABLE 2.7 ENROLLMENT IN GHANAIAN SCHOOLS [Percentages] 1970 1980 1985 1987 1988 1989 1990 MALES PRIMARY 57.0 55.6 56.0 55.0 55.0 55.0 55.0 SECONDARY 72.3 62.0 61.0 61.0 61.0 61.0 62.0 HIGHER 85.7 82.6 83.0 83.0 82.0 78.0 80.0 EDUCATION FEMALES PRIMARY 43.0 44.4 45.0 45.0 45.0 45.0 45.0 SECONDARY 27.7 38.0 39.0 39.0 39.0 39.0 38.0 HIGHER EDUCATION 14.3 20.4 17.0 17.0 18.0 22.0 20.0 Sources: United Nations,MW Atrial 1986- Uorld Bank.W. 1980.1990 United Nation. W. 1993- 35 TABLE 2.8 mm POPULATION 15 YEARS or ass AND osz a! sxx [PERCENTAGBS] 1981 1985 1990 Total Male Female Total Male Female Total Male Female 46.3 56.3 35.0 53.2 64.1 42.8 60.3 70.0 51.0 Source: United Nations,W. ‘ 1991, Economic Commission for Africa: p. 19. 36 engaged in the service sector. For males, about 55 percent of them.are found in the agricultural sector, 20 percent in industry, and 25 percent in the service sector. These data show that for both males and females, agricultural activities are the most important sources of occupation. The major difference is in the area of services, particularly commercial activities. There are absolutely more women in commerce than men. In 1970, there were 368,900 women employed in the commercial sector compared to only 67,000 men in the same sector. Simdlarly, the women in trading accounted for 84.6 percent of total employment in the commercial sector. WOmen's participation in the industrial sector should not be overlooked; women play a recognizable role in the manufacturing sector, especially in the manufacture of bakery products, miscellaneous food preparation, and the manufacture of wearing apparels. This section has painted a picture of Ghana, and has provided socio-historical and demographic characteristics of the population. It has been shown that Ghana is a country which has been struggling for a place under the sun. Its economy and politics have suffered several setbacks since independence, and have produced ups and downs in its development process. Education is major asset of Ghanaians. but women in Ghanaian consume less of the quantity and quality of education in the society. women are not only over-represented in commercial activities in the society, but also provide the labor for the production, 37 transportation, and distribution of food, and other agricultural commodities. KUMASI Kumasi is generally called "The Garden City of West Africa“ because of its beautiful landscape, and trees along its streets. It is the administrative capital of the Ashanti region, which is the region with the largest population in Ghana. The development of Kumasi as a city is directly linked to the political, cultural, and economic history of Ghana, in general, but the Ashanti people in particular.8 Pre-Cglonial Kumasi According to Ashanti royal traditions, Kumasi was established by Oti-Akenten, the predecessor of Osei Tutu who founded the Asante nation, in the seventeenth century. Later, Kumasi came to serve as the administrative, commercial, and religio-cultural center of the Asante Empire in the nineteenth century. Kumasi served as the administrative capital of the Asante Empire. This function focused on the King of Asante's palace, and on the dwabrgim, the national meeting place of the Asante people. The palace in Kumasi served not only as the local residence of the Asante king, but also as the national treasury, and the meeting place of the Asante councilors, and the highest court of the Asante people. Kumasi, therefore, became the focus of power in Ashanti. The 38 concentration of power was accompanied by a concentration in ‘wealth. The wealth of the courts came from diverse sources including tributes, poll taxes, death duties, court fees, state enterprises, and official monopolies or prerogatives in trade. This wealth went into the royal treasury, from which it was dispersed to support the court. The second function of Kumasi was as a religio-cultural center of the Asante people. The assumption of this role resulted from its position as a political capital, and thus the location of the Asante King, and the Golden Stggl, which is traditionally believed to be the symbolic spiritual embodiment of the Asante state. The Asante King who resided in Kumasi, had the responsibility for prescribed acts of veneration and rituals to honor dead kings of Asante. Kumasi's role as a commercial center was due largely to its central geographical location. On the North-South axis, it was strategically located between European trade on the coast, and the Muslimrdominated trading entrepot of the savannah to the North. Thus, Kumasi's central location, access routes, wealth, royal monopolies and control of trade, all contributed to the emergence of Kumasi as a commercial center. In addition to local agricultural produce, items of trade included dried fish from the coast, and European goods such as rum, and textiles/clothing. 39 Kumasi In the Colonial Period In the early part of the twentieth century when the British captured and occupied Kumasi, the latter's commercial functions assumed a clear predominance over its administrative functions. It became the railhead for the only rail transportation between the Asante and the coast. This opened the Asante region in the forest belt to the export-import economy, since the railway afforded relatively cheaper movement and transportation of agricultural produce (such as cocoa, rubber, and timber) from the forest regions to the coast. It also enabled European and indigenous bourgeois and petty bourgeois classes to locate in Kumasi to establish commercial enterprises. The presence of Europeans in thecity in the colonial period also opened the city to additional functions, as an educational and mission center. These developments ensured that the greatest concentrations of Europeans and educated Africans would be in Kumasi, and provided still greater demand for European imports, which reinforced Kumasi's commercial pre-eminence. Eumasi As A.Modern,Metrgleis In present-day Ghana, Kumasi continues to serve as a pre-eminent commercial center. It is still the political and administrative capital of the Asante. It is cosmopolitan, with different ethnic migrant groups, and immigrants from Africa, and other continents. 4() l . / ' ” ' 6 ' . “ \ a w E ‘ n - o o - . \ ( ) A I O I I I I n a m e . . . \ / . ' o ' 0 ” A 8 0 0 9 ” A “ ' . ' “ a s “ n _ _ ) / . A ; — . . . . . . 3 l o u n - a m o n g ) " \ 0 . 0 : “ . . . q u r s ‘ l ‘ “ : 3 7 p - \ v ’ f 0 “ u c h u r n ‘ 1 0 “ . \ I , I I “ 8 ' 0 ! l ’ l . _ \ \ . \ _ \ . \ l — u — ‘ n ’ 1 ' . m \ \ [ 0 I A I I I I ‘ I . l I ' l ( c a n I \ I I , ’ - - \ I - - . ‘ \ \ . . . . . . “ . \ . \ . ’ \ “ G O A - O I n . n o ” I I I ’ I I ' \ » \ . \ . \ , \ . u _ . _ ‘ I A I A I I t o _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ . _ . . t o t u m o u r ; L O C A T I O N O F R E S I D E N T I A L A R E A S I N K U M A S I C I T Y C O U N C I L A R E ’ A F I G U R E 2 . 2 ‘ . o n . { N , v \ \ ' \ . l o a c " . ‘ \ R — L ‘ " ' , 0 9 u - \ \ . . - — s o I , ’ ( . \ ' \ / \ . . " m \ - \ ) _ , ’ I 5 : 3 3 : _ . ‘ { ’ 1 : ‘ l o u r ’ 3 . 3 : " : { _ - . A J \ / ' \ . / . / \ a n s " m ‘ u ‘ \ _ ‘ n : I - a n a ‘ \ \ : : E ' . : : , “ : ,n e a n a t q \ s o m e . \ . : : . l . l ; . a l w ‘ ‘ \ ~ ) ’ ‘ ’ 1 J I M “ 4 0 0 0 0 8 0 ! ” e r I . / ) " \ \ t ) ~ “ " . - , ’ - I e m u . 1 ’ . / \ \ - : 8 L l : : l \ ‘ s . . - a ‘ 5 : ~ 0 - 0 ~ 0 ~ . _ . — . ' 0 ‘ “ ! ” . W ' w . : : ~ _ \ I / . " ' 1 . 1 L . . . . , - ’ . 2 ' . ' t . -. - 6 1 : , i d V ‘ " ' $ { = 1 : : ~ 9 ’ m u s t " e a m u s I C I ' m w ‘ “ / ° r ' - ° / ’ I _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ I ] _ 1 . ' / I a m , - — ~ a n a n ‘ \ I \ n u a - - - - n u n o u \ ’ , “ 0 : 0 7 4 . . . “ , e m u . , . \ ' o I \ . " ' / 41 Dggggggphic Characteristics Table 2.9 shows the estimated population of Kumasi from 1901 to 1990. At the turn of the century, it was estimated that there were only 3,000 inhabitants in Kumasi. By the middle of the century (1948), Kumasi's population had reached 71,436. In 1990, Kumasi had developed into a metropolis with a population of 600,000 people, and had spread its sphere of influence to the outlying towns and villages. Thus between 1948 and 1990, Kumasi experience a population growth of about 740 percent. Much of this growth came from in-migration from within the Ashanti region, other regions in Ghana, and those who were born outside Ghana. In fact, in-migration accounted for 57 percent of the total population in Kumasi in 1970 (Republic of Ghana, 1978). Table 2.10 shows a breakdown of the age and gender characteristics of the Kumasi Metropolis. It shows that there is a heavy dependency ratio, with over 40 percent of the city's population under fifteen years of age. 47 percent of the population were aged between 15-44 years. Only 8 percent of the city's population were over 45 years. These data demonstrate that majority of the city's population are relatively young. However, there were no significant differences in the composition of men and women, apart from the observation that there were more older men and women in the city. 42 THEIR 1L9 POPULATION PROFILE OF KUMASI, 1901-1990 YEAR POPULATION 1990 1984 1970 1960 1948 1944 1931 1921 1911 1901 600,000 488,991 345,117 218,175 71,436 45,133 35,829 23,694 18,859 3,000 Sources 3 1. Census of Population (Ghana, 1948, 1960, 1970, 1984) 2. Fry and Drew's Development Plan Report (1944) 3. Abloh, (1972) 4. Tetteh (1967) 43 TABLE 2.10 AGE AND GENDER CHARACTERISTICS OF THE KUMASI METROPOLIS, 1970 AGE snoop MALE FEMALE Total 8 Below 1 year 5592 5681 11273 3.3 1—4 Years 23840 24449 48289 14.0 5—9 Years 24481 27921 52402 15.3 10-14 Years 19358 24859 42717 12.5» 15-24 Years 38482 37420 75902 22.0 25-44 years 47282 39277 86559 25.1 45-64 Years 12579 8734 21313 6.3 65 and Over 2660 2502 5162 1.5 All ages 174274 170843 345117 100.0 Source: 1970 Population Census of Ghana: Special Report "D”: Statistics of Localities and Enumeration, page 508-509. 44 Table 2.11 shows educational attainment of residents (aged six years and over by sex, age, and type of school) in the Ashanti Region. The data indicate that overall, males and females made up 54.5 percent, and 45.5 percent of individuals who had been to all types of schools. In fact, at the primary school level, women made up a greater proportion (61.7 percent). However, as one moves up the higher levels of the school system, women's representation, like the national trends, decreases accordingly. At the secondary/high school level, women are less than one-third of the total enrollment. At the commercial and technical levels, men's proportion to women is almost 2:1. The most significant differences between men and women are found at the university/college level. women represent only 10.5 percent of total enrollment. These differences in educational attainment have significant consequences on types of occupations men and women in the Ghanaian society, in particular in the Kumasi Metropolis, would pursue. With such low educational attainment, women would be found less in administrative and managerial positions, professions, and technical fields. Realistically, most women who are found in towns and cities in the Ashanti region, particularly Rumasi, are found in retail/trading activities, and self-employment in relatively small-scale businesses. 45 TABLE 2. 11 EDUCATIONAL ATTAINNENT 0F RESIDENTS (AGED 6 YEARS AND OLDER) IN THE ASHANTI REGION (BY SEX, AGE AND TYPE), 1984 TYPE OF SCHOOL AND ALL 6 YEARS AND OVER GRADE ATTAINED TOTAL HALE FEMALE ALL TYPES OF SCHOOLS 582,120 317,373 264,747 2818181 ALL GRADES mm ‘ ALL GRADES 31mm ALL GRADES 108,379 41,493 ' 66,886 408,011 229,958 178,053 37,239 26,968 10,271 ALL GRADES 12,955 8,010 4,945 IEAQIEELIBAININQ mm mm ALL GRADES 11,105 7,053 4,052 W W 480 358 122 mm ALL YEARS 3,951 3,533 418 Source: 1984 Population Census of Ghana, Demographic and Economic Characteristics, Ashanti (Statistical Service, Accra, Ghana) 46 Economic Activities Kumasi lies in the forest belt, and in the Ashanti region which is the largest producer of agricultural commodities including foodstuffs, timber, and cocoa, the chief export of Ghana. Its strategic position in the transportation system in Ghana, both road and rail, makes Rumasi a very good candidate for commercial activities. Traders have direct access to agricultural commodities, locally-manufactured commodities, as well as imported commodities. Table 2.12 shows selected occupations of employed persons 15 years and over in the Rumasi Metropolis. It demonstrates that more than two-thirds (70 percent) of Kumasi workers are engaged in commercial activities (sales, wholesale, and retail). Wholesale trade involves the selling of commodities in relatively large quantities, to be retailed by others. Retail trade involves selling commodities in small quantities. Generally, male traders in the commercial sector of the urban economy dominate the wholesale trade. Women, however, are over-represented in retail trade. They made up 78.5 percent of persons employed in retail trade. Wholesale trade generally involves large investments of capital for purchases, and storage facilities. One explanation for the apparent gender stratification in the commercial sector is the unequal access to capital markets. Generally, men have more access to capital markets than women. In fact, it is a common 47 TABLE 2.12 OCCUPATIONS OF EMPLOYED PERSONS 15 YEARS AND OVER BY GENDER IN THE EUMASI METROPOLIS, 1984 Total Kumasi Ashanti Region Metropolis All Occupations 922,762 207,568 Sales Workers 119,955 74,131 Men Women 20,536 99,419 15,430 58,701 Iholesale and Retail Trade 116,896 71,777 Men Women 18,392 98,504 13,793 57,984 Source: 1984 Population Census of Ghana, Demographic and Economic Characteristics, Ashanti Region, Statistical Service, Accra, Ghana, pages 125-131. 48 practice for most formal banks in Ghana to require women who apply for loans, to get the signatures/approvals of their husbands. Retail traders are dependent on wholesale traders. The former make arrangements with the latter to supply them commodities, in most cases on credit, which they sell in small quantities, and later pay back to the wholesalers. Others arrange with indigenous and multinational firms for supplies, and sell on ‘commission' basis. ‘Commission' is the ‘wage' retailers earn from the sales they make for commercial firms. Finally, other women, although the minority, operate in both worlds, serving as both wholesalers and retailers. Ethnicity and Suburbination Ethnic groups tend to be concentrated in different suburbs of the city. This may be attributed to the historical development of the city, rather than intentional ethno-class discrimination. The local Asante people are concentrated in the “old“ sections of the city: Bantama, Asante New Town, Manhyia (Manshia), and Mbrom to the north, and Asafo and Amakom to the west of the city. Fantis who migrated from the Central Region along the coast, settled in Kumasi in numbers after the opening of the railway between Kumasi and Sekondi-Takoradi. They were attracted by the prospects of work in rebuilding Kumasi and for Europeans traders (Tetteh, 1967). The Fantis in Kumasi 49 are concentrated in Fanti New Town, which is sandwiched between Asafo and Ashanti New Town. A second in-migrant group, the Ewes from.south-eastern Ghana and Togo, came to Rumasi after the opening of the railway to Accra in 1928. The Ewes are concentrated in Oforikrom and Anloga, in the south-western section of the city. Ethnic groups from.the Nbrthern and Upper regions of Ghana are found in Kumasi in large numbers. Historically, the 'northerners" performed services for the Asante Ring, serving as scribes, and keeping accounts and records in Arabic (Schildrout, 1978). The Nertherners in Kumasi are found in large numbers to the north of the city, where they have created a 'Zongo" community. It should be pointed out, however, that although areas like Anloga and Fanti New Town are known as Ewe and Fanti areas, respectively, they are not ethnically homogeneous. There are Asantes and other Akans who live in Zongos, while some Fantes live in Ashanti New Town. While in Kumasi for the fieldwork, I observed that new suburban communities that were being established included people from different ethnic groups. Here, social class was becoming more significant than ethnicity in determining people's places of residence. Thus the new residential developments in Danyame, Asukwa, Ahinsan, Atonsu, and Chirapatre, did not seem to exhibit a concentration of any one ethnic group. These areas had the most expensive real estate properties, and attracted residents and homeowners from across the spectrum of ethnic groups in the city. 50 In this section, I have attempted to provide a historical as well as demographic and socio-economic characteristics of the Kumasi Metropolis. I have demonstrated that Kumasi is a city in transition. As a precolonial town, it served as a significant administrative, political and commercial center. Colonialism which was directly connected to commercial activities in Ghana, heightened the commercial preeminence of Kumasi within the global economy. In modern Ghana, Kumasi continues to grow as a strategic commercial, political, and educational center. With Ghana's further integration into the global economy, and dependence on imports and primary commodities, Kumasi has come to serve as the connecting rod in the nexus of rural-urban interchanges, and a gateway to the hinterland of Ghana. In the process, commercial activities have become the pre-eminent sources of employment for the city's population, particularly women. The next chapter will discuss the commercial sector of the Ghanaian economy, particularly market trader retailing activities in the Kumasi Metropolis. CHAPTER THREE IN'PARTICULAR IN'GHANA, EUMASI Markets and.Marketplaces There are several definitions of the term.‘market' or ‘marketplace', but one of the clearest and most concise is that proposed by B.W. Hodder (1965:57): "...an authorized public gathering of buyers and sellers of commodities meeting at an appointed place at regular intervals". Similarly, Polly Hill (1966:295), defined a marketplace as ”an authorized concourse of buyers and sellers of commodities, meeting at a place more or less strictly limited or defined, at an appointed time”. In my analysis, the two concepts, ‘market' and ‘marketplace' are used interchangeably. Generally, there are two main classes of markets in Ghana; "rural" and “urban" markets, depending on the location of the market. About eighty-eight percent of markets in Ghana are rural, and their economic functions are basically the collection, bulking, and distribution of local farm.produce. A subsidiary function of the these markets is to act as a distribution center for imported commodities. These functions link gggg; markets to gppgg markets. The urban markets are usually found in the major towns and cities, and serve as centers for the distribution and retailing of farm produce as well as imported commodities. Markets can also be classified according to the level 51 52 FIGURE 3.1 fiagunmnum . €3unumu.uumcr OIEWOHLINMIT clmeaucovnm. 'ru’ inn” 290-- 70001 taint! omsr LEGEND has!“ mm Yacht-e- 41 . ‘“ . .. I “‘ Ameyaw (1990:20) GHANA DISTRIBUTION OF MARKETS 53 of organization, and frequency of meetings. In the case of Ghana, there are “periodic" and "daily" markets. Periodic markets are usually coterminous with rural markets. They are held at specific time intervals: thus, there are definitive days on which the level of activity is conspicuously high, and hence have come to define those days as "market days“. So far, there are six periodicity types: 3-day, 4-day, and six day, or one, two or three fixed days on a calendar week (Apeldoorn, 1977). The ggily markets are continuous, and the level of organizations are equally active on all days except on a day earmarked for religious or social festivities (especially Fridays, and Sundays), when the volume of the market activities go down. Daily markets may be held in the day, morning or night. However, the Rumasi Central Market which I studied is a day market: it opens as early as 6 O'clock in the morning and operates for twelve hours and closes at 6 O'clock in the evening. In fact, local government bye-laws stipulate that all traders and customers are expected to be out of the market at the specified time or else they would be prosecuted. The linkages between rural and urban markets correspond with the nature of the Ghanaian economy. Rural economic activities are mainly agricultural, hence agricultural products, particularly farm.produce find their way to the urban centers. Similarly, imported commodities from the neighboring countries, as well as overseas find their way to the rural areas mainly through the urban markets. Thus, the 54 FIGURE 3.2 RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN URBAN AND RURAL MARKETS IN GHANA Rm] Market District "P‘ Nation-l UrbanDaily Manner Pundit Market <—-w ‘— WenchLN‘huransah. Techiman Kunusi.Accn.Tamale Kintarupo Sunyani '31:” .l . 41:14me -selltprodweinbu1k ouanspunpruducehom .mmm monsoon: mordprwveproduce omgeuanspun pencdncmrkctcenw -pmcesandsellto 'FW. grading -payfmners 'Wsm -produca's-aelleo -wholelalc . mbanemsumen «seam-sells «harm qualms . («mutating vilhgeshup. hawker: Jam-gene's -insututiaulbuyer - :32 to huyingpost hukorwholesale disuibutionmtail mental! centres W. W Wholesalers. Cm retailers retailer's Somme: Stephen Ameyaw, 1990,.‘TheJDYnamics of Female Entrepreneurship in Indigenous Food Markets: A Case Study of Techiman, Ghana, p.23 55 dependent nature of the Ghanaian economy, creates some rural-urban interchanges of locally-produced and imported commodities. Figure 3.2 shows the relationship between rural and urban markets, periodic and daily markets in the food marketing structure in Ghana. The starting point of the food marketing structure is the rural market, where some farmers who are producer-sellers sell their commodities directly to wholesalers in the food business. These wholesalers are sort of "food contractors" who buy in bulk and transport them to district markets, such as wenchi, Nkoransah, and Kintampo in the Brong Ahafo Region. The district markets are the next levels of food marketing. Here, wholesalers purchase food in bulk, store them for some days while they arrange to transport them to the next level of marketing, at the national periodic markets. District markets and national periodic markets feed into each other; market traders commute from one market to the other to sell and purchase food and non-food commodities. Urban daily markets serve as centers for the distribution of locally-produced commodities, including food items, as well as imported commodities from neighboring countries and overseas. Urban markets are relatively larger in size and have higher volumes of activities than rural periodic markets, with the exception of a few national periodic markets which attract large numbers of traders on market days. Figure 3.3 presents a model of the interchanges between 56 m o m s a n d G o o d s / 4 — . ' R a w M a t e r i a l s I n d u s t r i a l P r o d u c t s F u n c t i o n — - ) I m p o r t e d I t e m s — ) P e r f o r m e r s P r i m a r y E s s e n t i a l C o m m o d i t i e s o f t h e B r o k e r a g e 4 — 9 S e c t o r I M P O R T S U r b a n E c o n o m y E n c l a v e E c o n o m y R u r a l E c o n a y A f r i c a n U r b a n N o t e s 2 ( 3 ) , P . 4 7 S O U R C E : R u t h S i m m s a n d E r n e s t D u m o r , 1 9 7 6 , " W o m e n i n t h e U r b a n E c o n o m y o f G h a n a : A s s o c i a t i o n a l A c t i v i t y a n d t h e E n c l a v e E c o n o m y " I N T E R C H A N G E S B E T W E E N S E C T O R S O F T H E G H A N A I A N E C O N O M Y A N D T H E G L O B A L E C O N O M Y F I G U R E 3 . 3 57 various sectors of the Ghanaian economy and the global economy. Ghanaian markets and market traders are major players in these interchanges. It demonstrates that the local Ghanaian economy and the global economy are integrated. This is made possible with the presence of an intercalary commercial activity both in the rural and urban sectors of the economy. An enclave economy emerges which serves as a conduit completing the incorporation of the periphery into the world trade system. The dominant economic functions of the enclave economy, therefore, are to intermediate between potential consumers and the producers. The enclave economy in the urban setting is dominated by women, particularly those that can be referred to euphemistically as the ”commercial proletariat“. In essence, therefore, women control this enclave sector within the urban setting (Nypan, 1960; McCall, 1962; Little, 1965; Sanjek and Sanjek, 1976). Within the urban enclave economy, the retail subsector is critical for the bulking and distribution of commodities. More significantly, it is mainly one to two-person economic enterprise which serves as a major source of employment for many women (Simms and Dumor, 1977). In the Ghanaian context, market traders perform a variety of functions for the urban, national and global economy. Mintz (1971:248-249) has summarized these functions: 58 a. they convey badly needed produce from the agricultural and craft producers, as well as import houses, to the consumer; b. the both bulk produce and break that bulk into small quantities which facilitate exchange at costs appropriate to the scale of production and buying capabilities of the customers; c. they process goods, like prepared foods, cosmetics, and condiments, as well as grinding or winnowing grains; d. they assume credit risks for customers regarded as bad risks by lending institutions because they have no collateral; e. they provide a market for the produce of widely scattered and accessible producers, even in the face of great transportation difficulties; f. they arrange and assume the costs of shipping, storage, and market fees and taxes; g. they substitute labor for capital at every opportunity, providing employment for many illiterates whose other avenues are strictly limited; h. they are the chief recycling agency for all sorts of waste materials like beer cans, newspapers, bottles, and even old homework papers, which are sold to other market women for wrapping produce; 1. they provide entrepreneurial training for young people, an alternative for those who cannot or do not want formal education. Gender Divisign of Lghor women constitute over eighty percent of participants in the commercial sector of the Ghanaian economy (Ewusi, 1985). women's dominance in the commercial sector could be explained from historical as well as structural perspectives. Prior to the establishment of the colonial economy, women in Ghana, were involved in food production, distribution, and marketing. But within the colonial context, women's status in agricultural production was reduced. Boserup states that I'European settlers, colonial 59 administrators, and technical advisors are largely responsible for the deterioration in the status of women in the agricultural sectors. It was they who neglected female agricultural labor force when they helped to introduce commercial agriculture to the overseas world and promoted the productivity of male labor" (1970:53-54). With decline in their status in agricultural production, women in Ghana tended to look to other alternatives. Historical evidence suggests that trade in small luxury items and food was probably carried out by women long before contact with Europeans (Robertson, 1974:212). But by the seventh century, when products sold in local markets became diversified to include imported agricultural commodities, provisions, textiles, and so forth, it was natural for women who were already involved with food distribution to enlarge their stocks to include the foreign items brought in by European firms (Sai, 1971:3). By the middle of the nineteenth century, women were said to be trading in all kinds of items in the urban centers, as well as in the remote villages (Simms and Dumor, 1977:47). 'In this way these women performed a valuable function for the European firms on the coast by retailing imported goods to even the smallest villages at no overhead cost to the firms" (Robertson, 1974:226). Thus colonialism.changed structural sectors of the Ghanaian economy, with the result that women came to concentrate in the commercial sector of the economy. 60 According to Clark (1982:12), withdrawal of men from.market trading intensified with Africanization of the government and business sectors after WOrld war Two. Some women moved into the lower levels of white-collar work at this time, creating even more room in the market. Thus social change in the form.of formal education and modern sector employment, also intensified the gender division of labor, as men left the marketplace for better jobs in the civil service, and commercial houses, while women replaced men at the lower levels of the distributive sector. However, the gender division of labor still remains in present-day Ghana. In the market, women are concentrated in food-related retail businesses, which are generally perceived as "women's work". Men constitute a smaller proportion of traders in local markets, although they own relatively larger commercial businesses outside the market. In local markets, men engage in the retail of locally- manufactured and imported commodities. These include textiles, provisions (imported foods), furniture, and gold/silver smith products. Others are cloth designers (tailors), tinkers, and second-hand cloth retailers. The major factor which accounts for the concentration of women in retail trade in particular, but informal economic activities in general, is their low levels of educational attainment. Women's education has always lacked behind that of men in the Ghanaian society. Some explanations that have been given thus far stress cultural 61 practices and expectations. In a traditional society, a major role for a woman is to ensure the continuity of the lineage, and she was expected to marry soon after puberty. In addition, a woman was expected to be provided for by her husband, and since education became a means for entering highly-paid jobs in the formal sector, it was considered more important for men to have formal education, since they *were to be the breadwinners in the family. Even women who start school, a higher proportion of them.than men, dropout due to pregnancies, poverty, and family preference to invest in the education of men more than women (Dolphyne, 1991). For those with lower educational qualifications, retailing of commodities became a viable option for earning a living, since there is a higher correlation between educational attainment and participation in formal sector jobs. Retailing of commodities, however, does not require technical skills acquired from formal educational institutions. women traders, particularly food retailers, tend to commercialize their trading skills they acquire as part of their socialization (Greenstreet, 1976). Education was still important for traders in the market. Market traders who were literate (at least with a high school diploma) could trade quite well in imported and , manufactured commodities, and maintain well-kept records of their business activities. However, what determined higher returns and profits among market traders was the size of capital investment in the business, rather than educational attainment (Clark, 1984). 62 The Eumasi Central Market1 The Kumasi Central Market is the largest single market in Ghana, as well as the whole of West Africa. Historically, it used to be called the “Great Market of Kumasi' during the peak of the Ashanti empire in the 17th and 18th centuries, when travellers from Northern and Southern Ghana and neighboring kingdoms of Denkyira, came to trade in Kumasi. However, the Kumasi Central Market in its present form, was constructed in 1928 by the British colonialists to promote commercial activities in the region. Since Kumasi was situated in the hinterland, the Central Market was supposed to be a major center for the exchange_of both local and imported commodities. ‘Within the city, the Central Market is located in the Central Business District. Its strategic position in the center of the city provides the Central Market several advantages over other markets in the city. Within the Central Business District, it is directly linked to an array of retail activities. Retail sales of local and imported commodities, for instance, are conducted in state-owned supermarkets (like the Ghana National Trading Corporation) and multinational supermarkets, such as the United Trading Company (U.T.C.), and the United African Company (U.A.C.). These supermarkets have direct access to import licenses from the Ghanaian state, which enable them to 63 connect to the larger global market for manufactured commodities from core countries of the global system, such as the United States, Great Britain, and Japan, to mention, but a few of the countries Ghana is dependent on for imports. Traders in the Central Market rely on these supermarkets for manufactured goods for sale in the market. Some of the manufactured goods I found in the Central Market, and which originated from the supermarkets included cement, textiles, tobacco, soap, and sugar. However, it must be stressed that the Central Market and the other markets in the city, complement the activities of the retail shops by offering a variety of commodities, particularly local farm produce, which are brought to the city from the Ashanti region, and its hinterland, which supply the city with commodities. The Central Market, is open air. This is understandable given the fact that Ghana is located in a warm/humid temperature zone, with an average temperature of about 70 degrees Fahrenheit throughout the year. The market is circular in shape, and walled, with ten gates around it. An imposing two-story building which houses the sub-offices of the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority sits in front of the market. One could have a panoramic view of the whole market from the second floor of the story building. The market is bordered by streets, and other urban use areas on all sides, leaving the market no room for further expansion. The space within the market is divided into stalls and 64 stores. A 5551; is basically a space between two separate walls where traders carry out businesses. The stalls are built of wood and roofed with corrugated iron sheets. Some traders have enclosed their open stalls for the sake of security. According to data supplied by the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority officials, there were 3,000 stalls in the market. I observed that the stalls were of different sizes. The maximum size was fifteen feet wide, eighteen feet long, and twelve feet high (15 by 18 by 12 feet). One could contrast this with some of the stalls which.measured only six feet wide, eight feet long, and ten feet high (6 by 8 by 10 feet). On the other hand, stores (storerooms) are built of cement, enclosed, and roofed with corrugated iron sheets. In all, there were 1,000 stores in the Central Market. The stores seemed more secure for traders because in most cases they could be locked at the end of the day's businesses, compared with the open stalls, where traders had to arrange to transport their commodities home and bring them back the next day. The stores were of different sizes. The largest store measured twenty feet long, fifteen feet wide, and thirty feet high. The smallest store measured ten feet long, eight feet wide, and twelve feet high. Traders who need a stall or store are requested to apply to the Treasury department of the Rumasi Metropolitan Authority, which officially owns the market. The latter allocates stalls/stores to applicants whenever they became 65 available. My interviews with the market traders revealed that only a few of them originally applied for stalls/stores. In fact, only forty five percent of those I interviewed applied for their stalls/stores. The rest (55 percent) “inherited" the stalls/stores from relatives who had traded in the market in the past. Relatives of dead occupants of market stalls/stores are supposed to report to the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority about the vacancy. However, they often do not do so. They pass on the stall/store to another member of the deceased occupant's family. It became quite clear to me why they behaved this way, upon further enquiry. They intimated to me that it was always difficult to get a store/stall when one applied for one. For those who applied originally for the stall/stores, they indicated that they had to wait up to twelve months on the average, before their applications were approved, and were eventually allocated stalls/stores. There were others who had to wait for more than twelve months, and still others who did not receive any response from the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority. The inadequacy of stalls/stores for market traders accounts for a higher number of traders who sell in the open spaces in the market. Squatters squeeze themselves in the narrow aisles of the market. They displayed their commodities in the open to attract more customers. However, these squatters were always at the mercy of the weather. I saw some squatters who stood in the scorching sun for hours 66 on end to sell their commodities. I also saw some traders who struggled to deal with their commodities when it rained because they did not have any place to keep their commodities, apart from leaving the market for home. Some squatters also conducted their business outside the market structure, into the streets in front, and behind the market. The Kumasi Metropolitan Authority often attempts to get rid of these squatters because their activities around the market, and in the streets are perceived to be causing overcrowding in the streets and traffic jams. In fact, one city official confided that these activities are an eye-sore to the beauty of the city. However, these squatters return to the same spots, or move to another section of the streets around the market, whenever they have been raided by KMA officials or the police. The squatters' popular spot was the entrance to the market, where they could deal directly with incoming customers to the market. ‘Within the market, there was an area specialization of commodities whereby similar commodity sellers tend to sit together. The layout of the market make this possible. The food sections occupy the largest space in the market. Each food produce has its own section. Thus, there is a section for vegetables, including pepper, tomatoes, okra, onion, and garden eggs. There are sections respectively for plantain, cassava, yam and cocoyam sellers. There are also sections for imported commodities such as cement, corrugated iron sheets, tobacco, textiles, and second-hand clothing. Market 67 traders and customers alike benefit from such an arrangement: for it aids the traders to control prices and supply, and makes it possible for customers to compare the goods regarding the quality, quantity, as well as the cost of the commodities, in order hopefully, to make a good choice. However, it has its negative side; market traders often compete with one another for the attention of potential customers. Dgggggaphic Characteristics of Central Market Traders a. Educational Attainment The educational attainment of traders in the market was generally low. Table 3.1 provides data on the educational attainment of traders in the Central Market. 46.5 percent of the traders had primary education, while 44.5 percent of them had no formal education. Only 9 percent had high school education. The relatively lower educational attainment of market traders is consistent with the educational characteristics of participants in other sectors of the urban informal economy as a whole. I have already argued that the lower the level of one's educational attainment, the greater the chances of participating in the informal economy. It leaves people with no possibility of being employed in the formal sector to become self-employed, often operating at the periphery of the urban economy. 68 TAHUS 3.1 LEYEL_QE_EDDQATIQN. HUNGER: BERGENTAQE PRIMARY SECONDARY VOCATIONAL/TECHNICAL COLLEGE 93 13 4 1 46.5 6.5 2.0 0.5 NO FORMAL EDUCATION 89 44.5 200 100.0% Source: Data Compiled from Field Research, 1992. Satple=200. 69 b. Sources of Capital There are several sources of capital formulation in the market. Table 3.2 provides data on the sources of capital for traders in the Central Market. The data show that the main source of capital for these market traders is personal savings, which accounted for the source of capital for about three-quarters of the traders in the sample. Upon further enquiry, traders indicated that they usually started their business life trading in small quantities of commodities. Others engaged in the processing and distribution of foodstuffs, and made some profits. Normally, traders move a step further to enlarge their businesses by depositing a seed capital with relatively larger commercial enterprises for supplies of commodities, and are credited with commodities over and above the initial capital. Others depended on esusu groups (pot banks) which provide ease of access. In Ghana, for example, designated collectors make daily tours of markets, accepting deposits from.market traders in the workplace. These esusu collectors charge a small fee for keeping the money over a period of time, and when the money had matured into larger sums, traders could collect the large sum from the money collectors. Family members are also an important source of capital. Twenty-three percent of the respondents indicated family members provided them capital. Financial support for family members to set up businesses is a strong value in the Ghanaian society. A family member may provide the initial 70 TABLE 3 . 2 SQEBQB NUMBER EEBQENIAQE PERSONAL SAVINGS 148 FAMILY MEMBERS 46 GOVERNMENT GRANT MONEY LENDERS BANK CREDIT OTHER l 3 1 1 74.0 23.0 0.5 1.5 0.5 0.5 200 100.0% Source: Data Compiled from Field Research, 1992. Sarp1e=2oo 71 capital for a trader to obtain supplies from.wholesale commercial houses. A few traders obtained capital from.money lenders. MOney lenders are indigenous credit-granting financial institutions. They usually charge higher interests for money they lend for fixed periods. In.most cases the interest rate is 100 percent of the amount of loan taken from them. Only 1.5 percent of the traders in my sample took loans from money lenders. Interestingly, the least sources of capital for market traders are formal banking institutions, and state development agencies. Less than two percent of traders received any support from these sources. The problem traders have with these formal sources of capital formation has to do with direct and indirect institutional discrimination: preferences for large-scale business because they are perceived to be relatively risk-averse, compared with small- scale businesses. Secondly, they emphasize l'collateral'I for loans, which.most small-scale business entrepreneurs, especially market women could hardly afford. But more importantly, because of kinship and femily relations, land titles, the commonest form of collateral, were not always clear, so banks did not wish to risk-losing money. Moreover, there was no governmont credit agency available to meet the valid economic needs of the people. As already demonstrated, these situations set the stage for alternative means of obtaining credit through esusu groups, as well as special 72 arrangements with commercial firms and support from.family members to establish credit. The foregoing section has argued that market traders depend on various informal credit institutions to generate capital for their businesses, supported by local values and traditions. It demonstrates that market women are quite resourceful, and ingenuous in overcoming the institutional discrimination against them in gaining access to capital. c. Family Characteristics It was interesting to observe that market traders were not different from the rest of the adult population: most of them were married and had children. Table 3.3 provides data on the marital status of traders in the Central Market. Seventy percent of the traders indicated they were married, while thirty percent of them were ‘single' individuals. Of the latter group, 16.5 percent were divorcees/separatees, one percent was widowed, and 12.5 percent had never married before. Table 3.4 presents data on family size of market traders. Twenty percent of the traders had more than six children per family. thirteen percent of them had five children per family. Fourteen percent of them had no children. Overall, the traders had an average of three children per family. One would have expected a higher average family size given the relatively low level of their education among traders. However, it seemed that the factor 73 TABLE 3 . 3 MARITAL_$IBIQ§ NUMBER EEBQENTAQE SINGLE (NEVER MARRIED) 25 12.5 SINGLE (DIVORCED/SEPARATED) 33 16.5 SINGLE (WIDOWED) MARRIED 2 140 1.0 70.0 200 100.0% Source: Data Compiled from Field Survey Research, 1992. Saqfle==200. 74 TABLE 3 . 4 1 CHILD 2 CHILDREN 3 CHILDREN 4 CHILDREN 5 CHILDREN 25 32 28 21 26 6 CHILDREN AND OVER 40 NO CHILD 28 12.5 16.0 14.0 10.5 13.0 20.0 14.0 200 100.0% Source: Data Compiled from Field Research, 1992. Saqfle==200. 75 of urbanization mediated the effect of educational attainment on number of children per family among these traders, since generally urban women have relatively smaller family size than those in rural areas (Ewusi, 1984). d. Mode of Market StallLStore Acquisition How did you acquire your stall/store in the Central Market? When this question was put to traders, it became clear that most of them.(55 percent) acquired their stalls/stores directly from family members, and not from the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority, which owns and operates the Central Market. The practice was that they "inherited“ these facilities from family members who previously rented them from the KMA. The rest (45 percent) indicated that they acquired them through direct applications to the KMA. Generally, the former method of stall/store acquisition is easier than the latter approach. Since there is a high demand for market stalls/stores, applicants wait for more than twelve months to get their applications approved, if they apply directly to the KMA. Those who do not get stalls/stores in the market could still operate their businesses on tables in the aisles within the market, at an approved fee of C 50 per day. The only disadvantage is that those who operate in the aisles of the market have no shelters, and they have to cart their commodities to their homes at the end of the day's activities. Q 76 e. Reasons for En a in Tradi Activities I also enquired about the reasons why the traders set up their own businesses in the market. The most popular response was the need to raise sufficient money to cater for their family needs. In particular, the women explained that their husbands' salaries from formal sector employment were inadequate. In fact, one woman narrated why she got into retail activities from home and gradually moved into the market. The husband's income was barely enough to pay for rent, much less able to feed the entire family of five people for thirty days. She was, therefore, forced to sell charcoal and processed foods in her neighborhood, until she was able to raise some money to venture into a relatively larger business in the market selling second-hand clothing. These stories could be repeated over and over, with variations on details and contexts. Most of the women were more concerned about the education of their children, and therefore their immediate purpose for engaging in retail trade was to generate revenues to pay their children's school fees, and provide stationery, and other resources to facilitate their children's learning at school and at home. Other traders admitted that the only means by which they could obtain any property of their own was through their business activities. In the Ghanaian context, women traders who are well off undertake real estate projects either in the city, or in their hometowns in the countryside. One woman intimated that she was engaged in 77 trading to raise capital for large-scale agricultural projects, such as cocoa farming and animal husbandry, in her hometown in the Ashanti region. Realistically, I discovered from.my interviews that the reasons why women and women engaged in trading activities were not different from those who worked in other workplaces: workers in both groups had a responsibility to provide for their personal material needs, as well as cater for the needs of their families, and hopefully raise enough money to undertake projects which could meet their immediate and future needs. In summation, this section has demonstrated that market traders, particularly market women, have relatively lower levels of formal education. But this was not the only reason why they engage in retail activities at the lower levels of the distributive system in Ghana. Institutional discrimination towards small-scale businesses bars these women from generating large capitals to expand their businesses. The traders have adapted to these hindrances by organizing grassroots institutions which provide them access to seed capital formation, as well as networks for supplies of commodities from.wholesale commercial houses. Their relationship to farmers and food contractors from the countryside is based on mutual trust which ensures the flows of commodities from the hinterland to the urban centers, of which traders in the Central Market, play a critical role as 78 distributors and intermediaries between producers and consumers. Market Associations ‘ In the Central Market, traders within each commodity sector are organized into informal associations. Formation of such associations is predicated upon the famous Ghanaian adage which states that "dodo so a mien [literary it means that when many people carry the load, it becomes lighter'] . Titles given to the leaders of these associations follow after titles given to leaders in Ashanti political system. For example, the title for a women leader of a commodity association is ohma or 'queenmother". She is normally chosen as the woman who has been on the market the longest and commands a degree of generalized adjudicative authority. She is expected to settle disputes among members. These disputes often center around competition for customers. Retail trading is a very competitive business, since no single trader can monopolize the commodities traders engage in. Quarrels often arise as traders compete for traders who visit the sector of the market where the commodities are sold. Traders vie to catch the attention of potential customers. They shout, and even sometimes persuade customers to purchase their commodities. I once visited the vegetable section of the market and observed this cometition. I observed that several market traders rushed on potential customers aggressively, to the extent of drawing them away from other competitive traders. Generally, traders have an understanding about the rules of the game, but if any trader felt that there was a foul play by other traders, she could report the matter to the 'queenmother', whose responsibility it is to settle the dispute. Thus, she is expected to maintain orderly commercial relationships among members by ensuring that they compete fairly in the marketplace (Clark, 1984). The ohemma or 'queenmother' also has control over the supply of commodities in the market. This is quite common among food traders. The ”queenmother' of a particular food sector negotiates the prices of food supplied in bulk by food contractors from the hinterland. In fact, it is the 'queenmother' who controls the prices of these foods, and her skills for such negotiations are critical for her selection as a leader. Unfortunately, she is often blamed for higher prices of food at the market when supplies are few (Dumor, 1982; Lawson, 1967). Ordinarily, these associations are a subset of the "voluntary associations" that have been observed in West African settings. Such voluntary organizations have been formed as common interest groups among members of the same ethnic, religious, and occupational orientations. They have been viewed as providing common security and welfare functions for members. Beyond providing emotional support, these organizations also assume economic and welfare functions in so far as they assist bereaved members, and contribute to funerals of deceased members, and act as 80 savings and credit associations). The commodity associations in the Central Market are very political, since their activities are tied to the overall urban political economy. They influence the extent to which the state can ensure affordable food prices for urban residents. When the prices of their commodities are prohibitive, they influence workers to persuade state authorities to demand lower prices in the market through price controls. Since market traders lose profits when they are forced to sell at controlled prices, they often do not adhere strictly to price controls. State authorities, however, enforce price controls with brutal force, and seizure of market trader commodities. For instance, when soldiers imposed price controls on foodstuffs in Ghanaian markets in 1979, 'queenmothers" of food commodity associations in the Central Market, made representations at the Ashanti Regional Administration offices. Under the sponsorship of the Regional Commissioner, they negotiated with representatives of consumer groups, government buyers, and the military on price controls for different sizes of foodstuffs (Clark, 1988). Apart from the informal commodity associations in the Central Market, traders had also formed a ggllgggizg of commodity associations. The purpose was to strengthen their capacity to deal with the external environment which influences their business activities in the market, particularly the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority, which is the 81 landlord of the market. The General Traders Association (GTA) was the collective at the Central Market which articulated the collective interests of market traders. The General Traders Association (GTA) was formed in 1979 in response to the repressive military regime of the Armed Forces revolutionary Council (AFRC). As already explained elsewhere, the AFRO took some measures that were detrimental to the survival of market traders. The AFRC sent military and police personnel to the Central Market to seize market traders' commodities, particularly imported commodities, such as milk, sugar, flour, building materials, among several others. During this period, market traders intimated that it was impossible to deal with the military and police personnel as individual commodity associations. They needed a concerted effort to articulate their collective interests to pressure the state authorities to stop the harassment of traders in the marketplace. Although the price control policy had been abandoned in pursuant of economic reforms in the regime of Structural Adjustment in 1983, the commodity associations stuck together, and their collective was alive and well. They revealed that the local government, the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority, was 'a thorn in their flesh“, as landlord, and enforcer of state policies pertaining to business activities in the market. 82 Organizational Structure of the General Traders Association Each of the commodity associations had representation in the General Traders Association. Usually, it was the aha-la ('queenmothers“, for female-dominated businesses.) and ahggg ('chiefs", for the male-dominated businesses) who represented their members. However, the queenmothers/chiefs could ask members of their associations to deputize for them, whenever necessary. In all, there were thirty commodity associations that were represented in the General Traders Association. All the representatives formed a General Council of the GTA. The main functions of the General Council were to formulate policies pertaining to the conduct of business in the market, and also to assess the impact of state (central and local government) policies on market traders' activities in the Central Market. The General Council was also charged with the responsibility to establish an Executive Committee, whose membership was chosen from.among representatives in the General Council. The Executive Committee was made up of the Chairperson, Secretary, Treasurer, and eleven other members. The function of the Executive Committee was to implement the decisions of the General Council. In 1992, when I undertook my study, the Chairperson and the Secretary, were members of the Provision Sellers Association. The provision sellers were retailers of imported food commodities. Their sources of supply of commodities included Multinational Supermarkets 83 (such as the United Trading Company, and the United African Company), as well as state supermarkets (such as the National Trading Corporation). Others also travelled outside Ghana (including Ivory Coast, Nigeria, and Togo) to purchase their commodities, but there were few traders who could afford the large capital involved in these ventures. Other members of the Executive Committee included the following associations: 1. Enamel Retailers Association: These traders sold enamels (buckets) that were made from aluminum.and plastic. They received their supplies from.the Aluminum.Products Factory in Accra, and the Chinese Plastic Factory in Takoradi in the western Region. 2. Textile Retailers Association: These traders sold textiles manufactured in Ghana and overseas. The sources of supply included multinational supermarkets, while others received theirs from indigenous Ghanaian entrepreneurs and textile dealers. There were a few'who travelled to countries in the West African sub-region, particularly Togo and the Ivory coast. However, the bulk of the supply of textiles were from.made-in Ghana textiles. These factories were located in Tema and Akosombo. 3. Route Retailers Association: Kente is the traditional clothing worn by Ghanaians. particularly the Akan people, of which the Asante are the majority. The Kente factory is at Bonwire, which is about twenty kilometers from Kumasi. Retailers of Kente receive all their suppliers from the Bonwire area. 4. Cosmetic Retailers Association: ‘Women specialize in the retail of cosmetic products. Most of their products are imported. These products include powder, pomade and skin- breaching creams. They receive supplies from supermarkets in Rumasi. They usually buy in bulk quantities, and retail them.in small quantities to customers. 5. Toffee Sellers.Association: Toffee retailers receive supplies from supermarkets in the city, and rebag them in small quantities, before selling them to customers. 6. Scarfs Retailers.Association: Scarfs are used by adult women to cover their hair in the Ghanaian society. Scarfs are imported into Ghana by the government, indigenous Ghanaian wholesalers, and multinational trading corporations. The traders retailed the scarfs apiece to customers. 7. Ear-gigg Sellers Association: These women sold imported and locally-manufactured earrings. The latter were manufactured by gold/silver smiths in the Ashanti Region, which is known for quality earring products. 8. Sgall Fish Rgtailerg Association: Fish retailing was a female-dominated activity. These women received supplies from the coastal regions of Ghana (including Central, Greater Accra, Volta, and Western regions). 9. Tailorg.Asgociation: Tailoring is a male-dominated activity. Tailors designed men's clothing, and sold them. They also undertook alterations of old clothing. 85 10. Shoe-Makers Association: Shoe-making and repairs is a male-dominated activity. These men design and produce shoes for the local market. However, the materials they used including leather, the machines, and other accessories were all imported. In addition, the shoe-makers repaired worn-out shoes for a fee, depending on the nature of the problem. The day-to-day affairs of the General Traders Association was run by the Chairperson, Secretary, and the Treasurer. There was a monthly meeting of the Executive Committee every second Sunday of the month, and preceded by the General Meeting of the Association on the last Sunday of the month. Press releases of the GTA's activities were usually made by the Secretary. Petitions were expected to be signed by other members of the Executive Committee, upon consultation with the General Council. However, the petitions I examined did not always have all the signatures of the members of the Executive Committee. So far, this section has demonstrated that market traders organize themselves for the purposes of enhancing their business activities. At the commodity sector level, market traders have organized themselves, and the leadership is charged with maintaining orderly commercial relationships among members. Taking the market as a whole, the General Traders Association, as a ggllgggigg, articulates the collective interests of market traders in dealing with their external environment, particularly the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority (KMA). 86 6. Administration of the Central Market In pre—colonial Ghana, local traditional authorities (chiefs) had a "natural“ mandate to control and regulate markets. The traditional authorities set out the rules governing the terms and conditions for the operations of markets. In return, market traders paid fees in the form of foodstuffs and commodities they were engaged in. Traders who deviated from the established norms were usually tried by chiefs in traditional courts, and whenever they were found guilty, they were sanctioned in the form of fines and/or banishment from.market trade in the locality. Disputes among traders were settled by representatives of chiefs and market traders.2 However, with colonization came control of local markets by colonial institutions. City, town, and village markets came under the control and regulation of state officials in the localities. Markets became formal sources of tax revenues for colonial authorities. Ghanaian governments, in the post-independence era, have also continued the practice of taxing market traders, as a source of revenues for local governments. The administration of the Kumasi Central Market falls under the jurisdiction of the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority (EMA). The KMA has responsibility for planning, building and providing essential physical facilities in the market for the convenience of traders and customers. The KMA is 87 FIGURE 3.4 Organizational structure of the Runasi Metropolitan Authority [1...]- ...;1 Cflq'mummu'l l Departmental Headel nunxh Ixemnnq'o Iagu cal t? Imanui ——IEEEF‘—Emfiafiar_—EEEEEEF’ 1mghunrhg'lmgflunnUg Alhurs smut ‘ , [’ amenabonmmorommnurj Lynne mmnma l mun: . l Source: Compiled from field data, 1992. 88 also expected to provide places of convenience (washrooms), drainage, water supply, clinic, and day-care centers, within the market. The EMA has a responsibility to initiate and enforce regulations pertaining to activities in the market. For instance, the KMA is supposed to open and close the market each day. Market traders and buyers were expected to operate between the hours of 6 am and 6 pm. Also, market traders and customers with communicable diaeases were not expected to enter the market during its hours of operation. The KMA is expected to arrest violators of its bye-laws and prosecute them at the City Court (Local Government Bulletin, 1988). KMA directly administers the Kumasi Central Market through the offices of the Chief Engineer, Treasury, and the Medical Officer of Health. The Chief Engineer's department is responsible for the construction of market stalls/stores, as well as their maintenance. However, in the Central Market, they do not construct additional stalls/stores due to lack of space. Only old ones that are destroyed by fire are replaced. For instance, when fire destroyed 120 stalls/sores in the market in 1987, the Chief Engineer's department replaced them'with new ones, and the refurbished stalls/stores were reallocated to the affected occupants (zhg_gigggg;, Movember 24, 1987:8). The department was also expected to repair the roofs of the stalls/stores that leaked. Failure to do so means the roofs would leak when it rained, and cause damage 89 to the traders' commodities. Other services the department was responsible for were the construction and maintenance of the drainage system, and to provide outlets for rain water to flow out of the market. Without an effective drainage system, the market would be flooded when it rained. Moreover, the Chief Engineer's department was expected to provide pipe-borne water in the market. Pipes/taps are supposed to be placed in all sections of the market, so that both traders and customers would have access to water when they were in the market. On the other hand, the Medical Officer of Health's (MOH) department was responsible for general sanitation in the market. This included arranging for its workers to sweep the market on a daily basis. The workers were expected to sweep the market at the end of the day's activities, so that by the following day, it would be ready for business activities. Market traders were expected to clean their own stalls/stores, and deposit the garbage in designated spots in the sections of the market. Conservancy laborers of MOH's department were supposed to clean the spaces within the market and collect all the garbage dumped in the designated spots. The workers were also responsible for cleaning the drainage system, or else it would be choked by garbage which may have been dumped by traders. According to the MOH's department, twenty conservancy workers were assigned on daily basis to clean a market which has a size of 9.6 hectares, and the largest in the country. 90 Any casual visitor to the Central Market would observe that workers from the Treasury Department were the most visible elements in the market. They are responsible for collecting fees from squatters and hawkers who operate in the aisles, and outside of the market. The KMA provides each revenue collector tickets to be sold to the squatters and hawkers for each day. Revenue collectors are assigned to different sections of the market where squatters and hawkers carry out their businesses. They begin their work as soon as the market gates open at 6 am, and end at 4pm, to enable them to file reports of their activities at the Treasury Department before it closed at 5 pm. Revenue collectors were expected to hand out tickets to squatters and hawkers within their zones, and demand fees from them, unless they showed receipts to the effect that they had already bought tickets, which cost C 100 per day. Revenue collectors worked in pairs; one collected the fees for the tickets while the other was expected to seize the commodities of any squatter/hawker who failed to pay for a ticket. The commodities of default traders were taken to the Treasury Department, and released when the affected trader paid the fees, plus the cost of transporting the seized commodities. Perishable commodities, such as foodstuffs were usually destroyed by the end of the day if they were not claimed early in the day. Squatters and hawkers I interviewed complained that the problem they had with the 91 revenue collectors was that the latter usually came to them too early in the morning, when they had scarcely made enough sales to be able to pay for the market fees. However, I found out that the more experienced squatters and hawkers paid market fees with money from the previous day's sales, to avoid trouble with the revenue collectors. A.Market Superintendent is charged with the responsibility to supervise day-to-day operations of the market. All KMA workers who are assigned to work in the Central Market have to report to the offices of the Market Superintendent. Also, traders and customers who had any problems in the market were supposed to report them to the Market Superintendent. The Superintendent in turn had to file reports at the City Manager's office regarding problems and complaints he/she received, as well as observations of daily activities in the market. The Market Superintendent's offices also broadcast public announcements to traders, as well as customers, through a new public address system the KMA had purchased. In sum, the Kumasi Central Market is administered and regulated by the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority. The latter is responsible for providing and maintaining the physical and social infrastructure in the market to facilitate business activities between traders and their customers. 92 Summary This chapter attempted to achieve three objectives. First, it has provided background information on Ghana, as well as the Kumasi Metropolitan Area. Second, it has demonstrated that the commercial sector in Ghana is well and alive due to the dependent nature of the Ghanaian economy. It has also shown that women predominate the commercial sector due to a combination of historical and socio-economic factors, particularly their low levels of education, and structural barriers to better opportunities in the Ghanaian society. The chapter has also demonstrated that "markets“ are important institutions in the economic and social life of Ghanaians.‘Within markets, it has been revealed that traders, particularly women, play a key role in the transportation, distribution, and retailing of commodities, activities which invariably connects them to the local Ghanaian economy as well as the global economy. Associations which market traders have formed are important institutions for the maintenance of an orderly organization of each commodity sector. But more importantly, it has been shown that the collective which represents all market traders, is critical for mobilizing the collective interests of market traders. The next chapter will place Ghana's experience of market trader-state relationship within a broader conceptual/theoretical and research contexts. CHAPTER FOUR PUTTING THE GHANAIAN EMPERIENCE INUA BROADER THEORETICAL AND RESEARCH CONTEXT Introduction The purpose of this chapter is to review literature pertaining to the relationship between market traders and state/local government institutions. First, it evaluates the relevance of conceptual and theoretical approaches to the phenomenon of the informal economy for my study. Second, past research on market traders and their relationship to state/local government institutions will be reviewed. Third, it presents the conceptual and theoretical framework for understanding market trader mobilization and articulation of their collective interests within the context of global/state restructuring processes. .A. The Informal Ecgpggy The phenomenon of market traders is often discussed under the general rubric of the “informal economy". However, the informal economy is one of the most elusive and controversial concepts in the social science literature. Since its inception, scholars have debated over its origins, meaning and scope. It is, therefore, not surprising that there is no one definition for the concept. However, researchers on the informal economy phenomenon seem.to agree 93 94 that one's definition and application of the concept is relative: that is, the form it takes and the various reasons why people engage in these activities vary from country to country. In the literature, such apparent omnibus application of the concept is illustrated by different names that have come to be associated with the informal economy: "black market", "informal sector", “second economy", “parallel economy", “underground economy“, and “the hidden sector", among several others. Thus, it would seem that the words and meanings one chooses to describe the informal economy should correspond to the problem of concern (Tripp, 1990). In this study, the problem is about the relationship between market traders and the state in Ghana. 1. Modernization/Dual Economy Perspectives It was Keith (1973) who first used the concept “informal sector“ in his study of the urban poor in Ghana. The thrust of his study was that new entrants to the urban labor market were compelled to undertake self-employment due to inadequate opportunities in the formal sector on the one hand, and their lack of skills and training, on the other. He went on to label individuals dependent on informal income opportunities as the “urban proletariat". Since the earnings received by this group of people were usually below the legal minimum.wage they were also considered underemployed. The study of informal income opportunities in Ghana raised questions about the role such activities might play, not 95 only in individuals' survival, but also in economic development. Hart (1973:61) phrased it this way: Does the "reserve army of urban unemployed and underemployed' really constitute a passive exploited majority in cities like Accra, or do their informal economic activities possess some autonomous capacity for generating growth in the incomes of the urban poor? The International Labor Organization (ILO) popularized the informal economy concept in the 1970s. In its 1972 Kenyan report, the ILO identified an employment problem which it traced to both imbalance between the growth of the labor force, urban population growth and education, and the overall growth of the economy, as well as an imbalance between people's aspirations for work, and the structure of income and opportunities available. The ILO conceptualized the urban economy of developing countries in a dualistic framework: "formal“ and “informal" sectors. It defined the informal sector activities in terms of some distinguishing characteristics: a) b) e) d) e) f) 9) ease of entry; reliance on indigenous resources; famdly ownership of enterprises; small-scale operation; labor-intensive and adopted technology; skills acquired outside the formal school system; unregulated and competitive markets (1972:3). 96 I n t e r n a t i o n a l L a b o u r O l I i c e , I 9 7 2 : 6 ) . S o u r c e : I n t e r n a t i o n a l L a b o u r O l l i c c , E m p l o y m e n t . I n c o m e s a n d E q u a l i t y : A S t r a t e g y f o r I n c r e a s i n g P r o d u c t i v e E t t t p l o y n t c n t i n K e n y a ( ( i e n e v a . S k i l l s M a r k e t s a n d o f t e n i m p o r t e d a d a p t e d a n d t r a d e l i c e n s e s ) P r o t e c t e d ( t h r o u g h U n r e g u l a t e d a n d t a r i i I s , q u o t a s c o m p e t i t i v e m a r k e t s o l t c n e x p a t r i a t e s c h o o l s y s t e m F o r m a l l y a c q u i r e d , A c q u i r e d o u t s i d e f o r m a l S c a l e o f o p e r a t i o n L a r g e S m a l l O w n e r s h i p C o r p o r a t e ' F a m i l y - o w n e r s h i p T e c h n o l o g y * C a p i t a l - i n t e n s i v e L a b o u r - i n t e n s i v e a n d E n t r y R e s o u r c e s D i l l i c u l t E a s y o n o v e r s e a s F r e q u e n t r e l i a n c e R e l i a n c e o n i n d i g e n o u s 1 C h a r a c t e r i s t i c s o f t h e F o r m a l a n d I n f o r m a l S e c t o r s C h a r a c t e r i s t i c s . F o r m a l I n f o r m a l F I G U R E 4 . 1 97 On the other hand, the features of the formal sector were conceptualized as the obverse of the foregoing characteristics: a) entry by new enterprises is difficult; b) enterprises rely frequently on overseas resources; c) corporately owned; d) large-scale operation; e) capital-intensive and often imported technology; _ f) skills acquired from the formal school system; g) regulated and protected.markets (through tariffs, quotas and trade licenses) [ILO, 1972:3]. ' I _ ' _ _ In fact, Sethuraman (1981:17) defined the informal sector as: small-scale units engaged in the production and distribution of goods and services with the primary objective of generating employment and incomes to their participants notwithstanding the constraints on capital, both physical and human, and knowhow. Due to the complex nature of these criteria for purposes of operationalization, Sethuramam.(l976:15) gave the following as conditions for membership of the informal sector: a) employment of no more than ten people; b) nonapplication of legal and administrative regulations; c) employment of family members; d) no fixed hours or days; e) no institutional loans; f) production intended for the final consumer; 9) less than six years of schooling; h) and for some activities, no use of mechanical and electrical energy; 1) the semi-permanent character of the activity. 98 Essentially, the ILO model of the informal economy attempted to draw a theoretical connection between rural- urban migration and informal income-opportunities in the urban centers of developing countries. Their argument was that new entrants to Third Werld cities create excessive demand on the urban labor market, and since “formal" sector employment is limited, rural-urban migrants cannot wait but rather create their own jobs as well as generate their own incomes through “self-employment". The ILO saw income- generating activities outside the "formal“ sector as important for labor absorption, and poverty alleviation among urban migrants in developing countries. ILO's conceptualization of the informal economy as an urban migrant phenomenon does not fully reflect the Ghanaian urban experience, since traditional residents of urban . communities have been involved in the so-called informal sector for a long time (Simms and Dumor, 1976). Second, these studies lacked analytical rigor since they only focused on the income-generating activities, without analyzing the larger economic, political, and social contexts within which they emerge. Furthermore, these studies had theoretical and conceptual problems. As Effron (1980) quizzed: Is it not possible to identify some firms that have most, but not all, of the given characteristics, but which clearly belong to the "informal" sector? A researcher has the problem of identifying which of these 99 characteristics are necessary and sufficient for the purpose of identifying the "informal" sector. 2. §§atist Perspectives A growing number of scholars have tended to place the distinctions between the "formal“ and "informal" economic activities within the context of state institutional framework governing participation in the economy. Within this school of thought, one can distinguish between those who emphasize the intended/unintended consequences of policy makers' preferences for large enterprises (Remy and Weeks, 1973), and those of the 'legalist' tradition, whose focus is largely on bureaucratic/administrative barriers that obstruct the creation and operation of self-employed enterprises (Desoto, 1989). Remy and Weeks (1973) maintain that it is the relationship of enterprises to the state that defines formal/informal enterprises, and argue further that the organizational and economic characteristics identified by Hart (1973) and the ILO (1972), respectively, are a consequence of this relationship: . t I " . 100 The formal sector is encouraged, nurtured, subsidized, and fostered by the state....it enjoys tariff and quota protection; competition in the market is frequently restricted administratively; it has privileged access to foreign exchange and is aided by low interest rates in the banking system, As a consequence, the formal sector is large-scale, uses imported capital-intensive techniques, and earns high profits. On the contrary, they revealed that: The informal sector....is largely ignored by government. It is a competitive world of small-scale enterprises where entry into the market is relatively easy and the techniques of production must be adapted to local conditions in the absence of state measures to alter relative factor prices (1973:295). According to this model, enterprises in the informal sector are defined by their relationship to the state, and by what they are not: they do not receive government attention, privileges, benefits, and recognition. The ‘legalist' perspective, while not underscoring the presmmed privileged position of formal enterprises, focuses on regulatory and legal barriers that obstruct the creation and operation of small-scale enterprises. According to this interpretation, the informal economy has shown and continues to show strong signs of adaptability, innovation, and resourcefulness, filling many of the economic niches left vacant by relatively larger enterprises, as well as providing employment opportunities, and on-the-job training and entrepreneurial skills. However, they argue that the productive potential and growth of the informal economy are 101 constrained and stunted by excessive and redundant state policies and regulations including licensing, taxation, location of businesses, labor recruitment, access to credit and training, and technology transfer (DeSoto, 1989). Azarya and Chazan (1987) have conceptualized the informal economy as a form of disengagement from the state. They define disengagement as “the tendency to withdraw from the state and keep at a distance from its channels as a‘ hedge against its instability and dwindling resource base and declining performance." As Third World economies deteriorate, they argue that citizens adopt coping strategies in the face of declining resources. In the case of Ghana, they identified four major coping responses including “suffer-manage“, "escape“, “self-enclosure“, and 'beat-the-system' strategies.‘ For the purposes of my study, I will elaborate on the “beat-the system" coping response. They define 'beat-the-system' strategy as alternative outlets for needs that remain unfulfilled by official channels, which help to reduce dependence on these channels. A parallel economy to the formal one is constructed, but feeds on the formal sector, and diverts its resources to the informal economy, and sets to manipulate the state in order to serve the needs of diverse groups of persons within its boundaries. This scheme has come to be known in Ghana as kalabule or malpractice of various sorts involving attempts to skirt existing controls or to knowingly defraud in order to maximize one's own gains. 102 In the context of disengagement, the informal economy enables people to withdraw from the state and still meet their basic needs. State reactions to disengagement also vary widely, ranging from.encouragement to policy adjustments, repression and even reconciliation to a palpable decline in state control over society. For example, state clamping down on ‘black markets' in an attempt to forestall such disengagement may lead to increased smuggling out of the country or reduced production altogether. If the state imposes production quotas and punishes producers for reducing their marketed produce, it might force them to emigrate. State-society relations are thus interlinked in a dynamic network of action and reaction which, in some instances, exacerbates existing tendencies and pushes them into more radical forms. Regarding disengagement, Azarya and Chazan (1987) explain that as it further undermines the state's ability to control resources and to exert authority, the state may use all means necessary, including coercive force, to combat such tendencies. The state may attempt to extend its grassroots control; regulate more aspects of the citizen's life, and outlaw many of the disengagement devices and impose stiff punishments on transgressors. However, the coercive reaction to disengagement is also very costly and depletes the state's meager resources. 103 Finally, they argue that the state may also react to disengagement in a constructive way, by introducing reforms that would increase its efficiency, enhance its penetrative capacity and re-create the attractiveness of its channels. Implicit in the refomm strategy is the desire to create conditions that would make existing forms of disengagement unnecessary and obsolete. But the opposite result is obtained when the government, in order to implement its reform.programs makes increasing use of force and lets the coercive aspects of reform.implementation overshadow the reform per se. Reform programs often ignore and compete with ongoing survival strategies, and the state is mostly preoccupied with imposing restrictions, breaking opposition and punishing transgressors who standin the way of its reforms. The paradox that emerges is that on the one hand, the reforms try to resuscitate state-society relations, while on the other, daily activities focus on quashing strikes and repressing opposition. By overlooking actual survival strategies in the society, the reform programs could ironically detach the state itself from society, and demonstrate little understanding of ongoing processes in the society, and have poor chances of success (Azarya and Chazan, 1987; Azarya, 1988). 104 3. Global System/Dependency Perspectives a) Petty Commodity Production Marxist and Neo-Marxist scholars have been critical of the dualist/modernization models of development and their conceptualization of the informal economy. They argue that at any one time, there is only one economy, determined by the dominant mode of production. Within a capitalist Isociety, there may exist pre-capitalist and/or petty commodity modes of production, but in the Marxist framework, these do not indicate duality because they are effectively dominated by capitalism. In petty commodity production, the producer owns the means of production, and.may work alone, with apprentices, or side by side with hired laborers. Because of the incomplete separation of capital and labor, there can be no firm line demarcating an informal sector. Rather, there is a continuum of productive activities ranging from the simplest artisan-producer to large capitalist enterprises (Bose, 1984; Lewin, 1985). However, Marxists envision that petty commodity production will inevitably disappear as the dominant capitalist system.expands (Lenin [1917] 1966:27-28), but Lenin's generalization that large-scale industry will completely squeeze out small enterprises is increasingly being called into question (Lewin, 1985: 130-131). In fact, small-scale/petty commodity production, even if it is 105 destined for eventual disappearance, will continue to be part of the Third WOrld economic reality for some time to come because of their structural dependence on the global system (McCormick, 1988). b) Global Economic Crises and Restructuring Other scholars have conceptualized the informal economy by locating it within the context of the restructuring processes associated with the general impact of the global economic crises. Portes and walton (1989:87) defined the informal sector as including “all income-producing activities outside of the formal sector wages and social security payment". The objective of Portes and his associates has been to explore the extent to which informal labor processes function to subsidize capital accumulation in both the periphery and the core countries of the global-system (Portes and Sassen-Koob, 1987; Castells and Portes, 1989; Benton, 1986). Basically, Portes et al. view informalization as a process: The informal economy is not an individual condition but as a process of income-generation characterized by one central feature: it is unregulated by the institutions of society in a legal and social environment in which similar activities are regulated (1989:12) 106 Portes et a1. argue that the source of the differences between the wages of core capitalism and peripheral capitalism.could be traced to the structure of peripheral economies which invariably facilitates profit maximization by keeping labor costs at a minimum, The informal sector is supposed to facilitate this process at two levels. First, it subsidizes part of the costs of capitalist enterprises in peripheral countries, enabling them to enforce comparatively low wages on its own labor. The basic needs of formal sector workers are partially met by goods and services produced and distributed more cheaply using unpaid and paid informal labor. Moreover, parallelling the mechanism.of subsistence- transfer, but in a far more diversified and complex.manner, capitalists are able to exploit not only the work-energy of the worker, but that of his/her kin, neighbors, and friends as well (Portes, 1989). In fact, within the core of the world-system, especially in the United States, studies have shown how capitalists have resorted to informal production strategies to cut down costs of production, in order to meet the challenges of the global economic crisis, as well as maximize capital accumulation. Sassen-Koob (1989:60) has demonstrated that in the city of New York, for example, a large portion of the construction, apparel, electronic and furniture industries are carried out on an informal basis, and heavily dependent on immigrant labor. 107 c) Dependent/Uneven Development and the Enclave Economy Critical to my analysis is an understanding of foreign capital penetration in the political economies of peripheral countries. According to the dependent/uneven development perspectives, the economy of Ghana, other African and Third world nations have been historically conditioned by their relationship to other more powerful and dominant economies. Thus the interdependence of such economies assumes contrasting forms of dominance and dependency, to the extent that dependent nations develop as mere reflection of the expansion of dominant nations, and become underdeveloped as a consequence of their subjective relationships (Santos, 1970). Historically, uneven development assumes a relationship among nations of the world based on exploitation and unequal development. In this respect, it starts with the assumption that development and underdevelopment are integral parts of a global system. The global economy itself is seen as a total system of which Third Werld nations are ipgo facto, subsystems. Modern economies, from the 15th century onwards have developed within a global economy following the laws of peripheral capitalist development. According to Booth (1975:15), relationships of dependency are essentially asymmetric because: 108 development of parts of the system occurs at the expense of other parts:....it is the combination of inequalities plus the transfer of resources from underdeveloped to developed countries which explains inequality, deepens it, and transforms it into a necessary and structural element of the world economy. Simms and Dumor's (1976) ”enclave economy” phenomenon provided an excellent insight into the structural position of market traders within the context of Ghana's dependent status in the global economy. They defined the ‘enclave economy' as "an economy which is a direct response to the economic penetration of peripheral nations by industrial countries in search of raw'materials, as well as a market for finished products from these countries." According to the enclave economy model, at one end of the economic spectrum are modern/formal enterprises, including multinational investments, and local capitalist ventures. At another end are potential consumers. Therefore, what the enclave economy does is not only to link the two sectors of the economy, but also intermediate between the potential producers and consumers. Sanjek and Sanjek (1976) have categorized market traders in the enclave economy into four analytically distinct groups for the purposes of analysis. They identified: a) working-class traders who act in their capacity as petty commodity producers involved in food preparation and processing, along with other similar activities; 109 : 1 ‘ b) small traders who are relatively stationary, selling commodities at fixed locations; c) middle-class traders who have higher levels of capital and own larger stocks of commodities; d) business-owners who have relatively larger capital, employ labor, lend out money to other businesses, and also invest in other income-generating ventures. So far, I have attempted to demonstrate that there are varied conceptual and theoretical explanations of the phenomenon of the informal economy in the development literature. Although some aspects of market trade such as size of enterprise, ease of entry, and acquisition of skills outside formal institutions, correspond with the informal sector characteristics as articulated by the modernization/dualistic framework, market trade also has formal sector characteristics. These include obtaining license for operation, as well as operating within a built environment defined by state regulations. Also, market traders have linkages to large-scale enterprises in the formal sector, as commission-sellers and sometimes as competitors. Thus, the modernization/dualistic framework needs to be modified to capture the complexities and dynamics of market trade activities in developing countries, particularly Ghana. The statist and global/dependency perspectives serve as backdrop for my analysis of the relationship between the 110 state and market traders in Ghana. The statist perspective demonstrates the policy and regulatory environment within which market traders operate, as well as its concomitant effects on market traders. Clearly, the global-dependency perspectives throw more light on the historical and structural factors which affect peripheral economies, and the strategic position of market traders within the enclave economy. As intermediaries of indigenous and foreign producers and local censumers, market traders are major players in the political economy of peripheral countries. Hence, the relationship between the state and market traders in Ghana, should be understood within the larger context of Ghana's dependence on the global economy, and its ramifications for state control/regulation of the domestic economy, especially market trader activities. B. Previous Research on.Market Traders versus the £122 Previous research indicate that the relationship between market traders and the state in Africa, and other Third world societies, is generally marked by conflict. One of the most celebrated accounts of the conflict relationship between market traders and the state in the West African sub-region was the “Aba Riots" or Ibo "Women's war“ of 1929 in Nigeria. A British colonial administrator's 111 decision to count women and their property sparked fears among women that they would be taxed. Word spread quickly through trading networks, and tens of thousands of women protested. Once they had won written assurance that they would not, in fact, be taxed, they continued mass marches, and local “disturbances" against regional colonial administrators, for failing to recognize women's political organizations. eventually, the police and army turned on the protesters, killing fifty, and wounding fifty more (Ifeka- Moller, 1975; Van Allen, 1976; Johnson, 1978; Sacks, 1982; Wipper, 1982). Market queens in Southern Nigeria continued to lead women anti-colonial activities through the 1940s (Johnson, 1982). Gracia Clark's (1988) Market Traders and the State documents instances of hostility and tension between specific sets of traders and government functionaries in several countries across four continents. In the case of Ghana, Clark discussed the conflict between market traders and the Rawlings' state when the latter imposed price controls for local foodstuffs in Kumasi, (Ghana) in the 1980s. In the process, market traders who rebelled against the new policy were harassed in the form.of public humiliation and physical assault by the police and military personnel. In Tanzania, two studies have revealed the tension/conflict between the state and traders (particularly 112 in the informal economy or magendo). First, Kerner (1988) has shown that during the crisis of the 1980s, the Tanzanian state launched two concurrent campaigns aimed at restructuring commodity distribution in the society. The “war Against Economic Sabotage" which was initiated in 1983 was a state crackdown on large-scale black market racketeers trading in luxury imported items, foreign currency, and locally-produced commodities. The second program.'Human Resources Deployment Act (October, 1983), entailed the detention, registration, and resettlement of thousands of urban jobless persons along with traders, vendors, workers, and housewives, on state plantations in rural areas. The root of the problem seemed to have been state conception of “hard work" which was ideologically defined as "activities that were directly related to food production in the rural areas". Consequently, state legislations were designed to convert the urban unemployed, the underemployed, and traders into rural casual laborers. 113 Tripp's (1990) The Urban Informal Economy and the State in Tanzania, documents the struggles of ordinary Tanzanian citizens to overcome state control of formal economic activities. She argued that the more the state tried to adopt interventionist posture, the less it was able to affect change in the direction it intended. She saw the noncompliance of Tanzanians in the form.of private small- scale economic activities, contrary to state policy, as a testament to the capacity of Tanzanians to resist policies that infringed on their ability to carry out informal income-generating activities. In conclusion, Tripp argued that the informal economy may have played a critical role as an internal factor that allowed Tanzania to embark on a program of economic refonms and austerity measures. Babb (1988) studied the repression and harassment of marketers in Peru in the 1980s when the country was experiencing severe economic crisis. Two related and pressing problems faced the Peruvian state: rising food prices and a proliferation of urban marketers and street vendors. The state, in an attempt to provide affordable food to the middle class, and the masses of the people for political reasons, scape-goated food retailers who seemed to be at the lowest end, and the weakest in the chain of distribution of commodities in the society. Regulation of petty traders took several forms including increased taxes. health/medical certification, and relocation from street 114 trade. She indicates that ambulantees marched in peaceful protests against government initiatives to relocate them to undesirable and even dangerous locations. However, they were met violently by the National Guard, who showed very little regard for women and their children. The most important revelation of the study was that the Peruvian state and its functionaries failed to appreciate the broader international context of the Peruvian economic crises in the 1980s, and its implication for Peru's food prices. Peru, like other Third world nations are dependent on the global economy, hence the availability of commodities and their distribution within peripheral societies are contingent upon the "health“ of the national and global economies, and not petty traders, who contribute to the production and reproduction of labor within the global system. Freidberg's (1991) Market women and Sgage Viglgnce in west Africa, analyzes the tension between market women traders and the state from a feminist perspective. She states: state violence toward market women is clearly not arbitrary. It is a manifestation of a struggle for control over women's income, labor, food, and sex—- a struggle, in other words, over the basic means of production and reproduction (1991:2). She argues that since the state apparatus is dominated primarily by men, state violence against women, in particular market women, is an attempt to deny women the right to economic autonomy, with the aim of pushing them 115 back to depend on men in society. She points out that African states have staked a great deal of legitimacy on cheap urban food provided primarily by cheap female labor, both on the farm, and in the market (Guyer, 1987a, 1987b). When this legitimacy is threatened, men, she argues, in the State simply cannot afford to mind their own business, and let market women mind theirs. The review in this section has shown that the conflict relationships between market traders and states in peripheral countries stem from.numerous sources including conditions induced by the dependent positions of peripheral states within the global capitalist system, as well as internal dynamics such as class and gender inequality. C. Human-Social Agent! and Collective Action Agency is the means of exerting power and influence to bring about change whether at the level of the individual, the household or larger collectivities, like networks, and groups. Agency, therefore, has to do with sources of‘ influence and directions of power (Strathem, 1987:23). Thus, the basic questions that need to be asked are: What mechanisms do people have at their disposal in influencing others, and in shaping the contours of the everyday world around them? What are their capabilities to affect their world and the actions of others? Much of the contemporary research on agency and 116 activism. has often been associated with the Marxist tradition. After all, Marx himself was concerned with working-class consciousness, mobilization and social change. Marxists have for a long time established a connection between class interests and collective action. They argue that individuals who share the same "life situation", by sharing the same relations of production, have a similar stake in “contemporary bourgeois society.“ They are also affected similarly by events that enhance, sustain, or erode this material stake. Those who are similarly situated and affected, constitute a collectivity, known as a “class“. Members of the same class situation have a common set of economic and political interests. Individuals who make up a class are "objectively" related to one another because of the interests they share. The incumbents of class positions have a predisposition to act collectively and conflictually, a process which is "given and conditioned“ by the structural position itself (Davis, 1991: 20). While the classical Marxist model of collective action based on class identification is profoundly illuminating, it focuses on collective action occurring inside the workplace, and therefore it is not easily applicable to collective action occurring outside the place of work. It conceptualizes 'class' in terms of productive property. It is the common position that people occupy in relationship to the means of production--owning or not 117 owning productive property; controlling or not controlling the labor process--that determines their common interests and their common orientation to political action. Class formation and class conflict are both engendered by relations of production. What is problematic about this for my study is the observed fact that groups in the enclave economy, particularly market traders, often form.and fight along lines that have little to do with productive property. These groups are not “classes" in the Marxist sense, since they are engendered by relations of distribution and consumption, not by relations of production. Neo-Marxist interpretations of collective action have tended to focus on urban-based social movements. Castells (1978; 1983; 1987) has attempted to integrate the ideas of class, ideology and disposition, as he relates them to the processes of urbanization, uneven development, and urban social movements. His unique contribution has been his ability to have conceptually and empirically linked constituency movements to class structures through the notion of urban space ts medium, Space, he reminds us, is as much a material dimension of production as are land, labor and capital, for the ways in which space itself is appropriated to produce them» Castells further explains that it is how people experience the gggtttttgt and ggtttg;_that flow from the spatial form associated with the city that 118 leads to urban-based social movements. In such cases, these need not be class-based, since they are more likely to emerge from what a group sharing a common residential area perceives as a threat to its cultural identity and/or neighborhood autonomy. The form these non-class movements take in response to pressures from the class structure, he argues, are contingent rather than determined. What is crucial, he stresses, is that whatever the value or interest or goal at the base of a non-class movement, it has been precipitated by the workings of a particular mode of production on the shapes of people' lives (Kling and Posner, 1991). Overall, Castells is moderate in his conclusions. Urban movements are not the new historical actors creating social change, nor the pivotal source of alternative social forms (1983:319). Secondly, he saw urban movements not as agents of structural social change, but symptoms of resistance to the social domination, which in the process may have major effects on cities and societies (1983:329). D. Market Trader Aggociational Activity Market traders generally form.associations, which have been conceptualized as voluntary associations. Earlier studies on voluntary associations in West Africa conceptualized them as mechanisms for helping migrants to adjust to urban life. They were seen as surrogate familiar 119 institutions in the rapid urbanization processes (Llyod, 1959; Little, 1965, 1973; wallerstein, 1966). Simms and Dumor (1976) studied associational activity among women in the urban enclave economy of Ghana. They highlighted the economic, and social significance of associational activity for the survival of market traders. They revealed that market women's associations enabled them to create institutions of mutual support such as credit, networking, and general welfare of their members. This study was quite important in that unlike earlier studies which associated voluntary associations with urban migrants, they saw them as mechanisms devised by market traders, especially market women, to survive in the marketplace, within the context of lack of resources and support from state/local government institutions. Simms Hamilton's (1967) Urban Social Differentiation and Membership Recruitment among Selected Voluntaty Assgciations in Accra, Ghana revealed some interesting facts which are pertinent to the present study. She demonstrated that voluntary associations are ggt substitutive of familial institutions but rather additive. That is, the functions they perform within urban structures are not meant to compete with, or replace the functions of social institutions such as the family. Instead, they supplement the functions of familial institutions within the context of the urban environment. 120 These associations provide economic and social benefits for their members. They may provide economic support in the form of providing capital for members to start their business, or to enlarge the trade they are already engaged in, by providing the necessary capital. A typical form of economic support is the provision of working capital. This is done by holding meetings once a week, at which a collection is taken. All the traders present hand over as much money as they can afford, and their contributions are recorded in the book supplied to each member for this purpose. The officials receiving this money also have a list of the associations's members, in order of seniority, depending on the date on which they have joined. When the collection is finished, all the money is given to the member whose name has the first place on the list; the following week, it is given to the second, and the third, until every member of the group has received a contribution. This system provides a useful alternative to negotiating a private loan from.money-lenders, or from the public and private banks (Little, 1973:52). Members of market associations may also buy in bulk, which would help them to obtain produce and commodities at relatively cheaper prices, by saving the overheads of buyers. Others may take steps to ensure direct access to supplies of commodities in which their members trade. The social functions of these market associations are 121 also quite significant. They provide welfare for their members and their families, when they are bereaved or sick. They may also contribute to the funeral expenses of a deceased member. The market associations may also regulate trading practices of their members, in an effort to prevent under- cutting by shrewd members. Any member found under-cutting may be brought before the officials of the association, and disciplined, which could result in the expulsion of the member from the association. These informal social control mechanisms are designed to ensure healthy competition among members who trade in the same commodities. While these economic and social functions of market trader associations are critical for their members survival in the marketplace, the focus of my study is the relationship between these associations and their external environment, particularly state/local government institutions. Activism of market traders may be attributed to their commonality of interest and identity, as well as their perceived threat (real or imagined) of the policy/regulatory environment on their survivability in the marketplace. The policy and regulatory environment refers to “central/local government policies and regulations spelling out rules regarding licensing, labor hiring practices, location, taxation, and general operations of public markets.“ Self- 122 employed workers with similar business interests may mobilize to deal with regulations and micro-policies that affect their businesses. The effects of the regulatory and policy environment have been the basis for mobilizing trade groups (Harrod, 1987). Market traders also constitute a community of tenants. In fact, local market structures are under the jurisdiction and supervision of state/local government institutions. Thus, market traders who occupy public markets engage in a landlord—tenant relationship. Much as tenants in urban neighborhoods may mobilize to demand better utilities and services from their landlords, as well as articulate other concerns pertaining to their occupancy, so could market traders organize to express their concerns regarding increases in their rents, and lack of relevant facilities that could enhance their business operations in the public markets such as safety and security, clinics, day-care centers, and public places of conveniences. In some cases, the commonality of interest may be spontaneous, based on characteristics which provide a sense of collective economic and/or social identity (Portes and Borcos, 1988). In others, the commonality may come into being in response to a situation which adversely affects the interests of a wide range of self-employed workers. For example, self-employed workers in various trades formed themselves into a single organization to oppose their eviction from an area which the city authorities (in 123 Chandigarh, India) wanted to use for other purposes. (Sarin, 1979). Similarly, in Ahmedabad, India, petty traders and street vendors in the central business district (CBD) got together to fight police harassment and won a major concession: that they could not be barred from selling on the streets in that area unless the local authorities provided an equally attractive alternative location (Sebstad, 1982). Lessinger's (1985) Nobody Is Here to Ygll At Me: Political Activism Among Petty Retail Traders In An Indian Qtty provides some of the conditions which pave the way for political mobilization among market traders: 1. In cities, petty retail trade is comparatively secure in terms of income and steady employment. This security, in comparison to other types of jobs, makes trading an attractive occupation, drawing in workers from.other occupations, and swelling the number of traders and market places. Such security, he argues makes trading an occupation worth defending through political means, and the ability to organize becomes an important component of job security; 2. The ability of traders to monopolize the sale of particular kinds of goods such as fresh foodstuffs because their sale is too risky and labor-intensive to involve the formal sector. This kind of monopoly gives traders a potent political'weapon if they should decide to strike; 3. Relations of production and social relations surrounding marketing which create a physical concentration of traders 124 and impose on them.a high degree of cooperation. Unlike many other informal sector workers, traders are often concentrated, cheek by jowl, in congested market places. This concentration often demands a high degree of cooperation among market traders; 4. Conflicts between traders and state/local authorities which can be perceived clearly by participants as instances of class conflict. Disputes over the right to sell on vacant r public land are particularly clear examples, but official complaints that markets are dirty, unhealthy or unsightly can also be seen as aspects of class conflict. Disputes which threaten to eradicate traders' livelihood in marketing are most likely to mobilize traders; 5. The existence of a political culture which legitimates popular protests and offers some avenues for conflict resolution. As Portes and Walton (1976), Gutkind (1973) and Sandbrook (1977), all point out, the political potential of workers has to be judged against the background of the local political culture. Does that culture offer ideological justification for purposes of protest from below? Gender is also an important unifying factor for mobilization among market traders. women in most Third Werld societies, particularly Ghana, predominate commercial and distribution sector activities. Market trader grassroots mobilization is often conceptualized as a strategy by women to protect and defend their collective interests in response to attempts by state/local government institutions to 125 regulate and control their lives and businesses. (Ewusi, 1987:14; Greenstreet, 1981; Date-Baah, 1986; Parpart and Staudt, 1989). Pare women in Tanzania rioted to protest the levying of a graduated income tax in the 1940s. The women organized a 25-mile march to the district headquarters and, once there, stoned colonial officials, demanded settlement of the matter, and created so much trouble that a compromise had to be settled (O'Barr, 1976). In the case of Ghana, Accra Market women withdrew their services until state officials reinstated their control over pricing and the market in 1982. Thus, gender is a critical factor for mobilizing African, as well as Ghanaian market women in negotiating state institutions, and serves as a basis for political solidarity among market women. However, in situations where men participate in local markets as well, they provide support to the cause of market traders because of their identification collectively as traders vis-a-vis state/local government institutions. E. FRAIENORE FOR.UNDERSTANDINGIMAREET TRADER.ACTIVISI IN GHANA EITHIN THE CONTEXT OF GLOBALZSTATE RESTRQQQQQ PROCE SE The premise of the present investigation is that market traders mobilize to articulate their collective interests. Their ultimate goal is survival in the marketplace. It is the contention of the author that market trader activism in the period under study (1983-1992) should 126 be situated within a broader context of the effects of global restructuring on peripheral countries, particularly Ghana. Global Restructuring2 Global restructuring is defined as ”attempts to reform capitalist structures/institutions in response to crises within the global/world system". According to Castells and Henderson (1987:l), the world economy is undergoing a process of global restructuring that redefines capital-labor relationships, and the role of the state, while furthering the asymmetrical interdependency of economic functions across national boundaries. The process manifests itself differently in different contexts, thus triggering diverse social and political conflicts upon which its outcome will ultimately depend. For the purposes of my study, I‘will focus on Sub-Saharan Africa, particularly Ghana. Sub-Saharan Africa experienced substantial debt crises in the early part of the 1970s, but it was until the 1980s that they became major issues in international relations. Total Sub-Saharan debt was about US$156bn at the end of 1989. However, most of these countries are highly dependent on imports and manufactured goods, oils, services, food, and capital goods. They purchase imports with foreign exchange from two main sources: exports of a narrow range of commodities with volatile world market prices; and foreign grants, loans, and investment. In 1980-1989, their commodity 127 export prices fell by 18 percent compared with import prices, and export volume fell by 15 percent. Net capital transfers--disbursements minus repayments--also declined in real terms (allowing for inflation) after 1981. Higher aid failed to compensate for lower transfer from the IMF, export credit agencies, banks, import suppliers, and foreign investors. Though rising in the period 1986-1989, real net transfers in 1989 were 20 percent below the 1980-83 annual average. These development reduced annual imports by 32 percent of their US$ value during the 1980-1989 period. On a real per capita basis, imports in 1989 were at or below the levels of 1985 (IMF Survey, June 1988; UN, 1988; WGrld Bank, 1989). Since the early part of the 1980s, Ghana's debt crises, and crises with debt service payments culminated in the imposition of Structural Adjustment Program by the WOrld Bank, and the International Monetary Fund, under the general rubric of state restructuring, with the aim.of redressing distortions in the Ghanaian economy. State RegtructuriAgf State restructuring is defined as "adjustments/changes in the structures/functions of state institutions in response to fiscal crisis emanating from the global economic restructuring processes'. The emphasis on state restructuring under Structural Adjustment was predicated on the fact that the source of Ghana's economic malaise was a 128 direct result of state-led development planning and management of the economy. This observation was in sharp contrast to Post-war development theorizing in the 19503 and 1960s, which stressed that state apparatus could be used to foster development and change in developing economies. The role of the Ghanaian state, for example, was to accelerate industrialization, to modernize agriculture, and provide the infrastructure necessary for modernization. In addition, since the private sector was small and relatively weak, the state became the major employer of many qualified personnel in the public sector. By the early 1960s, there were more than one hundred state parastatals in Ghana. They increased to a total of 235, of which the state had majority holding in 181, which provided employment for approximately fifty percent of labor force in Ghana (Ada, 1989:305). Furthermore, the Ghanaian state had substantial role in economic development. It initiated development plans and mobilized resources to provide the basic infrastructure for national development. The major weakness of this strategy, however, was that development projects were dependent on the country's major exports: cocoa, timber, and minerals, which‘were often affected by expansion and contraction in the core economies in Western Europe, North America, and the Pacific Rim” State restructuring in Ghana has been based on three principles: reducing the role of the state relative to the private sector, "getting the prices right", and opening the 129 economy to foreign trade and investment (Wbodward, 1992). For the purposes of this investigation, I will focus on the first one, pertaining to attempts to "roll back" the state. Reduction of the role of the state under economic restructuring has taken three main forms: restricting the level of state expenditure as a share of national income, shifting production and provision of services from the public to the private sector; and relaxing regulations affecting transactions in private markets. State expenditure cuts are deliberate shifts away from the concept of the state as an economic agent and social provider, and towards more minimalist view of its role in society. The irony is that at a critical time when most people, especially the poor, need social protection under Structural Adjustment, the state attempts to divest itself of responsibility for economic developments affecting the welfare of the population. This implies an erosion in the accountability of the state for the consequences of adjustment policies. This approach leads to contraction of public sector expenditures on welfare, education, and health. It has been estimated that women and children, who are the major consumers of welfare and public sector services, suffer most when state services become contracted (Afsher and Dennis, 1992). As if expenditure cuts were not enough, the state also responds to fiscal deterioration by resorting to the tax base to generate increased revenues. These include increased 130 individual and corporate direct taxes, as well as taxes on domestic goods and services. This is understandable giving the fact that, under the regime of adjustment, the fiscal crisis of the state is exacerbated by the fact that a greater proportion of revenues from.exports is used to service debts accrued from international and bilateral institutions. Local Government Restructurtgg State restructuring processes have also affected local government institutions. Local governments have been reconstituted and restructured in a move to make them.more responsible to their local communities. It is a strategy on the part of the central government to reduce state expenditures for public services. Accordingly, decentralization of local government administration has been accompanied by increased roles and functions for local communities. In the pre-Adjustment period local government institutions tended to depend on central government transfers to promote community development. However, the fiscal constraints imposed on the state by the Structural Adjustment Program.has placed a greater burden on local governments to generate revenues from the local community. Local governments, it is argued would tend to use the strategies of the central government to generate incomes from their local communities: expenditure cuts, and restoration of the tax base to generate revenues. However, 131 expenditure cuts often lead to reduced community/public services, as well as the maintenance of existing physical and social infrastructure in the local community. GlobalZStateZLocal Government Restructuring and Market Trgder Activism Market traders are affected by global/state/local government restructuring processes: First, market traders are dependent on the global market for sources of commodities for their businesses. Trade liberalization and removal of price controls create opportunities for traders to obtain imported commodities, as well as sell them at prices determined by the market, as opposed to the dictates of state officials. However, policies associated‘with state restructuring such as retrenchment of workers in the formal sector increases mass poverty, unemployment, and underemployment. As a result, the supply of labor in the informal sector increases, and thus reduces real informal sector incomes, including incomes from retail activities in the market. Market traders, most of whom are women, and consumers of welfare and public sector services, are affected by expenditure cuts and contraction in public welfare services. In addition, SAP policies such as liberalization of prices, devaluation, and removal of government subsidies from commodity prices, contribute to higher cost of living. Market traders, like other Ghanaians. are impacted by the 132 higher cost of living as they have to pay for higher schools fees, cost of food, health care, transportation, and energy. State/local government policies designed to generate incomes through increased taxes also affect Ghanaians in general, but market traders in particular. These include increased income taxes, rents for market occupancy, licenses, and basic rates. Local government expenditure cuts and contraction in public services would affect the provision of, and maintenance of infrastructure, including market facilities in the local community. Under these conditions, it is argued that market traders, as human-social agents will mobilize to articulate their collective interests vis-a-vis state/local government institutions, to survive in the marketplace. Their collective interests would center around control of their incomes: to resist state/local government income-generating strategies, to demand accountability for activities of the local government officials, as well as to seek improvements in the physical and social infrastructure in the market, to enhance their business activities. The State Agtinst Natigg Dilemma‘ The foregoing framework taps into the theoretical discussion of the state against the nation dilemma in the periphery of the world system. One of the classical contributions to the dialectical relationship between the state and the nation/civil society 133 is Antonio Gramsci (1971:210-276). In Gramsci's view, the state encapsulates ”political society" and represents the moment of force and coercion, while "civil society“ is the complex network of educational and ideological institutions in which leadership is more important than force. Most of the institutions that exert direct domination are controlled by the state, whereas civil society encompasses the bodies and solidarities usually termed "internal and private" (Macciocchi, 1974). Gramsci (1971:209) wrote that “between the economic structure and the state with its legislation and coercion stands civil society". In the periphery, however, the state as a phenomenon is not an independent variable. State forms are constantly created, reproduced, maintained, and modified. These processes of reproduction and change are intertwined with the historical evolution of the particular society and culture within which the state functions (Trouillot, 1990:19). Peripheral states are subjected to many inherent tensions, and historically, instability is inherent in the social structure of peripheral capitalism (Alavi, 1982). It stems from the very dependency that characterizes these societies (Amin, 1980:17). Peripheral societies are characterized by a permanent tension between the centripetal forces of the state, and the centrifugal forces inherent in dependency (Trouillot, 1990:23). In the case of Ghana, the disjuncture between the state and the civil society has been exacerbated by global restructuring processes, particularly 134 the Structural Adjustment Program, The Structural Adjustment Program tends to pit the state against the civil society, and the dialectics lead to change in state structure, and the (re)emergence of a meaningful civil society. mums PROPOS ITIONS Based on the foregoing framework, the working propositions for the study were: 1. It is expected that global restructuring processes ‘will redefine the structure, functions, and sources of revenue of state and local government institutions. Consequently, state/local government institutions will adopt fiscal policies for increasing revenue—generation from their communities, particularly market traders, as well as adopt austere measures to conserve financial resources to the detriment of community service needs; 2. It is expected that conflict between local communities, particularly market traders, and state/local government institutions will be engendered by the latter's fiscal policies for revenue-generation, lack of accountability for local government officials, as well as declining conditions of physical and social infrastructure in the community, especially in the marketplace; 3. It is expected that market traders, as human-social agents, will mobilize to articulate their collective interests/concerns vis-a-vis state/local government 135 restructuring processes that affect their activities. Thus, market trader activism.would be aimed at protesting and resisting state/local government fiscal policies, holding local government officials accountable, s well as demanding the maintenance of the physical and social infrastructure in the marketplace, to enhance their business activities. FIGURE 4.2 RELATIONSHIP BETHEEN GLOBAL RESTRUCTURING AND COMMUNITY ACTIVISM luommtmmmmmmum: .Redefines Capital-Labor Relationships .Redetines the role of state in development V. Eymramnmmnmnm ’ some namummomm nmumnm INSTITUTIONS .Fiscal Retrenchlent \ [ .P .P;:::::n .florld Bank ,zur .ODA .Manpower Retrenchment .Privatization .Decentralization .Devaluation .Nev Tax Revenues J, JLOCAL amnmxmmum: .Decentralization .Fiscal Retrencnaent- .Hanpover Retrenchaent .New Tax Rev.nues ' [ _ CHAPTERFIVE RESUME OF RESEARCH PROCEDURES This chapter contains a resume of the manner in which the field research was conducted, as well as a concise explanation of the methods and techniques employed in the collection and analysis of data for the study. The methods I used to gather data for the study included, interviews, documentary/archival research, survey, and personal observations. The research was conducted from January to June 1992. I was assisted in my fieldwork by five Ghanaians, made up of three women and two men. Each of these assistants had a high school diploma, and was teaching in local public schools in Kumasi. The criteria for the selection of these assistants were familiarity with the city's people, fluency in the local Asante Twi language, and another Ghanaian ethnic language, as well as research experience. I was personally raised in Kumasi, and so I was familiar with the urban informal economy, particularly petty trading, from a personal experience: my family was involved in informal income-generating activities. My mother, in particular, began her work life as a seamstress, and later through friendship networks acquired a 'passbook' to sell textiles on commission basis with the United African Company (UAC), a British multinational company. Later, she landed a job as a bottle-collecting subcontractor for the Kumasi 136 137 Brewery, which was owned and operated by the United African Company. She also rented a stall at the Kumasi Central Market for selling second-hand clothing. My parents have lived in the city for more than forty years, and I had lived in Kumasi for twenty years. I was fortunate to draw on these experiences in carrying out my fieldwork., The target groups for my research were members and leaders of the General Traders Association, and officials of the local government institution, the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority. 1. Members and Leaders of Market Associations The major challenge I faced when I arrived in Kumasi in January 1992 was how to get in touch with members and leaders of market trader associations in the city. I went to the District Office of the Department of Cooperatives for names of market associations in Rumasi. Unfortunately, the records at this office did not contain names of market associations. Fortunately, after reading the local newspaper, the Pioneer, I came across an article on a petition submitted to the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority (EMA) by members of the General Traders Association (GTA) in the Kumasi Central Market. The petition was signed by the leaders of the GTA. I wrote down the name of the secretary of the association and followed up on him at the Central Market. I introduced myself to him, and made him.aware that I was 138 interested in researching into the problems they had with the EMA. Initially he was taken aback, and later, after I had developed a rapport with him, he revealed that, actually he was quite apprehensive of my motives in conducting the research. He thought I was a "secret" agent of the state. He revealed on my first encounter with him that apart from.the petition I followed up, he had copies of other petitions the association had previously submitted to the EMA regarding several issues the market traders were concerned about. These revelations gave me hints that I could begin my research from.there, and gradually broaden my network to other traders in the market. On the second encounter, the secretary of the GTA introduced me to other leaders of the association, and explained to them my interest in studying the association, and its relationship to the EMA. This step was quite important, in the sense that it ensured the cooperation of the leaders, who later introduced me to members of the association. For the uninitiated to the nuances of Ghanaian, particularly Akan culture, just bumping into people in the public place, and asking them questions about their personal and business lives, could breed suspicion and non- cooperation, as well as contempt for the intruder. From the records of the GTA, I realized that the association was the largest single ggttggttygitttgt of market associations in the Central Market, as well as in the city. The GTA was the mouthpiece of the traders in the 139 Eumasi Central Market. It had an active membership of about 20,000 traders. Eighty percent of the members of GTA were women, while the rest (20%) were men. After examining the files of the association, I had a pretty good sense of its goals/objectives, as well as the rules/norms governing its day-to-day operations. These were spelt out in the association's constitution. I was formally introduced to members of the association at their first monthly meeting in January 1992, at the Ghana National Culture Center in Eumasi, which had enough room for members, since meeting in the Central Market is virtually impossible due to the small sizes of the market stalls/stores. The meeting was preceded by a prayer, and the president cf the association introduced the agenda for the meeting. Among the items on the agenda was an introduction of the researcher. Since I had already been introduced to him.by the secretary previously, he knew my mission and made sure the members understood what I was doing, and therefore, appealed to them to cooperate with.my research. I was given the opportunity to speak to the group briefly. I expressed my gratitude for the opportunity to meet them, and their ‘willingness to cooperate with me in the research. However, I took the opportunity to outline the pertinent aspects of my research, and gave them assurance that the information they provide would be used only for academic purposes, and would be kept confidential. By the time the second monthly meeting arrived in 140 February 1992, I had successfully selected my fieldwork assistants, and had provided them.some background training/orientation to the research processes. I took them to the meeting, and by permission of the president, I introduced them to the members of the association who were at the meeting. This step was important because the assistants were younger persons who were later going to be sent out to gather information from relatively older people. In the Ghanaian culture, respect for relatively older people is a social value and highly regarded, hence younger persons could not just go to people older than themselves to ask them questions pertaining to their personal and business lives. By introducing them to the group, it provided "legitimate“ basis for the association's members to cooperate with them.when they saw them around. I prepared a survey questionnaire which included questions on demographic and socio-economic background characteristics of members of the General Traders Association. These included questions on age, marital status, and educational attainment. Questions were also asked about the history of their businesses, and probed into traders' assessment of physical and social conditions in the Central Market, EMA's rent increment policies, and security and safety in the market. Most important of all, I probed into their participation in associational activities and actions vis-a-vis the EMA. With the help of the five field assistants, I pretested 141 the questionnaire through a random sample of twenty-five members of the GTA in the Central Market. The intent of this pretest exercise was to assess the appropriateness and suitability of the questions. This procedure enabled me to test the accuracy of the interpretation of the survey questions from English to the local Asante Twi language. After the pretest, some of the questions which seemed inappropriate were dropped, and.meanings of some apparently difficult concepts were sharpened and clarified. The assistants also had the opportunity to share their experiences and observations, as they tried out the pretest questionnaire. Through these exchanges, I was able to provide some guidance regarding the next phase of data collection. The final version of the survey questionnaire was administered to a random sample of 200 members of the General Traders Association. The sample was drawn from members who attended the monthly meetings, as well as those in the Central Market. Few of the members of the association were capable of completing the questionnaire themselves, so I and the assistants interpreted the questions to them and wrote down their responses. The next step of data collection from the GTA.was interviews with leaders of the association. For these leaders, I deemed it appropriate to interview them privately in their stores/stalls at prearranged times in the market. In order to facilitate free flow of information and 142 exchanges, I tape-recorded the "conversations" I had with them, with their informed consent. Later, in my own privacy, I reviewed these conversations and extracted the relevant information for my present study. The conversations centered on the leaders' assessment of EMA policies to raise rents and fees, and the physical and social conditions in the Central Market, including safety and security. Others included specific actions taken by the association in the past (1983-1992) toward the policies of the EMA, and in response to physical and social conditions in the Central Market. I interviewed the president, secretary, and treasurer of the General Traders Association. They were quite candid with their responses. These leaders cooperated quite well with the sessions I had with them. 2. State/Local Government Officials I gathered data from officials of the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority, who were involved in the design and implementation of policies that affected market trader activities in the Central Market. Other officers I targeted were those in charge of providing physical and social infrastructure in the market. At the EMA, I interviewed the Metropolitan Secretary, the City Attorney, and heads of the health and treasury departments, and the Manager of the Central Market. The interviews centered on a) EMA's relationship to the central government; b) the effect of the Structural Adjustment Program (SAP) on the operations of the 143 EMA; c) administration of the Central Market; d) their assessment of conditions in the Central Market; e) facilities EMA provided in the Central Market in the 1984- 1992 period; f) EMA's rent increases, fees for late payment of rents, fees for tables traders set up inside and outside their stalls/stores; and g) werld Bank Funds for Central Market rehabilitation. The next section of the interviews focused on the relationship between the EMA and the market associations in the Central Market, particularly the General Traders Association. I was interested in what the EMA did or did not do with actions of the market traders to resist/protest the farmer's policies, such as petitions, demonstrations, and appeals through highly respected personalities in the city. Documentary/Archival Data Gathering I also used documentary and archival sources to gather data on the present study. First, the University of Science and Technology Library in Eumasi was invaluable to my research. Established since 1960, the library had pertinent books, magazines, newspapers, and research papers on the subject I was investigating. These resources were essential, since the local press house, the Pioneer, had lost much of its previous editions in its archives for the 1981-1992 period due to "search and destroy" tactics of the military government. I was highly impressed with the up-to-date 144 collection of local, national, and international newspapers and magazines in the University Library including the following: 1) State-owned newspapers: The Pegple's Daily Graphic, The Ghanaian Times; The weekly Spectator, and The Mirror. 2) Local private newspapers (for example, The Pioneer), which covers the Eumasi Metropolis, and 3) The‘West Africa Magazine, which covers news items from the West African sub- region. 3) In addition to these documentary sources, I had access to the relevant records of the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority for the period of my study (1984-1992). Another major source of information was the Local Government Bulletin which is published.monthly by the Ministry of Local Government. The General Traders Association at the Central Market also made available to me the few files they had, which contained information on their activities/actions vis- a-vis the EMA. Leaders of the GTA provided historical data on the association, membership characteristics, structure, and organizational procedures of the association. The activities and actions of the association vis-a-vis state/local government policies, and conditions in the Central Market were analyzed from a historical perspective; detailing the issues, and activities of the members of the trader association in the Central Market. Simdlarly, the data from the EMA were analyzed from a 145 l historical perspective, paying particular attention to the state restructuring processes, and their effect on the relationship between the EMA and the central government, EMA's restructuring, and strategies it had adopted to survive financially in the period of state restructuring. EMA's relationship with market traders were analyzed with the help of the historical/archival data, as well as the information obtained from interviews with officials of the EMA. Limitations of the Study A case study approach was adopted for this present study. This approach was done on purpose. Previous attempts to study informal economic activitieshave often used a cross-sectional approach, a survey of people engaged in the manufacturing, distribution, and retailing of goods and services through self-employment, and outside the sphere of influence of the state/local government regulations. I realized this approach, much as it covers a variety of activities, often led to nowhere in terms of policies to either promote or limit these activities. After all, no one policy could deal with all spheres of informal economy activities. My conviction was that a focused study of a particular sector of the urban informal sector, was a better way to provide detailed information on its activities, and relationship to state/local government institutions. 146 However, the researcher is aware that such a strategy limits comparison of market associational activities with other sectors of the informal economy. Second, by limiting the study to the Central Market, it does not allow for comparison with activities of market associations in other markets in the city, in relationship to the EMA. Similarly, others may question the applicability and extension of conclusions of this focused research to other market associational actions/activities in other Ghanaian cities. Much as these questions are legitimate, the researcher had to deal with practical realities of time and resources. The researcher would make recommendations at the end of the study for further research into questions that were not addressed in this research, but which could be quite useful for comparative purposes. For instance, what is the relationship of market associations in the Central Market to market associations in other markets in the city? How are the Central Market associational activities/actions different from associational activities in other markets, or associations representing other sectors of the urban informal economy? Although the findings of this study, and its conclusions may be useful for comparison with other traders, they do not reflect on, nor are they meant to represent all traders in Eumasi, nor all cities in Ghana. The second limitation was record keeping at both the EMA and the General Traders Association. Although the EMA is 147 a bureaucratic institution which was expected to have well- kept records, what I observed was below expectation. Some of the data, particularly petitions they received from the market association were missing. I had to rely on recollections of officers who were in charge of responding to these petitions. Similarly, record-keeping in the GTA was quite poor, given the relatively low-level literacy and educational attainments of the traders. In most cases, I made follow-up enquiries of the few items I found in the records, and the leaders had to recollect the information from.memory, which was not always easy to verify. Conclusion I was generally impressed with the outcomes of the interviews and responses to the survey questionnaire. The initial contacts I made with the leaders of the General Traders Association were quite helpful, and abated any suspicions of my motives and intentions in carrying out this research. In all instances, I explained to traders the purpose of study, and assured them of anonymity and confidentiality. I believe my familiarity with the Eumasi Metropolis was an asset in undertaking the fieldwork. While my gender as a male could have hampered my study of market traders, most of whom were women, my selection of three women assistants helped to diffuse any negative responses. Moreover, my knowledge of the cultural, political, and 148 social contexts within which these market traders operated, provided unique insights which could have escaped a foreign researcher. Finally, the data gathered from the foregoing methods and techniques are used throughout the dissertation; they are used for the discussion and analysis of the research questions for the study. Overall, it was a rewarding fieldwork experience. CHAPTER SIX GLOBAL RESTRUCTURING AND THE STATE VERSUS NATION DILEMMA IN GHANA Introduction This chapter discusses the state versus the nation dilemma in Ghana within the context of global restructuring. It argues that the conflict between the state and the civil society in Ghana cannot be divorced from Ghana's historical experience(s) as a dependent, peripheral state within the global system. First, it demonstrates that global restructuring processes have redefined the structure, functions, and sources of revenue of state and local government institutions. Second, it is argued that these processes have engendered a bone of contention between the state and the civil society, as exemplified by the conflict between state/local government institutions and market traders in Ghana. The Context of State Restructuring In April 1983, the Provisional National Defence Council (PNDC) formally launched its Economic Recovery Program (ERP), which contained the Structural Adjustment Program (SAP). Although the policies and programs contained in the SAP package were presented as a novel idea of the PNDC, it 149 150 was an open secret that they were prepared with the expertise, and moral and political suasion from the International Monetary Fund and the WOrld Bank. The fact that the PNDC adopted the Economic Recovery Program itself testifies to the vulnerable and precarious position of peripheral African states in the global system. The PNDC came to office through a military coup led by Flight Lieutenant Rawlings on December 31, 1981. It launched a "revolution" which was interpreted to mean a radical change and restructuring of the political, economic, and social institutions in Ghana. Politically, the PNDC provided a unique experiment in 'people's power' and a level of spontaneous mass mobilization not seen since the early days of the independence struggle. In fact, the aims and tone of the revolutionary tasks were aptly summarized in the last paragraph of the PNDC's policy preamble: The policies projected under the December 31st Revolution should bear the characteristics of a genuine National Democratic Revolution. They must be anti-imperialist, anti-neo-colonialist, and must aim.at instituting a popular democracy. These policies must at all times ensure that the national interest is supreme [PNDC, Preamble, 1982:81 The political restructuring involved the formation of grassroots organizations. These were of two types; People's Defence Committees (PDCs), and.Wbrkers' Defence Committees (WDCs). PDCs were organized by the community, and WDCs were formed at the workplace, whether it was part of the Ministry of Agriculture, a school, a factory, or a unit of the Army, 151 FIGURE 6 . l People's Defence Committees (PDCs) and Workers‘ Defence Committees (WDCs). I983 Chairman's National Defence J.J. Rawlings Chairman PNDC Committee I National Defence Committee (NDCI I l NDC inter-departmental Committee (head: of the six dmrtmcntsl NDC Secretariat l Regional PDC Secretariat I I District POC Secretariat l Zonal PDC Secretariat Neighbourhood PDC Block POC Unit PDC WDC s Source: Donald Ray (1986:67) 152 FIGURE 6 . 2 PNDC Ghana (1 984): Political Structure =0 PNDC political control —-l> Civil Service administrative control PN DC (Provisional National Defence Council) \ / Chairman (JJ. Rawlings) Hsead of W ”2 mmm’ cm. Defence Staff National Defence Committee PNDC Special Advisor on Security and Foreign Affairs National Commission on Democracy (Cabinet) ’ PNDC Coordinating Secretary flooioml 0"“ m PNDC in“ PNDC “0‘0““ Secretaries Secretaries whim”, L ii I Sewflty I V II ' Ministries Administrations Regional (I'LQJ District Defence puoc District ‘- Tribunals Judieiaryj I 1 fl Paoplo‘g Defence I Cmmmm I Wm”. Defence Committaea I District Administrations I ‘ Source: Donald Ray(1986:67) 153 Navy or Airforce. In theory, there was a hierarchy of defence committees that extended from the local unit of the PDCs with between forty and a hundred members, up to the National Defence Committee, chaired by the PNDC chairman (that is, Rawlings), which operated in a democratic centralist manner. At the lowest level, three to five unit PDCs composed one Block PDC; three to five of these constituted one Neighborhood PDC; and three to five of these made up the Area PDC, which was the effective membership level. Three to five Area PDCs were contained in the Zonal PDC Secretariat which actually organized community projects and monitored prices of commodities in the locality. Several of these were formed under the District PDC Secretariat which corresponded to the administrative districts and provided the political back-up to the PNDC-appointed political head of the district administration, the District Secretary. The District PDC Secretariats in each region were grouped under their Regional PDC Secretariat, which.was the body in charge. of the region's political strategy, political education, and cadre training. The National Defence Committee (NDC) Secretariat coordinated the administration of the Regional Secretariats, in particular through the NDC departments: (1) Education and Research; (2) Information and Press; (3) Monitoring and Coordination; (4) Administration; (5) Complaints and Investigation; (6) Projects and Programs. The Standing Committee of the NDC, consisting of a maximum 153a of nine members, was the central executive committee of the structure of PDCs and WDCs. The NDC chaired by the PNDC Chairman, also acted as a source of policy and political advance to the PNDC. Thus, the PDCs and the WDCs were designed as the primary units by which the December 31st revolution would promote itself. The PDCs and the WDCs were to be instruments of popular participation, political education, channels of communication to and from the leadership, and political control (Ray, 1986:65-67). The economic restructuring process as articulated by the PNDC when it came to power was not clear. In retrospective, one could argue that, the PNDC had none. In his radio speeches, Rawlings promised a "merciless struggle“ against such social ills as corruption, fraud, profiteering, and smuggling. First, the bank accounts of ministers, and their deputies were frozen by PNDC decree. Each day, new lists of persons charged with crimes against the state and the people were published for public consumption. The PNDC also launched a campaign to eradicate profiteering, which flourished in the previous regime. Lists of price controls, violation of which could entail criminal liability, were published periodically, and prices were monitored by PDCs and WDCs. New rent legislation, another measure contrary to free-market economic, was adopted by the PNDC in the beginning of March, 1982. According to the PNDC, this move was to protect the interests of the poorest sectors of the population. Rents were reduced by half of what they were on 154 December Blst, 1981. Breach of the rent law by landlords became a criminal offence. Landlords could not evict tenants if the latter paid rent on time (PNDC Laws, 1982, Number 5). As a result, landlords tried by all means to withhold rental property, thus creating a housing crisis (Petchenkine, 1993). The rhetoric of populism which had provided the PNDC room to maneuver in the initial fifteen months was not enough to overcome the harsh realities of the Ghanaian economy, which had reached a state of decline and paralysis. As a matter of fact, as a player in the global system, the PNDC had limited options in transforming/restructuring the Ghanaian economy through moral persuasion and populism, The PNDC inherited an underdeveloped economy which was almost beyond repair. Between 1975 and 1981, the Ghanaian economy entered a period of profound crises. To an extent this reflected sudden adverse developments outside the immediate control of Ghanaian governments. Rain failures and drought affected agricultural production at a time of substantial government commitment to, and investment in food production. The rise in petroleum.import costs badly affected overall import capacity: petroleum imports rose in value from 6.7 percent of total export earnings in 1973 to almost fifty (50) percent of export earnings in 1981. In addition to this, generalized inflation on the world market led to severe import compressions. On the other hand, the international climate for Ghana's main exports were on the whole much more favorable than in any period since the early 155 19503. Yet this coincided with a precipitous and continuing decline in Ghana's entire export structure. Cocoa exports fell from 397,000 metric tons in 1975 to 246,5000 metric tons in 1981. Ghana's share of total world production dropped correspondingly from 24.4 percent in 1974-1975 to 15.4 percent in 1980-81. Also, there were similar declines of between thirty and sixty percent for mineral and timber exports. Current account deficits increased from C (cedi) 70 million in 1976 to C419 million in 1981, due at least partly to higher energy import costs (Hutchful, 1989). The directions taken by state finances were also alarming. Total public expenditures rose by 615 percent in current termm between fiscal years 1975-1976, and 1981-82, while revenues appreciated by only 56 percent. The total deficit rose by 690 percent. These state deficits were covered by heavy borrowing from the Central bank, with the result that money supply expanded by 933 percent. The PNDC's Program for Reconstruction and Development (PRD), introduced in December 1982, was the first statement of an economic recovery program by the government. On the face of it, the PRD was the initial phase in a nationalist and anti-imperialistic strategy of reconstruction. In this program, 1983 was designated as a period of preparation for launching a three-year recovery program.(1984-1986) which would lay the foundations for a 'self—reliant and integrated national economy'. In the first year, there was to be restructuring of the basic institutions of the economy, in 156 areas such as import-export trade, internal distribution, tax and budgetary reform, banking and insurance, and the establishment of a ‘sound.macro-economic framework' which would cover fiscal and monetary policy, prices and incomes, with the objective of rationalizing productive incentives. A state monopoly was to be instituted in the import/export trade, and internal distribution of essential commodities (basic household needs such as soap, milk, sugar, and milk) was to be taken over by I'People's Shops" under the control of PDCs. These measures were meant to eradicate trading malpractice, and attack the economic base of the foreign and indigenous factions. Thus, the basic tenet of the PRD was that the economic recovery in Ghana was not intended to be monetarist; that is, it required the restructuring of production relations, and sound financial management (Hutchful, 1989:102). However, elements within the PNDC and other ‘revolutionary forces‘ failed to obtain aid from the Eastern bloc, and anti-West sources, such as the Soviet Onion, Cuba, and Libya. Hence, they had to swallow their pride and seek aid from.alternative sources such as the WOrld Bank, and the International Monetary Fund (IMF). This shift in policy, one would argue, derailed the PNDC's initial economic ‘revolution', as it succumbed to rightewing, neo-liberal economic policies under the general term, Structural Adjustment Program (SAP). 157 The Structural Adjustment Prgggam (SAP) The Structural Adjustment Program (SAP) is a neo- classical economic approach ostensibly designed to solving the problems of underdevelopment in peripheral countries. It is championed by the core countries, particularly in the West, and financed through the WOrld Bank and the International Monetary Fund. Essentially, the SAP is predicated upon the ideology of the supremacy of “free“ market, and the elimination of centralized state economic planning. According to this school of thought, the root causes of economic crises in the periphery, Ghana in particular lay in state control of the economy, and very little, if any role for markets, prices, and the private sector. In other words, the problem.of economic development in the periphery is one of faulty monetary policies, characterized by strong role of peripheral states in the economy. The prescription that follows such prognosis advocates greater reliance on “free" markets, and minimum.state intervention in the economy. It involves reduced government spending, currency devaluation, reduction of imports and escalation of exports, and the primacy of the private sector. The WOrld Bank's own conceptualization of the economic crises in Ghana was as follows: 158 Ghana's economy has suffered tremendously for over a decade. This long neglect has brought the economy to a stage where instantaneous or quick remedies cannot be expected to work. A carefully phased program of adjustment has to be initiated with short, medium, and long term goals and supporting policy actions and institutional changes. While the needs of the economy are enormous, available resources and economic management capacity are limited. The external environment, especially the outlook for the country's major export commodity, cocoa, is extremely poor. At the same time, the chronic political instability of the past has generated deeply-ingrained attitudes of skepticism.and indifference among the main economic agents. Outside the country, other developing nations compete for the limited amount of concessional external assistance. One of the criteria for allocating external assistance is past economic performance and management, because of its track record, the perception of Ghana among bilateral donors and multilateral agencies has unfortunately not been very positive. Any acceleration in the flow of external assistance is likely to be gradual and will be based on Ghana's ability to demonstrate measurable progress in economic performance [Wbrld Bank, 1984:34]. In addition, the WOrld Bank identified the objective of the adjustment program as: to reverse the trend of declining per capita incomes through better overall economic management leading Ghana's economy to a stage from.where it can sustain more rapid economic growth. The process of adjusomont will entail three different phases (a) stabilization phase, (b) rehabilitation phase, and (c) liberalization and growth phase. While the stabilization phase will primarily attempt to restore macro balances, it will still contain elements of liberalization in so far as it affects relative prices. The emphasis in the rehabilitation phase would be on improved utilization and greater efficiency in the use of existing resources while in the liberalization and growth phases new investment would form.the basis. It is expected that the first phase should result in reduction in price distortions, the second in improving the capacity utilization of existing capital assets, and the third in trade liberalization and minimizing Government intervention [Wbrld Bank, 1984:34]. 159 The foregoing statements from the WOrld Bank regarding the diagnosis of the Ghanaian economic crises, and prescriptions to solve the problems, clearly contradicted the PNDC's own diagnosis and prescription for solving the economic problems of Ghana. How and why the PNDC accepted the perspectives of the WOrld Bank attests to the dilemma of peripheral states in the global system, The PNDC's economic pragmatism, fortuitously combined with rhetoric of populist assertion, had to strike a balance between domestic aspirations and international objectives to allow for a new initiative to achieve national economic recovery. Thomas Callaghy points out how critical this reconciliation is for peripheral states: The ability of Third WOrld governments to engage in sustained economic adjustment----caught as they are between strong and often contradictory internal and external pressures and economic and political logics --depends in large part on the technocratic and bureaucratic capabilities of the state apparatus and the ability of leaders to use these capabilities effectively. This means coping with the complex two-level negotiating 'games”---—economic and political games played simultaneously at domestic and international levels [Callaghy, 1989:20]. In the case of Ghana, there are three phases of the Economic Recovery Program (ERP) or SAP. The goals of the ERP I (1984-86,) were stated by the government: a) to arrest and reverse the decline in production, especially in agriculture; b) to control inflation; c) to stimulate exports and curb the consumption of luxury imports; d) rehabilitate the ruined productive and social 160 infrastructure; and mobilize both domestic and foreign resources to restore the living standards of Ghanaians (Government of Ghana, 1987:3). The goals of ERP II (1987-1989) were stated as: a) to ensure substantial economic growth at around 5 percent per annum; b) to stimulate substantial increases in the levels of saving and investment; c) to place the balance of payments on a sounder footing; and improve public sector management. The ultimate goal was to create a "growth- oriented, competitive, efficient, and integrated economy" (Government of Ghana, 1987: p.i.). The goals of ERP III (1989-1993) were focused on liberalization and economic growth. It aimed at reducing inflation, generating balance-of—payments surplus, promoting private investment, and promoting growth in the agricultural sector (Development GAP, 1992). Since its inception, the ERP/SAP in Ghana has been "the realignment of the price and incentive system in the economy in favor of the productive, particularly export, sectors" (Government of Ghana, 1989:2). The first phase of the Program (1983-1986) concentrated on halting the decline in industrial production and commodity export. The second phase (1987-1989) focused on economic development. The ERP/SAP has also emphasized efforts to restore fiscal and monetary discipline, to encourage both savings and investments, as 'well as to lessen the overhang of domestic and international imbalances. To implement this, the state and its 161 institutions were to be reorganized and, where necessary, reduced in size and function. In place of an over-concern with regulating every aspect of economic relations (something that was bound to prove ineffective under the conditions of weak state capacity prevailing in the country at that time), the bureaucracy, it was hoped, would concentrate on rehabilitating Ghana's productive and social infrastructure (Government of Ghana, 1988:11). Fiscal Crisis of the State1 One of the consequences of the ERP/SAP in Ghana has been a debt crisis of the Ghanaian state. In its quest for economic recovery, Ghana has drawn upon every funding mechanism available at the World Bank, and the International Monetary Fund. By the end of 1990 the government had contracted over US$1.75 billion in Bank loans and credits. In fact, by 1988 Ghana was the third largest recipient in the world of credit from the International Development Association (IDA), the Bank's soft-loan window. Only India and China, with a combined population of two billion, received more than Ghana, whose population is only 15 million. IMP funding under the ERP has totalled over US$1.35 billion, and total financial resources from bilateral and multilateral sources amounted to US$8 billion over the first seven years of the program, making Ghana one of the most favored aid recipients in the developing world (Development GAP, 1991:22). 162 TABLE 6.1 TOTAL EXTERNAL DEBT OF GHANA [03$ MILLION, UNLESS OTHERWISE INDICATED] 1970 1980 1985 1987 1990 1991 1992 Total - 1,407 2,226 3,262 3,296 4,209 4,275 Long-Term 521 1,171 1,337 2,276 2,705 2,992 3,131 Debt Use of IMF Credit 46 105 701 867 745 834 740 Short-Term - 131 189 119 312 384 404 Debt Source: The World Bank. 1994. W. p. 171. 163 Table 6.1 shows the debt status of Ghana from 1970 to 1992. It shows that in 1992, Ghana's external debt reached US$4.2 billion. Between 1980 and 1992, there was 203 percent increase in Ghana's external debt. Long-term debt accounted for the largest proportion of Ghana's external debt (73%), followed by IMF credit facilities (17%). Short- term debt accounted for 10% of Ghana's external debt in 1992. The data indicate that since the ERP and Structural Adjustment Programs were initiated in 1983, Ghana's indebtedness to the international community has worsened. However, external indebtedness under the ERP and SAP regime has had some consequences for Ghana. Essentially, it created a corresponding debt service burden for the Ghanaian government. Table 6.2 shows the total external debt ratios for Ghana. In 1980, the net value of total external debt was 236.2 percent of total exports. This remained the same for 1992. The net value of the external debt was 41. 2 percent of the Gross National Product, but declined in 1992 to 39.1 percent. State Policy Responses In the face of debt and debt service burden, Ghanaian officials have undertaken policy measures to correct the fiscal imbalances through restoration of the tax base to generate increased revenues, as well as intensify austerity measures such as reduced spending for social/community services. 164 TABLE (L2 TOTAL EXTERNAL DEBT RATIOS OF GHANA Net present value of external debt as % of Exports GNP 1930 1992 1980 1992 236.2 236.0 41.2 39.1 Source: The world Bank, 1994 Eorld_ne!elonnent_ncncrti P. 206. 164 165 Increased Tax Revenues Since 1983, tax revenue has risen as a proportion of Gross Domestic Product(GDP), reaching a peak of 12.7 percent in 1987, before declining to 11.6 percent in 1990 [Table 6.3 shows Central Government Revenue and Grants]. This increase reflected the combined effects of tax policy changes, improvements in tax administration and enforcement. The composition of tax revenue has changed significantly over the period of the economic recovery program; individual income taxation and export taxes now generate a significantly smaller share of revenue than in 1983, while corporate income tax and indirect taxes on imports and domestic commodities accounted for a larger proportion of revenue. The share of corporate tax revenue doubled, from just under 9 percent of total revenue in 1983 to 18 percent in 1988 (IMF, 1991). Reduced Expenditures One of the priorities of the economic recovery program was to restore discipline in government finances. To this end, in 1983, the first year of implementation of the adjustment strategy, the budget deficit was reduced from 6.3 percent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in 1982 to 2.7 percent of GDP, primarily through a contraction in government spending from 10.2 percent of GDP to 8.0 percent. This lower spending level was significantly below the budgeted level of 9.5 percent of GDP and was necessitated by 166 TABLE 6 . 3 Central Government Revenue and Grants. I975-9I I975 I980 I983 I984 I985 I986 I987 I988 I989 I990 I99I Budget Tax revenue Direct taxes Individual Corporate Other Taxes on domestic goods and (In percem of total revenue and grants) 89.8 90.6 82.6 79.2 80.7 84.5 85.5 84.0 8L4 82.2 84.4 20.6 26.0 l8.0 l8.2 l9.2 l9.2 2|.7 26.3 2L4 20.6 8.5 ll.8 I l.3 I4.2 0.8 0.! 8.6 8.8 0.6 7.3 7.6 7.2 7.4 7.2 5.7 6.5 l0.6 I0.8 I l.3 I3.0 l8.0 I4.6 I2.7 0.3 0.7 0.7 L4 LI [.0 L4 l6.9 5.2 l0.8 l.0 services l6.7 47.3 I5.9 24.6 22.3 26.6 23.6 25.2 24.3 26.8 36.9 General sales 5.7 6.7 2.3 L9 2.9 4.3 7.5 Excise except petroleum I0.S 4| .l I3.6 22.6 l7.9 l3.4 ll.5 Petroleum — — - — l.5 9.0 4 5 8.0 9.7 7.4 8.3 8.9 7.0 8.8 8.6 9.5 Taxes on international trade and » transactions 52.5 I 7. I 48.7 36.4 39.3 38.7 40.2 32.5 35.7 34.7 Import duties Export duties Non-tax revenue Grants Tax reveme Direct taxes Taxes on domestic goods ”.2 l6.3 I9.3 (4.0 l6.3 l9.3 l6.0 I6.6 2|.0 24.6 35.3 l0.l 0. I l3.8 3 2 0.8 8.0 L4 7.4 2| 28.6 22.0 22.8 l9.3 24.2 l5.9 I4.6 I0.2 I6.9 l6.8 l5.3 l0.3 0.6 4.0 4.0 5.3 9.| 5.4 8.5 7.5 8.7 9.9 7.4 NA (In percem of GDP) 4.6 l.0 6.6 l.5 9.5 2.3 I2.2 I2.7 l2.3 I2.3 I L6 2.8 3.2 3.9 3.2 2.9 . 7.3 7.9 2|.7 30.6 20.2 I0.3 6.8 8.7 l3.8 2 8 and services 2.6 3.8 . 0.9 2.I 2.6 3.8 3.5 3.7 3.7 3.8 6.0 Taxes on international trade and transactions Non-tax revenue Grants Total reverue and grants Memorandum items Total revenue and grants (broad) Grants (broad) 8.I L6 — l5.4 — — L4 0.6 0.I 8.I - — 2.7 0.9 - 5.6 5.6 — 3.0 L4 0.3 8.4 8.8 0.7 4.6 l.8 0.5 5.6 l.5 0.8 6.0 L4 0.8 4.8 L2 H 5.4 L3 (.5 4.9 I.0 LS 5.0 |.I I.4 I I.7 l4.4 l4.9 I4.6 l5.l I4.I l6.3 I2.4 l5.9 l6.7 l6.I I6.8. I5.8 ‘ I8. I I. l 2.2 2.6 2.5 3.2 3.2 3.2 chu:DanprovidedbytheGMuianamnues;sttafleathntes. Source: Internatiaalmtaty Fund. 19913 20- 167 TABLE 614" Central Government Expenditure and Net Lending. I975-9| I975 I980 I983 I984 I985 I986 I987 I988 I989 I990 I99I Budget Total expenditure 94.6 96.7 97.2 97. I 95.6 96.4 95.5 96.0 96.2 96.4 96.9 Current expenditure 75.I 82.2 89.4 84.9 80.3 83.0 75.3 74.I 72.8 75.I _ 74.7 Economic Classification (In percent of total expenditure and net lending) Goods and services 50.2 48.4 47.9 56.9 57.4 57.5 56.5 56.7 54.8 54.5 Wages and salaries 30.I 28.5 24.7 I9.2 30.3 35.7 33.6 33.0 30.8 3 I .2 Other goods and services 20.I l9.9 23.2 37.7 27.0 2|.7 22.9 23.7 24.0 23.4 Interest payments 6.I I2.8 l4.5 |2.5 |0.6 I5.5 Subsidies and transfers I3.7 2| .0 27.0 |5.S I2.3 |0.0 9.9 9.0 8.0 9.4 9.2 8.8 |0.3 l0.2 Capital expenditure |9.S I4.4 7.9 I2.3 |5.2 |3.4 l7.3 l9.9 I8.7 I8.3 Special efficiency Net lending — 5.4 - 3.3 Total expenditure 2| .7 |9.| Current expenditure I7.2 l6.3 Capital expenditure 4.5 2.9 Total expenditure and net lending 22.9 20.0 — 2.8 8.0 7.4 0.6 8.2 — 2.9 9.9 8.6 L2 — 4.4 — 3.6 2.8 4.5 2.0 4.0 4.7 3.8 3.0 3.6 (In percent of GDP) |3.3 l3.8 I3.7 I3.7 I3.9 l3.5 I |.2 ”.9 I08 |0.6 I0.5 |0.5 2.I L9 2.5 2.8 2.7 2.5 I0.2 |4.0 I4.3 I4.3 I4.3 I4.4 l4.0 Memorandum items Capital expenditure (broad) Total expenditure (broad) — - — — 0.6 8.2 L9 3.3 5.0 5.4 5.8 5.| 5.0 I H l5.4 I9.2 l9.| l8.9 l8.9 |8.I General public services 25.8 2|.0 26.4 24.9 2|.3 20.8 l9.3 22.0 l9.3 Functional Classification (In percent or total central government upmdimre) Defense Education Health Social security and welfare Housing and community ameni- ties Other community and social 7.8 6.3 4.6 6.0 7.5 6.5 6.5 3.2 3.I 20.6 I7.I ' 20.4 . 20.2 l8.0 23.9 23.9 25.7 24.3 8.3 | LG — 6.4 7.2 — 4.4 4.3 |.7 8.6 4.2 2.I 9.8 5.0 2.0 8.3 5.3 L9 8.3 6.4 L9 9.0 l0.l 6.9 3.5 7.3 2.6 services 3.9 3.I L8 2.2 I.5 L7 L7 I.5 2.0 Economic servicesa |6.2 22.7 2|.6 l8.9 23.8 |5.4 I8.6 |7.9 l6.9 Interest on public debt 6.5 l3.2 I4.9 I2.8 I |.I l6.I I0.4 Special efficiency - _. — - 2.9 8.3 2.I 9.5 4.9 54.2 30.4 23.8 I0.7 9.8 I9.0 3.2 3.I |4.0 l0.8 2.8 l4.5 5.9 l9.3 Sources: Data provided by the Ghanaian authorities; and MF staff urinates 'Data for I975 and I980 are on a fiscal year base (year ending Harem; from I983 onward the fiscal year coincides with the calender year. "MW services for agriculture. forestry and fish-rug. mg. manufacturing and construction. roads. and other tramport and commutation. Soiree: International mtary fund, 1991:21 168 a shortfall in government revenue (IMF, 1991:30). Table 6.4 shows Central Government Expenditure and Net Lending, 1975- 1991. Total expenditure as a percentage of the Gross Domestic Product was 21.7 in 1975. In 1983, when the SAP was introduced, it was reduced to only 8.0 percent of the GDP. However, in the 1991 budget, it was projected to be around 14.0 percent of the GDP. Apart from the increased tax revenues and discipline in expenditures, state restructuring has also involved privatization of state enterprises, retrenchment of workers in civil and public services. and local government restructuring. Privatization of State Enterprises Privatization of state enterprises is based on the fact that many of the state-owned enterprises (SOEs) had been created for political purposes, and therefore they performed poorly as commercial enterprises. For instance, between 1980 and 1982, the deficits of Ghanaian public enterprises were around 0.2-3.3 percent of Gross National Product (Swanson and WOlde-Semait, 1989:31). In 1982 alone, SOEs received approximately thirteen percent of total government expenditure in the form.of subsidies, equity contributions, and capital grants, and by 1984 this figure had almost doubled to twenty-five percent of total expenditures (Ada, 1989:307). 169 Thus, state enterprise restructuring had two principal objectives. First, it was aimed at reducing state involvement in the productive sector, and also ease the state of financial and managerial burden. Second, for those enterprises in which the state continued to participate, the goal was to improve their efficiency, profitability, and managerial accountability. Since 1983, more than thirty SOEs have been lined up for divestiture wholly or partly. These include the State Fishing Corporation, Food Production Corporation, State Farms Corporation, and forty-two Cocoa Board coffee and cocoa plantations. The response to the divestiture program in Ghana has not been encouraging. The absence of a dynamic entrepreneurial class in the private sector, as well as harassment of private indigenous investors by past mdlitary/civilian governments, has created a credibility problem.for potential indigenous and international investors, and therefore, the privatization process has not been as successful as expected. Privatization and Rationalization of Social Services State provision of essential social services for the public from the taxes the former collected from the latter had been a traditional practice for a long time. For instance, free and compulsory public education was one of the hallmarks of the first President, Dr. Kwame Nkrumah. Through this practice, many Ghanaians from poor 170 families had the opportunity to receive good education from the primary to the university level. However, as the economic crises of the 19703 and 1980s caught up with all state institutions, education was not spared. By 1980, education was taking around twenty percent of government's total recurrent expenditure. However, under the regime of adjustment, SAP required external funding, and donors were not likely to provide additional resources for the educational sector without refomms within the educational sector. Consequently, the structure and financing of education underwent some changes. First, the structure of the national educational system was changed from seventeen years of preuniversity schooling, that is six years of primary, four years of middle, and five years of junior secondary, and two years of senior secondary school education before entering the university. The new structure required twelve years, that is six years of primary, three years of junior secondary, and three years of senior education (Dei, 1993). According to the WOrld Bank and Ghanaian education officials, the rationale was to release more resources to improve both access to, and quality of education, especially at the basic level. Second, the reforms also introduced user fees for primary school services, equipment, and laboratories (for example, health services fees, sports and recreational fees, textbook and stationery fees), parent-teacher association fees, and room and board charges for institutions of higher 171 learning. The state was to cut down on recurrent expenditures on staff, staff training, and textbooks. The latter action was based on WOrld Bank conceptualization of the educational problems in Ghana as largely due to administrative inefficiency, and the increased involvement of the state in running the educational system, As Dei (1993) points out, no adequate attention was given to the fact that deplorable national economic conditions and poverty of many people accounted in large measure for many of the educational problems. Through these measures, the state sought to remove the traditional responsibility of financing education from the collective whole (that is, the state) to the individual. The state has committed itself to privatization of the educational system, particularly the post-secondary levels, by making parents contribute more toward their children's education. Given the increasing impoverishment of ordinary Ghanaians in the 1980s (Hooper, 1990; Anyinam, 1989; Dei, 1992), such measures have consequences for educational equity and accessibility. These measures took place at a time when the SAP recommendations included "getting the prices right" and aligning domestic prices with international price structures. The costs of textbooks and stationery for students, teachers, and researchers are beyond the reach of the average Ghanaian salaried worker or farmer or trader. Not only have salaries/wages of workers fallen, but also they do not reflect actual purchasing 172 power. For example, on my visit to Ghana in 1992, a basic science textbook in the senior secondary school cost between C10,000-C20,000 (about $50-$100), while the daily minimum wage was C200 ($1.00). This was complicated by the fact that there was massive retrenchment in the job market. The state has also restructured the financing of health care in Ghana, and invariably privatized it. Prior to the SAP, Ghanaians enjoyed free medical care. Although there was a two-tier system.of health care, the private and public systems, most Ghanaians in cities and towns, could utilize the latter within their localities. Under the regime of adjustment, however, and for the first time in Ghana's history, health care provision was privatized. In 1985, the PNDC government introduced a range of fees for hospitals and clinic consultations and laboratory tests. The basic fee for an adult to consult with a doctor was from two-thirds to a full day's minimum.wage (C50-C75 in 1985, excluding a minimum.of 56 percent additional in allowances). Although the clearly destitute supposedly do not have to pay fees, fee collection efforts are insistent. Initial consultation fees by 1987 were C200, almost two days of minimmmuwage. An inpatient is required to make a Cl,500 initial deposit against costs, about ten days of a minimum wage worker's earnings. As one scholar has reported, some patients sometimes abscond to avoid payments of hospital fees (Kraus, 1991). i To add insult to injury, the privatization of education 173 and health services occurred at the same time that the state, with the recommendation of the WOrld Bank, retrenched workers in the civil/public sector of the state bureaucracy. Retrenchment of Civil and.Public Service‘florkers As part of the downsizing of state institutions, over 300,000 workers in civil and public services as well as State-Owned Enterprise (SOEs) have lost their jobs. According to state officials, the rationale for the retrenchment was to remove redundant workers, necessitated by the twin problems of low productivity and low incomes on the one hand, and the size of public expenditure, on the other. The exercise was executed according to guidelines issued from the Office of the Head of the Civil Service (DECS) I namely 3 a) eliminate officers whose work and conduct have been persistently negative; b) save officers whose work and conduct have been persistently positive and cannot be dispensed with without serious detriment; c) dispense with officers handicapped by physical infirmity; . d) eliminate officers engaged over and above approved establishment schedules; e) include officers who are willing to retire voluntarily; f) consider officers who are on secondment elsewhere who can be dispensed with; g) use the "last come, first go“ strategy, if it comes to the crunch, that is, if above figures do not produce target figures; 174 h) include officers whose qualifications were proven to be false (as quoted in Jonah, 1992:142-143). State downsizing in the form.of retrenchment has had far-reaching consequences for the survival of the affected workers. One reaction bears witness to its toll on individual‘workers: The 12,000 employees of Ghana Cocoa Board (Cocobod) who are to be made redundant are not happy with the way in which the government is trying to rush through the exercise. The Secretary-General of the Trades union Congress (TUC) told the Ghana News.Agenoy that the affected.workers had.begun receiving their redundancy letters even though negotiations on their entitlements were still going on. 'How on earth can the government drive these workers out of employment into the streets 'without paying them.anything to sustain them.in the harsh conditions that prevail today?, he asked (Nest Africa, 2-8 August, 1983: 1356). The reaction of urban workers was generally hostile to the retrenchment policy. While some of the redundancies may have been necessary in the context of reducing public sector expenditure, workers demanded that the PNDC should not make employees redundant without the existence of realistic programs to redeploy them” For example, in 1986, the explosive nature of this question was demonstrated by an accident at the Hall of the Trade Unions in Accra. Following the arrest of several union leaders because of their vocal opposition to the redundancy program, an estimated 1,000 armed police personnel surrounded the TUC Hall to control a crowd of workers which had gathered to express their displeasure (Africa Events, 1986:15). Eventually, the 175 leaders were released, but the government went ahead with the retrenchment policy, anyway. In 1987, the PNDC established a "Program of Action to Mitigate the Social Costs of Adjustment" (PAMSCAD) ostensibly to help redeployed and retrenched workers, as well as the poor, rural and urban centers in Ghana. Four main categories of projects were designed for implementation under the PAMSCAD, namely; (a) Community Initiative Projects that were intended to enable communities to design and implement projects that would help to rehabilitate their social and economic infrastructure; (b) Mt, Generation Projects, mostly food for work and public works projects to provide employment for the urban and rural unemployed; (c) Basic needs related projects at the grassroots level in such areas as housing, water, sanitation health, and nutrition; (d) §pecial Projects fgr Reggplgzed workers. These were projects that were meant to update the skills of workers to conform.to the needs of the Civil and Public Services. These included literacy training, computer workshops, and group projects (ILO, 1989). The world Bank and the IMF pledged US$84 million to cover the cost of the program, Although the PAMSCAD is often cited as if it is already addressing the social costs of adjustment, the ILO (1989) found out that the Projects had hardly taken off, and had a number of problems. Donors were slow in converting their pledges to funds for disbursement, partly because of 176 the complicated requirements by Donors, and partly because some of the preparatory work prior to funding had not been done. The reality then was that only very few programs were actually being delivered, and only a small proportion of the needed aid funds were available. The ILO concluded: Accordingly, the plight of the poor and the vulnerable remained unattended to. It is a matter for regret that with such large external funds being released for the economic program, it has not been possible for both Government and donors to streamline aid disbursement procedures so that the relatively "small funds“ needed to address the social dimension of adjustment could be available (1989:24). Generally, preliminary investigations indicate that while some twenty percent of retrenched workers left for the countryside to engage in agricultural activities, majority of them entered the urban informal economy as either micro- business entrepreneurs or laborers. By the mid—1980s, it was estimated that the burgeoning informal economy accounted for about eighty-five percent of employment in Ghana, up from sixty percent in 1980s, and fifty percent in the 19703, respectively (Jonah, 1989:15). The foregoing has outlined some of the effects of state restructuring processes in Ghana since the SAP was implemented. It demonstrates that the initial impact of the SAP has been quite drastic for many a Ghanaian; devaluation of the Ghanaian currency, retrenchment within public sector employment, and general economic hardship in the society have been quite stressful for both workers and the poor. The next section addresses how the SAP has redefined central- 177 local government relationships, and its implications for the civil society. Central-Locgl Government Relationship Central-local government relationship has also been affected by the restructuring processes in Ghana. In the pre-SAP period, local governments depended quite heavily on central government transfers and subventions. For instance, between 1950 and 1960, government transfers accounted for about forty percent of the total revenue of local governments. In fact, until 1985, the Central government was fully responsible not only for local government employees' salaries, but also provided funds for community development at the local level. But effective July 1985, local governments were required to take over fifty percent of the salaries of their employees. The PNDC Budget Statement and Economic Policy for 1985 stated: Government has decided to restore the traditional system of self-reliance in financial management by local bodies. These bodies used to meet their expenses on schools, labor, maintenance and salaries of local staff out of their own revenues. The transfer of responsibility back to them will be phased to ease adjustment. Local authorities will start paying overtime expenses from April 1, 1985, fifty percent of the salary expenses from July 1, 1985, and assume full responsibility later in 1985 (Budget Statement, 1985:22). However, the official rhetoric/explanation for this change in the central-local government fiscal relationship was that it would encourage local governments to be more 178 responsible toward their local communities. However, it could be interpreted as a strategy on the part of the central government to reduce state expenditures for public services, as well as oblige local authorities to seek alternative sources of revenue to provide services to their communities. How have local government institutions responded to this new challenge within the context of state restructuring in Ghana? Local Government Response Local governments were originally set up to fulfill several functions, but they generally fall into three major categories: environmental, protective, and personal services. ‘Environmental Services' are designed to secure g and improve the residents' surroundings, including public health services, such as prevention of diseases, and water pollution. ‘Protective services' relate to local authority police force. They are expected to safeguard public order, and safety of persons and property within their administrative areas. ‘Personal services' which local governments provide are meant to promote the general well- being of residents. Local authorities need money to pay for services which they are legally required to provide, and for services which they themselves plan. However, the fundamental problem.which faces local governments is how to provide this money to meet 179 the cost of these services without imposing too high a burden on their residents, and without becoming too dependent upon grants from the central government, and thereby losing much of their freedom of choice in the planning of their budgets, and in the way they execute their plans. In the period preceding the SAP, the main sources of revenue of local authorities in Ghana were: a) licenses, permits, dues, charges, and fees specified by the local authority's by-laws; b) land revenue and rents derived from letting and leasing of any building or land owned by the local authority; c) proceeds of annual levies imposed on all persons above the age of eighteen years who reside within the jurisdiction of local authority; d) interests from invested funds of the local authority; a) all fees, fines, penalties, amounts and costs in respect of offences committed within the jurisdictions of the local authorities; f) loans; and central government subventions (grants-in-aid). The contradiction in the restructuring process was that while the central government was "rolling back" its responsibilities to society, it increased the role of local governments in community development, but without the level of financial support it used to provide the latter to fulfill their functions. For instance, the 1988 Local Government Law empowered local governments to assume wide- ranging functions. They were charged with providing 180 infrastructure for community development such as schools, roads, and markets. The 1988 Local Government Law empowered local authorities to generate revenues for their operations mainly from their communities, as a means to reduce their dependence on the central government. It provided a broad- range of sources of revenues from the local community: 1. Income Tax (Registration of Trade, Business, Profession and Vocation); 2. Fee-related revenues from.activities such as market trade, and local restaurants; 3. License-related sources of revenue such as hawkers, local distillers, herbalists, and self-employed artisans (Local Government Law, 1988:56-58). The responsibility for the assessment and enforcement of fees and licenses were left to the discretion of local authorities, with prior approval by the Ministry of Local Government. In addition to new revenue-generating strategies, local governments have retrenched some of their workers in keeping with central government policy to reduce the size of the labor force in public institutions. Realistically, it is a strategy to reduce the financial burdens of local governments within the context of state restructuring and limited financial resources. Retrenchment of local government workforce will tend to have an effect on their capacity to provide adequate services for their local 181 communities. In particular, the retrenchment exercise will affect the extent to which local governments will be able to provide adequate maintenance for local markets. Local Government in the RumasiiMetropolis In 1924, the colonial administrators established the Kumasi Sanitary Board (KSB) as its first formal local government institution in the region. Hitherto, a Sanitary Committee had been set up to concern itself with improving 'the environment by improving street drainage and drinking water, and constructing incinerators and latrines (washrooms) [Adubofour, 1977; Tordoff, 1965]. The Kumasi Sanitary Board continued the work of the Sanitary Committee: it was aimed at improving the urban environment. especially in terms of public health and welfare. It appointed educated Ghanaians as public health officers who visited schools, and homes to educate people about personal hygiene and waste disposal. The services provided by the KSB were financed by the colonial government. The reason was quite simple: the EurOpeans were as much concerned with outbreaks of plague and yellow fever emanating from “native housing areas" as to increase the welfare of the indigenous population. Similarly, early housing policies tended to be based on sanitation requirements rather than on space and occupancy standards. This "Sanitation Syndrome" (Swanson, 1976) made the European administrators pay for health and environment services from central government coffers. 182 The Eumasi Sanitary Board was replaced in 1925 by the Kumasi Public Health Board (KPHB). It comprised of four official members who were appointed by the Chief Commissioner for Ashanti Region, and five African unofficial members. The latter were nominated by both the Chief Commissioner for Ashanti and the Eumasi Divisional Council, which represented the local Ashanti chiefs. The KPHB had more wide-ranging powers to initiate, and implement policies/regulations on public health. It was responsible for public parks, cemeteries, slaughter houses, and general sanitation in schools and homes. The Eumasi Town Council (KTC) replaced the Kumasi Public Health Board in 1943. For the first time, the principle of elected members was introduced. The KTC was made up of six elected members (each representing one of the six wards into which Eumasi was divided), three official members nominated by the Chief Commissioner for the Ashanti Region, two members from the Chamber of Commerce. For the first time, the local government institution was charged with more responsibilities beyond public health and sanitation. It was charged with the responsibility to levy taxes from people in the community, and license professions and business, as well as control buildings through zoning policies. It promoted community development, and was instrumental in the construction of public schools and markets, roads, cemeteries, and slaughter houses. The presence of a representative the Chamber of Commerce on the 183 TABLE 6.5 PROFILE OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT DEVELOPMENT IN KUMRSI l. COLONIAL PERIOD 1924-1925 The Kumasi Sanitary Board 1925-1943 The Kumasi Public Health Board 1943-1953 The Kumasi Town Council 2. POST-COLONIAL PERIOD 1953-1962 The Kumasi Municipal Council 1962—1989 The Eumasi City council 1989 Thelnmesilunznpokunn.memhly Sources: Government of Ghana, Ghana Enguiryiinto the Affairs of the Kumasi City Council, 1970. Government of Ghana, Local Government Bulletin, 1988. 184 Council was indicative of the influence of the indigenous and European bourgeois class in the city. The Eumasi Municipal Council (KMC) replaced the Eumasi Town Council in 1953. The Municipal Council Ordinance of 1953 broadened the membership of local governments, and emphasized the elective principle. In all, twenty-four members were selected from the wards of the city, which was a broader representation of the residents of the city compared with the previous local government institution, the Kumasi Town Council. The KMC assumed.both legislative and executive powers; it passed bye-laws and enforced and implemented them through its office outlets in Kumasi. These bye-laws invariably affected all aspects of the residents' lives, including birth registration, sanitation, education, lorry parks, noise, security, business, death registration, and cemeteries. The Kumasi Municipal Council was succeeded by the Kumasi City Council (KCC) in 1962. The composition, functions, and powers of the KCC were all determined by dynamics of national politics in Ghana. This accounts for changes that took place within the ICC from 1965 to 1988, a period during which the KCC went through patterns of elections, suspensions, and interimimanagement committees. For instance, the KCC was suspended by the Nkrumah state in March 1965, and its functions were transferred to an Interbm Management Committee. A new council was elected in October, 1965, and operated until February 24, 1966, when the first 185 military coup ended its operations. From.1966-l969, the military government appointed military personnel to head the Interim Management Committee of the Kumasi City Council. The return to civilian rule in the 1969-1972 period brought back the elective principle regarding membership into the KCC. The KCC was reconstituted, as the electorate had the opportunity to elect their own twenty-four representatives to the Council. But this did not last long when it was disbanded by the Acheampong military regime that overthrew the civilian regime in 1972. From 1972-1979, the Interim.Management Committees of the KCC were headed by military personnel appointed by the National Redemption Council, a military institution. The Eumasi City Council constructed schools, public markets, roads, and recreational/leisure facilities. It also continued to enforce health and sanitation standards in the city. It carried out this function by appointing health inspectors who were dispatched to suburbs of the city to enforce its bye-laws pertaining to health and environmental sanitation. They visited households, and business sites, to ensure residents and business people maintained some minimum. level of hygienic conditions which did not pose a health hazard to residents. They summoned residents who were in default to appear before the City Court; and those who were found guilty were fined.2 186 Local Government Restructuring in Eumasi (1987-1992) In 1987, the Provisional National Defence Council (PNDC) embarked upon a major local government restructuring process. It involved decentralization of political and administrative authorities, with elected representatives of the people. In pursuance of the policy of decentralization, the PNDC established 110 District Assemblies. Each District Assembly consisted of "a) The District Secretary; b) Two- thirds of the members represented the electoral units directly elected by the electorate; c) One-third of the members comprised of traditional authorities or their representative and other persons from the district, to be appointed by the Central Government from the District, in consultation with the traditional authorities and other organized associations of productive economic groupings in the district" (Ghana, 1987:2). The Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly was established in 1989. It comprised of ninety-one persons who were made up of: a) The Provisional National Defence Council Secretary responsible for the Eumasi Metropolis; b) Sixty persons who represented the electoral areas into which Metropolis was divided; c) Thirty persons who represented traditional authorities, and other persons ordinarily resident in the Metropolis, who were appointed by the Council in 187 consultation with the traditional authorities and organized productive economic groupings in the Metropolis (Local Government Instrument, 1989:1). The Eumasi Metropolitan Assembly (KMA) assumed a long list of functions [Local Government, (Eumasi Metropolitan Assembly) Establishment Instrument, 1989:61-67]. I would focus on some of its functions related to markets and market traders. The KMA was charged with the responsibility to build, equip, open, close, and maintain markets in the Metropolis. Furthermore, the KMA was supposed to prohibit the erection of stalls in places other than markets, and prevent the sale and purchase of goods near established markets. More importantly, it was expected to regulate and control markets including fixing andcollection of rents and fees from traders. Thus the KMA, like other local government institutions, was not only the basic political authority, but also the statutory deliberative, legislative and consultative body, concerned with the determination of broad policy objectives and the critical assessment of development programs. The Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly was also charged with the responsibility for the maintenance of security and public safety in the metropolis. It carried out this task with the support of national and local security agencies, such as the police and the mdlitary institutions. The Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly established other institutions to assist it to carry out its functions. These included the a) Eumasi Metropolitan Authority, b) The 188 ORGANIZATIONAL STRUCTURE OF THE KUMASI METROPOLITAN ASSEMBLY FIGURE 6.3 KUMASI METROPOLITAN ASSEMBLY METROPOLITAN AUTHORITY METROPOLITAN OF BOARD TECHNICAL PLANNING MINISTRATION~ OF MUNICIPAL INFRASTRUCTURE COMMISSION SERVICES ’ I presume, error a SOCIAL SUB-COMMITTEES i . Waste Management 11'. Metro PROGRAMMING ECRETARIAT SERVICES Engineering SUB-COMMITTEE iii . Estates &BUDGET (Legal Dept) SUB-COMMI i. Economic Planning Department — . . . . . ii . Budget De t i.Education Dept. iiJlin. of Health Dept. FINANCE & ADMIN. 1. Trees ii. Administration iii. Internal Audit isUB-METRO DISTRICT COUNCILS SUBIN - mu}. mm EOKWA —‘ DatacmpfledfrunthereoordsofthenetropolitanAssatbly. 189 Metropolitan Planning Commission, c) The Board of Municipal Services; and d) The Board of Administration. The Eumasi Metropolitan Authority serves as the Executive Committee of the Assembly. The thirty members who comprise the Metropolitan Authority are elected by members of the Assembly themselves. However, the Provisional National Defence Council Secretary responsible for the Kumasi Metropolis presides over the meetings of the Authority. The Metropolitan Authority performs the executive functions of the Metropolitan Assembly. Hence, it implements the resolutions of the Metropolitan Assembly, as well as overseas the day-to-day administration of the Assembly. The Metropolitan Planning Commission integrates, monitors, and evaluates development planning and management of the Eumasi Metropolis. It also integrates the functions of the sub-committees of the Metropolitan Authority, and proposals that come from such committees, and advises the Authority on such matters. The Board of Municipal Services is responsible for the efficient integration of the municipal services, which include construction of public facilities such as roads and bridges, schools, and markets, as well as the provision of health and welfare services. On the other hand, the Board of Administration organizes and manages the general administration of the Authority and the Assembly. In addition, it supervises the Treasury, justice, security, and estate management of the Assembly. 190 Financing of Local Government in the Eumasi Metropolis The major change that has occurred in local government restructuring in Ghana has been their revenue sources. Essentially, local governments have come to depend more on taxes from the community under their jurisdiction. For instance, Section 57(3) of the Local Government Law (1988) stated that certain revenue sources, like entertainment duty, casino revenue tax, betting tax, gambling tax and income tax (registration of trade, business, profession or vocation), which had been previously tapped by both central government (through the Internal Revenue Secretariat), and local government units, were now to be taxed exclusively by the district assemblies. The law, however, allowed for other agencies to collect the ceded revenue on behalf of the district assemblies. In practice, the Ministry of Local Government arranged with the Internal Revenue Secretariat for the latter to collect the money and pay into a special Ministry of Local Government Account on behalf of the district assemblies. What became obvious was that the central government ceased paying fifty percent of the salaries/wages of district assembly employees. Instead, district assemblies assumed greater responsibilities, as well as challenges to mobilize resources for its administration and projects. In fact, the Wbrld Bank committed $US 7.5 million to help the Ministry of Local Government towards fiscal decentralization. Under the Urban I Projec , the Werld Bank funded programs designed to 191 TABLE 6.6 (PERCENTAGES) 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1. Markets 25.8 34.1 33.6 26.6 40.0 38.1 2 . property Rates 20.7 21.8 13.5 14.0 13.9 10.8 3. License 18.2 11.4 16.6 16.9 17.3 13.7 4. Reimbursement (Government Share of 50% of Salary) 2.8 11.9 13.9 15.1 13.1 12.4 5. Fees 7.6 2.0 2.2 4.4 4.4 6.5 6. Lorry Park ___ 2.8 6.0 5.1 3.2 4.9 Source: Treasury Department, Eumasi Metropolitan Authority, 1992. 192 strengthen the management capacity and revenue mobilization of district assemblies. However, The Eumasi Metropolitan Assembly benefitted from the Urban II Projegg, when its staff participated in the project to enhance their management and mobilization capacities. Table 6.6 shows the major sources of revenues for the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority for the 1987-1993 period. It demonstrates that markets, property rates, license, central government reimbursement for local government employees' salaries, and fees were the major sources of revenues for the EMA. Throughout the period, revenues generated from markets in the city accounted for an average of thirty-five percent of the total revenues the EMA received. The average contributions of licenses, property rates, government share of employee salaries, and fees to total revenues of the EMA were 15.1, 14.7, 11.5, and 5.0 percent, respectively. In general, market traders bore a greater burden of the finances of the EMA in the form.of higher increases in rents, license fees, income taxes, as well as new strategies of the EMA to demand fees from traders for every table they set up both inside and outside their stalls/stores. Table 6.7 shows the rents for stalls/stores in the Central Market. ngn Spells are spaces designed for traders to display their commodities, but have no locks attached to them. The biggest increase for rents for Open stalls was since in the 1984-1985 period. It jumped from C 60 to C 400, an increase of 566 percent. However, the rents for the open 193 TABLE 6.7 KUMASI METROPOLITAN AUTHORITY RENTS FOR CENTRAL MARKET STALLS/STORES, 1984-1991 (Amount in cedis) % Change 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1984-1991 Open Stalls 60 400 400 400 600 600 800 1,600 2,550 Lock-up 120 300 400 400 800 800 1,500 3,000 2,400 Stores Super Lock-Up 200 500 500 500 1,000 1,000 3,000 5,000 2,400 Stores Source: Data compiled from the Ghana Local Government Bulletin, 1984-1991 editions. 194 stalls stabilized at C400 for the 1985-1987 period. In 1988, the rents increased by fifty percent, from C 400 to C 600. In 1989, the rents remained at C 600 without any increase. However, the rents increased by fifty percent in 1990, from C 600 to C 800. The rents doubled in 1991, from C 800 to C 1,600. Overall, open stalls experienced increases in the 1984-1991 period to the tune of 2,550 percent. The lock-up stores were spaces in the market which had locks attached to them, and were relatively more secured than open stalls. Market traders who owned them could lock up their commodities at the end of the day, instead of carrying them home, and carting them back for the next day's business activities. In the 1984-1985 period, rents for the lock-up stores increased by more than 150 percent, from C 120 to C 300. Also, rents for the lock-up stores doubled in the 1987-1988 period, from C 400 to C 800. Another major change in rents was in the 1990-1991 period, when rents doubled again, from C 1,500 to C 3,000. Overall, the percentage increase in rents for the 1984-1991 period was 2,400. The super lpck-up stores were relatively larger than the lock-up stores. In the 1984-1985 period, rents for the super lock-up stores jumped from C 200 to C 500, an increase of 150 percent. The rents remained stable at C 500 for both 1986 and 1987. However, the rent for the super lock-up stores doubled in the 1987-1988 period, from C 500 to C 1,000. The biggest increase in the rents took place in 1990 when the previous year's rent tripled, from C 1,000 to 195 C 3,000. To increase its revenues derived from.market traders, the EMA also introduced a new policy to charge market traders special fees for using tables inside and infront of their stalls/stores in 1985. Originally, occupants of stalls/stores were required to pay monthly rents for the stalls/stores allotted to them. Traders were expected to display their commodities inside the stalls/stores. However, customers had to enter the store to catch a glimpse of the varieties of commodities being displayed for sale. To increase sales, market traders set up tables infront of their stalls/stores to display their commodities. The EMA interpreted the practice of displaying commodities in front of stores/stalls as a strategy by the traders to increase sales, and therefore, should be taxed for extra sales they made. Specifically, for each table that a market stall/store occupant set up, he/she was expected to pay a fee of C 5 daily. However, this tax increased to C 50 in 1992. Another source of EMA's tax revenues derived from market traders were fees for late payment of rents. This policy was introduced in 1985. The penalty was set at C 500 for late payment of rents. EMA officials indicated that this policy was intended to deter traders from defaulting rent payment. The penalty was set at C 500 for late payment of monthly rentals. However, market traders felt that late fees were attempts by the EMA to generate extra revenues from theme They argued that it was not always possible to pay 196 monthly rents in person on time due to unforeseen circumstances. Market traders cited illness, and participation in some social and cultural events, such as funerals in their hometowns. However, the EMA did not accept traders' alibi, and went ahead with the implementation of fees for late payment of fees. Apart from generating tax revenues from the local community, the EMA also retrenched some of its workers to reduce expenditures. The EMA carried out two phases of retrenchment between 1985 and 1992. The first phase in the 1985-1988 period involved retrenchment of 1,500 employees. Most of these were casual laborers who worked for the Sanitary Department of the EMA. They used to clean the streets, markets, and washrooms in the city. The second phase of the retrenchment exercise (1989-1992), affected all departments of the EMA. The Treasury Department reported that the retrenchment exercise affected 161 revenue collectors, which they argued throw their collection of revenue estimates out of gear. The targets they set could not be achieved. Overall, by 1992, the EMA's labor force had been considerably reduced by 74%. According to EMA's annual report, "the retrenchment was carried out to ensure prompt payment of salaries, and also to purchase tools and materials for maintenance and development" [EMA, 1992]. 197 Summary In the foregoing section, I have demonstrated that the restructuring processes have redefined the relationship between central and local government institutions in Ghana. It has been argued that local government institutions have assumed more responsibilities towards their localities. However, local government institutions have come to depend on their communities for tax revenues to support their bureaucratic institutions, at the same tbme their capacity to respond to local service needs has been weakened by their fiscal crises. The next section of the chapter analyzes these contradictions, and the conflicts they have engendered between the local state and market traders. BONE OP CONTENTIGN: LOCAL STATE VERSUS CIVIL SOCIETY It is argued that contradictions in state restructuring processes have engendered conflict between the local state and workers in the community. The conflict hinges on the former's fiscal policies which are designed to control and exploit the incomes of the latter through increased taxation, while at the same time not having the institutional capacity for providing the social service needs of the local community, and the struggles of the latter for empowerment. These contradictions became quite clear in the struggles of the market traders in the Eumasi Central Market vis-a-vis the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority. First, the petitions of the market traders will be presented 198 to illustrate the major issues of their struggle. Second, these issues will be categorized and analyzed to demonstrate their centrality to the restructuring processes, and their effects on market trader activities. Market Trader Reactions Between 1985 and 1992, the General Traders Asociation (GTA) in the Central Market subitted six petitions which articulated their collective concerns and interests regarding the policies of the local state. First, I will present the petitions to illustrate the major issues of their struggle. Second, these issues will be catgeorized and analyzed to demonstrate their cemntrality to the restructuring processes, and their effects on market trader activities. Each of the petitions originated from the monthly meetings of the GTA. At these meetings, members discuss important issues facing them, and at the end of the meeting pass resolutions for action. These issues are further reviewed by the General Council of the association, and final recommendations are made to the executive committee of GTA. It is only the executive committee that writes the final resolution in the form.of a petition. Among the executive members I interviewed, I observed that it was only the secretary who had obtained a High School education. He drafted the petition, and sought the help of a local typist 199 TABLE 6.8 SUMMARY OF SOURCES OF CONFLICTS/CONTENTION BETWEEN THE KUHASI METROPOLITAN AUTHORITY AND MARKET TRADERS YEAR 1985 1989 1991 1992 SOURCE OF CONFLICT 1 . Poor Infrastructure 2: 2. State Taxation of Workers at and Traders 3. Accountability for World Bank Funds 4 . Gender/Hork-related facilities 3: x x x x 2: x x x x x x Source: Compiled and formulated from fieldwork data, 1992. 200 (Commissioner of Oath/thary Public"), for a typed copy. The secretary read the final copy to the members of the executive committee, and each of them either signed their names or thumbprinted. These procedures made the document official, for and on behalf of the GTA. After preparing the petition, market traders' next step was a strategy for presenting it to influence public opinion on the policies of the local state. They usually had a two- prone approach: first, to organize a demonstration throughout the principal streets of the city on their way to presenting the petition to the offices of the local state (the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority); and second, by presenting copies to the press houses in the city. Such strategies provided them photo opportunities to get their message out to the public. However, among the press houses, it was the Pioneer which generally covered the activities of the market traders. It was the only newspaper in the country which was privately-owned, and historically aligned itself with groups that were opposed to state policies. Although the public-owned newspapers received copies of the petitions, a content analysis of the Qaily Graphic and The Ghanaian Times revealed that they occasionally covered such stories, and even when they did reported on them, they castigated them in negative tones. Ironically, they were sycophantic and sympathetic of the state policies the market traders complained about. Thus, through its control of the press, the state also diffused attention from the popular 201 struggles of ordinary Ghanaian workers, especially market traders, to seek redress to their problems. The 1985 Petition In a letter dated May 14, 1985, the General Traders Association sent a petition to the Executive Chairman of the Eumasi City Council (now the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority). 1. Sanitation at the Eumasi Central Market is very poor as the Council laborers are not sweeping the market regularly. This often produces unhealthy atmosphere, and we the traders often have to do the sweeping and clearing of refuse all by ourselves. We, therefore, humbly appeal to you for consideration to effect transfer of some laborers to work permanently at the Central Market: 2. There are no fire-fighting implements at the Eumasi Central Market to fight any possible outbreak of fire. As a result of which some goods and stores have often been burnt to ashes. we are, therefore, appealing to you to consider providing us with the necessary firerfighting implements to fight all future outbreak; 3. We are also entreating you to give the necessary directives for the replacement of broken down Iron Bars or Iron Gates from the mouth of the Subin stream entering the market at two points opposite Dr. Mensah's Hospital and Ghana railway Corporation, respectively. Thieves often jump into the streams and pass through the two points and find their way into the market either to steal or hide themselves when being chased by the people; 4. 500 Association members were ejected from.Eejetia, and that the Regional Secretary has granted permission for resettlement of the traders at the “French Line" where dumped refuse were removed. we are, therefore, appealing to you to consider giving your assent for its implementation as it will raise revenue for the Council; 5. Our monthly rates have been increased from C 45 to C 200 per store, and from C 20 to C 100 per stall, and we still have to pay additional C 5 a day for any small table put infront of the stall or store, and therefore, appeal to you, and beg you for reduction of the rate; 6. The market gates were usually closed at 6 p.m. everyday to avoid possible entry of thieves into the market at night. This method worked considerably as market thefts were greatly reduced. Unfortunately, this order has been reversed, and people have to remain at the gate as late as 8 p.mm Thieves have, therefore, been raiding the market. We are, therefore, entreating you to consider reversing the 202 closing time to 6 p.m. to clear away all thieves and to enable the watchmen to go about their normal duties to arrest all suspected thieves after 6 p.mm [Emphasis mine] From the records of the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority (EMA). I gathered that this petition was received by the Executive Chairman, and subsequently referred it to the Market Committee of the EMA for consideration. However, it literally died through EMA's bureaucratic maze, and no further action was taken on it. I also discovered that the EMA did not have the courtesy to acknowledge receipt of the petition. Nevertheless, the market traders were not deterred by EMA's reaction, and sent them another petition in 1989. The 1989 Petition The petition submitted to the EMA on January 17, 1989, was more poignant, questioning the lack of action on the rehabilitation of the Central Market: “It will be recalled that the former City Council Chairman Lt. Col. Opuni Mensah, assured the association that the werld Bank had voted some money for the rehabilitation of the Central Market, particularly construction of drains and culverts to retrain the entry of water into stalls and kiosks; That when the Chairman was relieving his post as the Executive Chairman, he further told us that the commencement of the work will begin in June, 1988. That to our surprise, the June 1988 has lapsed and nothing has been heard from the Council about the rehabilitation of the market. we by this letter want to know from the Council the date or time the said project will take place; That prior to this assurance, the Council increased rates on the grounds that they will construct EVIP toilet, urinal rooms, etc. which the market has been denied; That because of this development which the Council assured us, we accepted the increase of rates with the hope that the Council will actually undertake the assured projects at the market, but to our dismay, the Council did 203 not fulfil its promise to the traders at the market, and where the Council's revenue is received; That we traders sweep the market and convey the refuse to the dumping places with our own resources instead of the Council's own responsibility; We are further by this letter requesting the Council to disclose to us the rates collected from January 1988 to December 1988, and the development made at the Central Market to enable us to advise ourselves accordingly". This petition had a more confrontational approach indicating the frustrations and seemingly powerlessness the traders felt in trying to get the attention of the local state to deal with problems they faced, and which affected their operations. It seemed quite logical when they appealed to other state authorities in the state bureaucratic structure, including the Ashanti Regional Administration, and the Offices of the Head of State in the capital city, Accra . 1991 Petitions In 1991, the General Traders Association submitted two petitions; one to the Ashanti Regional Investigating Committee, and the Head of State, Flight Lieutenant Jerry John Rawlings. Petition to the Ashanti Regional Investigating Committee (ARIC) The Ashanti Regional Investigating Committee (ARIC) was a local branch of the National Investigating Committee (that was established by PNDC Law No. 2, 1992). It investigated corruption in public office; and the office of the Special Prosecutor was responsible for prosecutions arising from 204 these investigations. under a rather unusual provision, those being investigated by the National Investigations Committee (NIC) had the right to confess and offer 'reparation' to the state in atonement for their crimes. In the first twenty-two months of their operations, the PNDC reported that the NIC collected over C 5 million in reparations (Ray, 1986). The petition to the Ashanti Regional Investigating Committee was designed to request investigation into alleged corruption and misappropriation of world Bank funds for the rehabilitation of the Central Market, as well as to demand accountability for the monies collected from the traders. The petition addressed these issues: 1. That the former Executive Chairman of the Eumasi City Council, Lieutenant Colonel Opuni-Mensah once said to us that after his transfer, we must question any new Executive Chairman if within six months of his office he fails to develop the Central Market because the world Bank earmarked an amount of money for the development of the Central Market; 2. That, when the present Metropolitan Secretary, Commander Yaw Mensah came to office, we consulted him for the development of the market, but he did not mind us since then; 3. That due to the failure to develop the market, we suffer rain floods resulting in the destruction of our goods in our stores and stalls in the market; 4. That, our store rent has been raised from C 600 a month to C 1,200 and then from C 1,500 to C 3,000, and then from C 3,000 to C 6,000; 5. That, despite these huge increases in rents, we also pay C 50 for the goods inside the stores, and also C 50 for the goods displayed in front of the stores daily; 6. That, despite such huge rents and rates collected by the EMA from.the traders in the market, they failed to develop the market to save our goods from floods; 7. That, we undertake repairs and renovations of our stores and also employ our own laborers to sweep the market with our own resources, despite the huge amount of money collected from us by the EMA; 205 8. That, we do not benefit from the huge amount collected by the EMA but they make use of the money collected from us for nothing; 9. That, we ask the Committee to investigate into these our cases for justice to be done. We also appeal to the Committee to reduce our high rents for us.“ My investigation revealed that the NIC did not investigate the EMA as requested by the traders. Initially, when the NIC was established at the beginning of the Rawlings' "revolution“, the target was public servants who were associated with the previous civilian administration (Limann's government, from October 1979, to December 31, 1981), and not the political functionaries of the PNDC. In addition, both the NIC and the EMA were chaired by military officers. I suspected that the comradeship among the mdlitary officers made the NIC overlook the traders' allegations of corruption within the EMA, for the purposes of political expediency. Petition to the Head of State On October 8, 1991, the General Traders Association sent a petition to the Head of State which specified basic problems their members faced in the market: We have learnt with dismay, the publication in the Pioneer, 13th September, 1991, whereby the EMA had voted C4.3 million solely to provide public address system to provide music and other information to the traders at the Central Market. And we wish to state that we object to such a project for the following reasons: 1. That, the said amount could be utilized to provide fire extinguishers at vantage positions in the market; 2. To provide day-care center since there is no such facility in the market and urinals; 206 3. To desilt the choked gutters in the market to avoid floods during rainy season, and also to avoid any epidemic; 4. To repair all the broken down telephone system in the market. The repair will enable EMA to communicate any information to traders and the staff of the Authority; 5. That EMA should liaise with the Ghana Railway Authority to resettle traders squatting near the railway lines. There is every possibility that in the event of derailment, there will definitely be heavy casualty of human lives among the squatters; 6. That we appeal to the EMA to allow the traders to renovate their stores without exhorting any money from them which goes into private pockets; In respect of the nwmerous rates paid by the traders, it is high time that EMA reviews them, We appeal to the PNDC to ensure that EMA initiates discussions on the reduction of rates to forestall any possible public demonstration by the traders. The rates of each stall or store have been arbitrarily increased to over 150 percent; Since the appointment of Metropolitan Secretary to Eumasi we have observed that, as a result of his poor leadership, no development has taken place in the market. We experience seasonal floods, the market is dirty, the gutters have been choked, and he is not tolerant to discuss the basic problems facing traders. At the moment, there are no keys to most of the gates leading to the market; As traders and citizens of Ghana, we can no longer accept him as our Secretary in Eumasi, and we fervently appeal to the PNDC to relieve him of his post. we want to finally inform you that the presence of the Metropolitan Secretary in the person of Naval Captain Yaw Mensah is retarding progress and hampering trading business of individuals in Eumasi. The earlier he is transferred from Eumasi the better, so that the PNDC could get a competent person to organize to support the good cause and assist the people who live in peaceful and honest atmosphere in Eumasi." The highest appeal any person or group could make in Ghana is to the Head of State. I did not know how the traders figured this out. On the part of the traders, this was an extra effort, since the offices of the Head of State is in the capital city, Accra, about one hundred and eighty miles from Eumasi. The traders sent a delegation to Accra to present this petition. 207 According to the traders, the Head of State assured them that he would look into the matters presented in the petition. However, nine months after the traders presented their petition, the Metropolitan Secretary, Naval Captain Yaw Mensah, was dismissed, and replaced by a non-military native from the Ashanti Region, Nana Akwasi Agyeman. Thus, state power was directly and indirectly used to appease an irritant group, a move which was calculated to further consolidate PNDC's legitimacy both in the Ashanti region, but Eumasi Metropolis in particular. 1992 Petition to the Ashanti Regional Secretary The GTA also sent a petition to the Ashanti Regional Secretary regarding EMA's tax revenues on January 15, 1992: “That, we have learnt with dismay the unprecedented yearly increase of market stores/stores monthly rentals ‘without considering matters affecting our welfare; That, we also appeal against the act of collecting daily rate of C 50 in the stores, and another C 50 for goods displayed just infront of the same store by the same storekeeper, while the same storekeeper pays a monthly rental as well. A tenant is obliged to pay for his/her monthly rental but does not pay additional money for /her personal belongings in the room to the landlord. Therefore, the daily collection of fees in the stores must be avoided by the EMA to give way to the monthly rentals only; That, on July, 29, 1991, our Executive members had a meeting with the EMA. At the meeting, we resolved that the EMA should avoid the daily collection of tickets inside the store, and stick to the monthly rentals only. The EMA agreed and promised to convene a meeting to resolve this matter, but never fulfilled this promise; That, a penalty for C500 for late payment of monthly rentals must be avoided in view of the fact that a trader could easily fall sick, and be admitted to a hospital, or be involved in funerals, etc. which does not need punishment; That, all our appeals to EMA to improve the drainage system at the Central Market have been to no avail, and this gives rise to a flooded market during the rainfall which destroys many of our wares; 208 That, many of the stores/stalls roofing were rotten and leaked profusely to soak our stock of goods in the stores/stalls but our appeals to the EMA for renovation proved futile. we therefore renovated the stores/stalls ourselves. and raised the level of the floors a bit against the flood with our scarce resources with approval and authority from EMA. Surprisingly, the EMA instead of refunding all our expenses involved has chosen to raise the monthly rentals of all the renovated stores/stalls from C1,600 to C 3,000, without considering hoW'much we spent on the renovation works. We therefore vehemently appeal against this uncalled for, and arbitrary increases which seriously affect our welfare and trading activities; That, of all these collections by EMA, there are no amenities like places of convenience for traders inside the market while the drainage system is still worse; We, therefore, humbly appeal to the PNDC regional Secretary for Ashanti to intervene on our behalf for a redress of these anomalies and predicament: a) Revoking the daily collection of C50 and stick to 5 3 E monthly rentals of C1,6000 for traders in stores and stalls; b) Daily C50 collection to affect only traders using tables on the open space; c) Revoking the new'monthly rental of C3,000 on the renovated stores/stalls to the normal rental of C1,600; We, therefore, conclude by appealing to the PNDC Regional Secretary to take immediate steps to remedy the situation to avoid any possible confrontation between us and EMA. After exhausting all possible avenues to seek redress to their problems, Central Market traders mobilized other traders in the city, and resorted to direct confrontations and violence means to achieve their ends: Angry response from traders in Eumasi's Central Market and Asafo Market has forced the Eumasi Metropolitan Authority to suspend the across-the-board increases of more than a hundred percent in the rent it charges for market stalls and shops. Following the announcements of the increases, the traders marched to protest through the principal streets to the offices of the EMA to present a petition against the increase. The demonstrators who carried placards, some of which read -we are fed up with dictatorship", "Why cheat, National Democratic Congress?', hooted and threw stones at the Chief Executive, Nana Akwasi Agyeman, when he attempted to address them, The EMA called in the police who dispersed the traders with teargas and warning shots. When he announced the EMA's decision to suspend the increase, Mr. Agyeman said the move was to allow 209 the matter to be discussed with the traders. He said that the decision to suspend the increases was the result of appeals from the Ashanti regional branch of the National Democratic Congress (NDC), traders, prominent personalities, and organizations in the region" (west.Africa, 15-21 February, 1993:254). So far, the foregoing petitions have provided ample illustration of problems market traders faced in the context of global/state restructuring. It has also been demonstrated that their attempts to appeal directly to different levels of the state bureaucracy for redress, yielded very limited success. The next section provides an analysis of the major issues in the traders' petitions. Analysis of Mejor Issues in the Traders' Petitions Table 6.8 provides a summary of the issues over which market traders petitioned the state bureaucracy in the 1985- 1993 period. The major issues that stood out consistently throughout the period were poor infrastructure, state taxation of urban workers/traders, accountability for werld Bank funds for market rehabilitation, and ‘engendering' of the workplace. 1. Poor Infrastructure Market traders were displeased with the conditions of the physical and social infrastructure in the Central Market. Specifically, these included the drainage system, sanitation, provision of water, roof leakage, absence of washrooms, day-care, and health care facilities, and security in the market. 2H) a. The Drainage System The drainage system involved provision of outlets for rain water to flow out of the market. The drainage system was not well maintained. The drains had been choked with wastes from the activities of market traders, as well as sand which had been washed into the drainage system, resulting in offensive odors. The drains were blocked, and hence water could not flow easily out of the market. The market traders complained about the damage caused to their commodities whenever it rained, and the market became flooded. Whenever the market became flooded, water would enter their stalls/stores, and soak the commodities packed in boxes. They filed reports with the Market Manager about the drainage problem they faced. However, the EMA did nothing about their drainage problems. In order to forestall .further damage, some of the market traders used their own money to hire workers to clear the choked drainage in front of their stalls/stores. They blamed the EMA for not clearing the drainage system on a daily basis. When I discussed the drainage problem with officials of the EMA, especially the Chief Engineers office, they acknowledged that they had received complaints from the market traders, but they interpreted the problem from a different perspective. They in turn blamed the market traders for the poor state of the drainage system, They felt 211 market traders deposited some waste in the drainage system which caused the drains to be choked. Consequently, the EMA had not taken the drainage problem seriously since the market traders were the source of the problem, Apparently, both the market traders and the EMA did not see eye to eye on the issue of the poor drainage system in the Central Market. b. Sanitation Apart from the drainage system, another problem.in the market was sanitation. The nature of operations undertaken in the market makes it imperative to seek effective ways for maintaining acceptable levels of sanitation in the market environment by controlling the disposal of wastes of all kinds. wastes in the market were produced by both traders and customers. They included materials such as leaves and papers for wrapping commodities on sale, peels from fruits, and leftover food. The high humidity experienced in the city promotes rapid decay when garbage piled up in the market, thus creating unwholesome conditions for business activities. To ensure effective sanitation in the market, the EMA bye-laws stipulate that: "Every occupier of a stall/store during his/her occupation thereof shall keep the same in a clean state, and shall brush, sweep or otherwise clean all dirt and rubbish before leaving, at the end of the day's selling" (1988 Local Government Bulletin, Appendix A). In 212 addition to market traders cleaning and sweeping the immediate area of their business activities, EMA conservancy workers were, however, responsible for the collection of the garbage deposited in designated spots in the market. In the market I observed that huge deposits of garbage sat in designated spots inside the market but had not been removed for days. I discussed the problem of sanitation in the market with officials of the Medical Officer of Health's (MOH) department in the EMA. They acknowledge the general sanitation problem in the market. They. however, explained their inability to maintain effective sanitation, particularly clearing the huge deposits of garbage inside the market was due to lack of conservancy laborers, and inadequate tools. V The Supervisor of the conservancy laborers in the MOH's office revealed that in the 1985-1988 period, the labor force in his department was cut down from thirty workers to fifteen workers, a reduction of fifty percent, although the use of the market, and the volume of activities in a market which covered an area of 9.6 hectares, remained the some. In addition to the retrenchment of conservancy workers, the supervisor identified lack of adequate tools to clean the market. workers needed equipment such as 'wheelbarrows', 'pushcarts", and brooms, but budget cuts in the MOH's department, had made it virtually impossible to replace worn out equipment workers needed to achieve satisfactory i sanitation in the market. 213 c. Provision of water in the Market The City Engineer's department was responsible for providing water for traders and customers in the Central Market. Each section was supposed to have at least one standing pipe to provide water for those who needed it. However, most of the public pipes in the market had broken down. Out of the twenty pipes in the market, only eight, that is forty percent of them, were in good condition. My survey of market traders revealed that forty-one percent obtained water from the public pipes in the market, while forty-six percent purchased water from‘water vendors. The rest, (thirteen percent) brought water from home, or purchased water from traders who had erected their own private stand pipes. The traders felt the EMA had to repair the old pipes, as well as increase the number of pipes in the market to serve them.and their customers. However, the EMA did not invest any money in the provision of pipe-borne water in the market for the period under study. d. Leakage in Roofs of Stalls/stores The roofs of the market stall/stores were supposed to be maintained by the Chief Engineer's Office of the EMA. Some of the roofs had become worn out and leaked. Thirty percent of traders I interviewed indicated that they had leaked roofs in the past. They demonstrated that leaked 214 roofs caused damage to their commodities whenever it rained, as water dripped into their stalls/stores. When I inquired about what they did with the leakage problem, they indicated that they reported it to the Market Superintendent. The Market Superintendent acknowledged that in all he received eighty reports from.market traders in the period under study. However, the EMA could fix only twenty percent of the reported cases. The traders whose roofs were not repaired by the EMA hired private companies to fix them at their own expense. The EMA refused to pay refunds for these repairs which on the average amounted to C 20,000 per store/stall. e. washrooms The Central Market lacked places of convenience. There were no washrooms inside a market which attract more than 20,000 people on a daily basis. There was only one toilet facility outside the market, but due to incessant and frequent usage, it was always full, and not well maintained; the tanks were full and overflowing. Traders complained that even when it was cleaned, they had to wait in long queues to gain access to the washroom, I observed that in the absence of adequate toilet facilities, both traders and customers to the market used a stream.which passed through a section of the market as a place of convenience. However, the EMA disapproved the use of the stream as a place of convenience, because of the environmental hazards it posed for other users of the market. 215 f. Market Security and Safety The market faced three security problems. The first was the lack of equipment for emergency fire outbreaks. Fire outbreaks in the past had claimed the property of some market traders. The major outbreak they remembered most occurred in 1987. Fire engulfed 120 stores in two sections of the market. The fire started late in the night, when market activities had ended. By the time the fire service personnel arrived, the fire had engulfed store/stalls in two sections of the market. Market traders lost their commodities, but had no insurance to cover the loss. Insurance premiums were unknown among the market traders and, therefore, they could not recover their losses. However, they blamed the EMA for not providing fire-fighting equipments for such emergencies, as well as the lack of telephone facilities in the market. The EMA renovated the burnt stores, and reallocated them to the affected store/stall occupants. However, the EMA refused to pay for any losses the affected market women incurred. The second security problem was related to broken down market gates. Six of the market gates had broken down, but had neither been repaired nor replaced by the EMA. Thieves took advantage of the damaged gates and made away with traders commodities in the night. For instance, on July 8, 1985, thieves broke into the stores of two traders, namely, Mr Yaw Apan, and Mrs Comfort Tosu. The thieves made away ‘with approximately C 104,000 worth of commodities, and were l “ . - . . . . . 4 - . m ’ T " — W i w 216 never apprehended (The Pioneer, July 9, l985:l). The EMA neither compensated these traders for the losses, nor replaced the gates immediately. In fact, it took the EMA more than twelve months to repair three of the damaged gates. Finally, the EMA had failed to enforce bye-laws regarding the operating hours of the market. The market was supposed to be closed at 6 pm, and all traders and customers alike were expected to leave at that time. However, some traders remained at the market far into the night. In fact, some were reported to have done their cooking and washing in the market past 6 pm. Market traders complained that those who remained in the market after the posted hours posed a security risk to other traders. They were suspected to have been accomplices of criminal activities in the market. The market traders demanded that the EMA enforce the operating hours of the market to reduce the potential for thieves to use traders who overstayed as a coverup to steal traders' commodities in the night. Thus, one of the sources of contention between market traders and the EMA was poor conditions of the physical and social infrastructure in the Central Market. The roofs leaked, the drainage system had collapsed, and the sanitation was generally appalling. The market also lacked day-care centers for the children of the traders. In addition, security in the market was less than desirable: it 9 . ! I 4.- Ir 1 S 217 lacked fire-fighting equipment to control fire out-breaks in emergencies, and its gates were broken, and provided opportunities for thieves to steal market traders' commodities. Traders who lost their commodities through floods, roof leakage, and theft or fire, did not receive any compensation for their losses, since insurance for small- businesses in the market and the Ghanaian society, is not common. The critical question that has to be addressed here is why the conditions of the physical and social 3 infrastructure in the market had deteriorated. Definitely, even before the local government fiscal restructuring, market conditions were not in good shape. In the 1970-1980 period when Ghana experienced one of its worst economic crises, conditions in the market also declined. However, the SAP, and its attendant effect on local state restructuring, exacerbated the deplorable market conditions with its emphasis on manpower retrenchment, austere fiscal measures, and benign neglect. The revenues it generated were used to finance the state bureaucracy. 2. State Taxation of workerslTraderg State control of workers' incomes and earnings also became a bone of contention. under periods of economic crisis, and regimes of adjustment, the state.uses all possible means to extract revenues from the society, particularly through taxation. J . u a m fi m W 218 As a landlord, the EMA maintains a monopoly over all decisions pertaining to public markets. In fact, it is not supposed to consult with market traders before initiating any increases in its rents for market stalls/stores. Decisions and policies affecting market rents are fixed by resolution of the EMA, on behalf of the Ministry of Local Government. In the 1984-1991 period, the EMA introduced substantial increases in rents for market stalls/stores in all public markets under its jurisdiction. As discussed in an earlier section of this chapter, rent increases for the Central Market were quite high and unprecedented in the history of market trading. The issue of taxing market traders for expanding the space in their stalls/stores began in 1985, and at that time generated controversy between market traders and the EMA. It seemed to me that the traders had a point in challenging the intentions of the EMA. In crafting such a policy, the EMA assumed that the addition of a table infront or inside a store/stall would necessarily increase sales for traders. In fact, for the first time in the history of the market, the EMA decided to implement such a policy. Apart from using it as a means to generate extra tax revenues, it seemed quite unfathomable why the city government should draft such a policy. After all, these stalls/stores were relatively smaller, and had not been expanded since they were first constructed more than half a century ago. Thus, the extra 219 fees the EMA charged were unwarranted, and mere excuse to extract more revenues from the traders. It goes to show that the state uses every means possible to exact revenues from the people. The controversy over fees for late payment of monthly rents was a more difficult one. Market traders gave several excuses why they could not pay rents on time, on certain occasions. Unlike the united States where people could pay their debts in cash, check/money order/bank draft, credit card, and other means, the only means to pay one's debt, W particularly rent, was in person, and cash. Whether it was an alibi or for fact, traders explained that sometimes they could not pay their rents on time due to their commitment to Ghanaian traditional customary practices such as attending funerals, and visiting sick family members in their hometown and other parts of the country. In Ghana, funeral celebrations sometimes extend over a fortnight, and family members are expected to stay as long as the grieving period can take. In fact, a family member who deviates from these norms could be sanctioned severely. The main challenge is that when these traditional practices come face to face with the ethos of modern and urban society, with emphasis on individuality and conformity to bureaucratic virtues, some Ghanaians are caught in the middle, and this was the dilemma some market traders had to deal with. Thus, the EMA took advantage of this situation to further exploit the market 220 traders by imposing penalties for late payments of rents. From the foregoing analysis, it has been shown that the state, both at the national and local levels, utilized all possible means to exploit the “nation“, especially poor working urbanites to support the state apparatus. For market traders, it has been shown that the state intruded their private and public lives with too many taxes. These included basic rates (locally called 'lampoo', a tax for every adult fifteen years and over), rent increases, licenses, tax for enlarging one's stall/store space, and tax for late payment of rents. In addition to the tall order of taxes, market traders were affected by other fiscal policies of the state. Privatization of social services, such as education and health care meant that market traders, like other workers in the society, had to pay more for their children's education and health care. Liberalization of prices, and removal of state subsidies for imported food commodities and energy had increased the cost of living in Ghana. On the average, A Ghanaian household spent over fifty percent of its income on food. Energy costs also increased remarkably, to the tune of eighty percent. Rates for water were also raised by between 150 and 1,150 percent (werld Bank, 1987). Historically, state exploitation of the "nation" through taxation and other strategies of revenue-generation to support state apparatus and the “hypertrophy of the 221 service sector" is well documented. The colonial state used it even in more sophisticated and complex form through its linkages to the metropolis-satellite nexus (Kay, 1972; Frank, 1967). In post—colonial Ghana, especially under the PNDC, contrary to the rhetoric of state officials that the state apparatus was being downsized, it actually became bigger. In particular, the PNDC created so-called "revolutionary" institutions and structures that duplicated the work of existing public institutions and bureaucracies. For instance, apart from the traditional courts in Ghana, new legal institutions, such as “public tribunals“ were established under the guise of ensuring "swift justice" in the country. At the district levels, apart from the head of the civil service in the locality, the PNDC also appointed its own District Secretaries. Institutions such as the National Investigation Committee (not mentioning its regional offices), Citizens Vetting Committees, which investigated persons whose lifestyles and expenditures exceeded their known or declared incomes (PNDC Law No. 1, Section 4), and the National, and Regional, District, Town/Village Defence Committees, to mention but a few, all enlarged the cost of managing the affairs of the country, and made existing structures virtually redundant. Of course, this expansion of state apparatus was designed to give state officials control and influence over every facet of the civil society. In addition, through these processes, the l I ~ - . “ ” 0 ‘ i - l 222 PNDC rewarded its political functionaries at the national, regional, district, and town/village levels. The irony was that these new structures were established through ”proclamations and decrees' of the PNDC, without any discussion by the public. However, in the end, the state had to tax the “nation" to sustain its huge bureaucracy which continued to grow, although its officials believed they were actually downsizing it. In addition to maintaining the state bureaucracy, the state was constrained under a dire necessity to fulfill its commitment to International Financial Institutions (IFIs), such as the werld Bank and the IMF. As discussed earlier in this chapter, Ghana's debts and debt service had increased sharply in the period of the SAP; from 26 percent in 1983 to 53 percent in 1987. In 1990, the figure rose to 65 percent (Frimpong-Ansah, 1992:152). This meant that for every dollar earned from exports, Ghana paid sixty-five cents to IFIs to service its debt. One therefore wonders how the state could finance a huge bureaucracy, and pay a substantial portion of its foreign earnings to service its debts, and still afford to provide adequate infrastructure and services for the "nation“. Consequently, the deterioration of physical and social infrastructure in Ghana, including those raised in the petitions of the Central Market traders, should be seen in a larger context of development crises, and contradictions within the state itself, exacerbated by both ! ? t a E - " 1 2 . 223 internal and external forces . Accountability for world Bank Funds The market traders also questioned the EMA to account for world Bank Funds for rehabilitating the Central Market. Apparently, they felt the EMA had something to hide in the deal between the Ghana government and the werld Bank for refurbishing the Central Market. Infrastructural Development in the Eumasi Central Market was part of the urban Two Prggpmm designed to “enhance the economic and social prosperity of the Eumasi Central area to improve the quality of the environment“. under the SAP agreement, the WOrld Bank was supposed to provide funding for this project, and other projects in the country, to ensure efficient returns to the investments and commitments the Bank was making in the country. According to the traders, they had a wind of the project in the newspapers, and it was later confirmed by the Metropolitan Secretary in 1987, who assured them that the project would commence in June, 1988. In fact, the final report on the Central Market Project was completed in March, 1993, and it is still subject to the approval of both the Ghana government and the world Bank. However, it was not explained to them that the project would have to go through several phases before final approval. It is not uncommon in Africa and other countries, for politicians to use projects as ] E . W W 1 f 224 political weapons, although these projects are paid for with public funds. Unfortunately, market traders who faced £25; problems regarding infrastructure in the market needed a quick fix to their problems, rather than depend on the empty “ promises and rhetoric of politicians. The critical questions that arise from the experience of the Central Market project are, to what extent did the state involve the market traders in its negotiations with the werld Bank? How'much will it cost to rehabilitate the Central Market? When will the project actually begin? Where will the market traders do business when the project takes off? I did not get specific answers to these questions from both the EMA, and world Bank officials. The main source of market traders' frustration was that they were left out of the picture, and were therefore left to ask only questions. This is a problem of the African state, particularly in Ghana. The state tends to alienate the people in decision making that affects their lives and day- to-day existence. It is an institution that takes its people for granted, and therefore, does not seek input from them. The fact that the market traders questioned the intentions of the local state regarding the market rehabilitation project, and demanded accountability, demonstrates an increasing awareness and consciousness, and the (re)emergence of civil society in Ghana. 225 Gendeerbrk-Related Facilities Finally, the traders made demands for the provision of day-care facilities in the Central Market. The idea of day- care centers is a good one. If market traders could send their children to a day-care center, they could have more time to concentrate on their business activities. Young children need a lot of attention, and their presence in the market distracted their parents' attention. In the market, I observed that some women brought their pre-school children along with them to do business. They were tied to the backs of their mothers, in the traditional African fashion of carrying babies. These women stood in the scorching sun with the children for several hours, while they sold their commodities. Those.who were fortunate to have stalls/stores had a place to lay these children when they slept. Sometimes the former arranged with the latter for space to put their children to sleep, while they competed with other traders in the open spaces in the market for customers. When asked why they sent their children to the market, there were different responses. Some indicated that they could not afford to pay for the private day-care centers in the city. Others mentioned that they preferred to have their children with them, since they could give them better care than the day-care centers. Others preferred to have a family member to take care of their pre-school children at home, but they had none in the city, and ! 2 — ! " ! 2 “ 1 ' " ” 7 5 226 therefore, had to carry their children to work. I realized that some older children took care of their younger siblings in the market after school hours in the afternoon, while their parents did business, and others sold some commodities. It gave them a hands-on experience in the art of trading, a real ‘job-training' and a headstart, which they needed for their own businesses in the future. It is interesting to note that the demand for day-care facilities is a work/gender-related issue, which women in Ghana, and other African countries, and even in the united States, have had to deal with. In the case of Ghana, although there is a need for more day-care facilities, it has not become a major public issue compared to the united States. Majority of Ghanaian women (seventy percent) live in the rural areas, and receive a lot of support from extended family members. However, for urban women, there have been some changes in the society which have affected their access to extended family members or maids to help them in child- care. Market women I interviewed.mmntioned that extended family members they brought from.the village to help them, had opted to go to school, and were, therefore, not at home at the time they had to go to the market to do business. Second, since they were self-employed, they did not have the option of negotiating with their employers for some allowance to send their children to private day-care centers. In fact, women in the civil service and private 227 sector employees, still do not have any allowance to pay for day-care for their children. So for the urban Ghanaian woman, like other women in modern societies, the dual role of caring for children, and pursing a career, is still a dilemma and a challenge. Thus, the traders' demand for day-care facilities in the Central Market was not only a service they felt the state should provide for mainly women workers through the taxes the former collects from them, but also demonstrates the increasing significance of a problem.which needed a national, rather than a local solution. In this chapter, two major arguments have been advanced. First, I articulated the view that global restructuring processes have redefined the structure, functions, and sources of revenue of state and local government institutions. Second, it has been argued that these processes have engendered a bone of contention between the state and civil society, as demonstrated by the conflict between market traders and central/local state institutions in Ghana. V What stood out in these processes was that inspite of their limitations, market traders mobilized their members and challenged large and powerful state bureaucracies, and sought redress for their problems, as well as demanded accountability for taxes extracted from theme This demonstrated a (re)emergence of civil society; an important 228 element of the larger I'democratization" process that is going on from the "bottom.up" in Ghana. "‘7llfilifllflfllfliiflWWW . " _—\o‘ a ‘ . ' ‘ , . a v . V . u: . (h .. ' , V . A ‘ £13“ 3;}; 31 p ,. 3' 33%“: 715$" 91313 ”3.21m " , a ‘ ;, - g; . $441,; . .{._ 2:”.wiglhi' I Aaififigfif . $4315 'fK'i' ma; 0.1 .3115. “a 5 3}} mt‘i "‘ ."il; ‘ q}. , 5L, IQ "‘9‘” ‘9 ' (a ,4; r -R-“‘gb.< Al. A . ‘. v fit a" . ‘1‘ . M; "12 air u .. a ,3. . '3'» #3? M“ 'Ffi , ‘I ‘ " . . ‘ J‘ . ‘ _ ‘ , , '~"\"5’ " - --. g L .3: 5‘7 , u v “ 3, .r 73“???“ ‘ “ w'ahgwf $1,, l 1 1 i’i‘ifi‘i . ‘ Wxflb’: 3““ ‘ 5mm.- V: ’ 7 . . , 7 . . . ,t 4. ‘ r . _ . mm. -‘ in 7 A ',.‘ . ‘ V ' ,1 V ' , > ; , . a x ~ In “*5 :i":~v‘w «4 ‘ ~ . . , . . . A ' ~ ‘ .w ‘ 9 ‘ - I. 1. ‘fi'i‘figfifi'fi‘ . I , ; - ‘ ~ «v , . 5 f ! .. 0 in l . .; 2' 5 ,1 a 1» I ' ‘ -’ “ i . ,i .;v t . l . r7 r} ‘ l . . Ir I » , ,_ l; . : . 3% «xflufiaxuxuz 932:. ‘. "WWW" . '36"‘;'\"' .b‘fisffil’?’ A.“ 1&ng a‘fi“ :33“ ' ~ ”é; mfikfifi‘c‘? Baa-i? ' "g? ' i’ 4"" KEV-{MW-fiéik’fiz‘ 3 ", K‘ ‘ ‘n, ‘ u.v«.;b.5«<+;a- we: ‘ gawk?" ‘“ ‘1‘: ‘5 5:: '.‘ g! 7‘ #‘x «3mm #46,! 'l" :1 Ra‘s" '. “may :4“. 7' 1 *«mw ' “Md: ’- .‘ff’IEuz' LV m .u ”givpfi‘fi. ‘llv , . =":§5'.fl.‘*5u, u." 'M‘FJ‘Q'.’ ”\H‘ .,‘ f -' K?" .1 . . n.3,, . l “ ‘33"? #33 ‘ ’ a; . .».1)qu 3;“ '.;.‘..~ ' .» - “ ‘ g I ‘ , “7.; ,1": . “2.7 , ~h - ‘1” f") ' A gym - . “if ‘3“ “v 4% . " k“ '3" ‘ W ‘1"“- , ”:33 ‘\‘ ‘1 G " , a . 1. '-' ' u J '5. ‘ fi‘fm? iV 32.1%.;1 :1 , t Us? ' 1 .’ ‘; ' 1: ugf f; “1.; , , “'5' ' .x ':".'¢ 1. 5‘ . 'u {i‘ ‘ "Hive, '5! A— a \,j 3‘ ..4 V: "n u r ‘1‘ t} . , _ I ‘. ~ ‘ . A ' A M .4 : r V,“ v:. V v; ~ a 4' v. . I V 4 . . ‘ ' .' A” {mg ‘ ‘ «1 .gx .. 5 u,' , ' .g‘: . ‘ , A - '. ' P! , . ' .2 _. .. . ‘ . ' . ,‘ I .' ; -z.~ . - ‘ - ‘f , ‘ ‘w , ' ‘ , - ‘ n . J . as. * v LIBRARY Mlchlgan State Unlverslty PLACE ll RETURN BOX to roman this checkout from your mood. TO AVOID FINES Mum on or Moro duo duo. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MSU I. An Affirmative Action/Equal Oppommlty lawman W”9.1 outc vis- trad offi affe inf: redr the iron tale bur: I rE\ I‘evC C Om; CHAPTER SEVEN MARKET TRADER.ACTIVISHIAND DEIDCRATIZATIGN PROCESSES IN'GEKNA INTRODUCTION This chapter has two objectives. First, it assesses outcomes of market trader collective mobilization and action vis-a-vis the local state. Second, it argues that market trader demands including accountability of public/state officials, participation/involvement in decision making that affects their day-to-day lives, physical/social infrastructure that would enhance their businesses, and reduced taxes, should be understood within the context of the larger “democratization" processes that are going on from the I'bottom.up" in Ghana. It must be pointed out that market trader activism.and relationship with the different levels of the state bureaucratic structure should be distinguished from I'revolutions" and I'national revolts“. Regarding social revolutions, Skocpol's formulation is the most recent and compelling: social revolutions are rapid, basic transformations of a society's state and class structures; and they are accompanied and in part carried through by class-based revolts from.below. Social revolutions are set apart from other sorts of conflict and transformative processes above all by the combination of two coincidences; the coincidence of societal structural change with class upheaval; and the coincidence of the political'with social transformation (Skocpol, 1979z4). 229 focus the 8 this struc apprc for a conti Conse to cc subsi defil mohi It i disp "hie aeti Pure PEti asge BhOu Stat 2M) Here, Skocpol's conceptualization of revolutions, focuses on outcomes: sustained and cataclysmic changes in the social structure. However, Walton's (1984) critique of this classical conception of 'revolutions' based on violent structural change is in order. While not denouncing the appropriateness of the criteria used by Skocpol, he argues for a broader conceptualization of a "revolution", as a continuum.whose outcomes may be a matter of degree. Consequently, walton's (1984) “national revolts“ idea seems to convey another level of collective action which has substantial outcomes, but short of a complete revolution. He defines "national revolts" as protracted, intermittently violent, non-local struggles involving large-scale mobilization of classes and status groups that become recognized claimants of rival sovereignty and engage the state in responses with the effect of transforming social or state power in the development process ( walton, 1984z6). unlike “national revolts", market trader collective mobilization and action is local, sometimes violent, but limited in the scale of its effect on the social structure. It is not intended to overthrow the state structure, nor to displace the powers there be. It is a local protest movement which seeks changes in harsh and harmful state policies, actions, and inactions. Although their immediate goal was to pursue their collective interests, as articulated in their petitions, one must look beyond that. A meaningful assessment of the outcomes of market traders' activism should be based on the extent to which they could get the state “off their backs“, and exercised greater self- de1 231 determination in the marketplace. REHABILITATION OF THE KDlmSI CENTRAL MARKET As revealed in chapter Six, market traders consistently complained and petitioned the local state regarding the poor state of existing conditions in the Central Market. So far, some plans are in the works to rehabilitate the Central Market. What was not clear to me in my research was whether the initiative to rehabilitate the Central Market was a direct result of market trader activism, or an idea which was part of the Structural Adjustment Program. Definitely, one could argue that the PNDC did not initially plan on rehabilitating the markets in Ghana; on the contrary, the PNDC took actions which actually led to the demolition of some market buildings in Ghana. For instance, as already demonstrated in chapter One, the state under both Rawlings I (June-September, 1979) and Rawlings II (December 31, 1981 until trade liberalization was introduced in 1983), was quite hostile to market traders. Market traders, mostly women, were caned in public (often naked) for selling above the price controls. Some traders were shot point blank for alleged acts of profiteering practices. The most devastating and glaring incident which symbolized state-market trader hostility was the demolition of the Makola Number Two Market in the capital city, Accra. The market space was developed into a parking lot for Accra elite shoppers. The Kumasi Central Mark: intez Ware and z unde: stat! Egg; stil as p trad deba SAP Inst reco proj dUe t 233 Market, was a target for demolition, but thanks to the intervention of the King of the Ashanti, Nana Otumfuor Opoku ware II, it was spared. Thus, from its own pronouncements and actions, the Rawlings State, had no plans/intention to undertake major market rebuilding projects. The first indication of any intentions of the PNDC state to rehabilitate urban markets was in tandem with the urban Two Program, which I discussed in Chapter Seven. It is still not clear whether this Program was designed initially as part of the SAP, or it evolved in response to market trader activism, The whole SAP was not subject to public debate, and one could not tell the contents of the original SAP package between the PNDC and International Financial Institutions (IFIs). However, according to the available records, the Urban Two Program.was a community development project designed by the Ghana Government, and funded by the world Bank/IMP. Its objective was to renovate old roads, and provide new ones in urban areas, as well as rehabilitate other urban facilities, such as schools and market buildings. Specifically, for the Kumasi Metropolis, it was “to maintain and enhance the economic and social prosperity of the Kumasi central Area, and to improve the quality of the environment“ (Integrated Development Consultants, 1993:1). Given the poor state of urban infrastructure in Ghana due to the economic crisis in the 19703 and early 19803, the Urban Two Program.was long overdue. Improvements in rural and ur] succes: effect, very W1 were d. rehabi and ur? SAP se agricu the ct increa betwee libel-a Ghanaj in thi in tku Ghana the I: Scien. study Cent-r; study marke. 234 and urban infrastructure were critical for the SAP to be successful. In my estimation, before the SAP came into effect, the world Bank and the IMF were in Ghana, and knew very well that the roads were dangerous, and the markets were dilapidated, and yet nothing was done about them. The rehabilitation of roads was necessary to reconnect the rural and urban areas of Ghana to the larger global economy. The SAP seeks to intensify the production of exportable agricultural products such as cocoa, timber, and rubber. On the other hand, the rehabilitation of the roads was to increase the volume of trade between cities, and also between the cities and the rural hinterland, when trade was liberalized, and allowed foreign goods to be dumped on the Ghanaian market. Urban markets have come to play a key role in this nexus, as the brokers between the producers (located in the rural hinterlands, and overseas) and consumers in Ghana and abroad. The Ghanaian Ministry of works and Housing contracted the Integrated Development Consultants at the University of Science and Technology in Kumasi to undertake feasibility study of the Infrastructural Development of the Kumasi Central Market in 1990. The final report of the feasibility study (1993) revealed interesting facts, which confirmed market traders' complaints: Cent: (301181: the p for c compl Sanit Devel. 235 a) The existing infrastructure in the market is obsolete and poor. Water and electricity connections are usually unauthorized and illegal, while telephones and hydrants for fire fighting are virtually non- existent. b) The few toilets in and around the market are all poorly managed, and refuse management is also poor. c) Disposal of surface water runoff after rains is poor due to inadequate drainage system and the silting of the few existing channels. Frequent flooding of the market is a common phenomenon during rains. d) paved surfaces in the market have deteriorated so badly that the market is suffering from severe erosion at some areas and sediment deposition in other areas. e) Most of the stalls are temporary structures, and are in very poor condition (Integrated Development Consultants, (Integrated Development Consultants, 1993z3). Consequently, the report recommended that the Kumasi Central Market should be redeveloped including the construction of two-storey and three-storey buildings, and the provision of other facilities such as day-care center for children of market traders, bank and post office complexes, health post, police post, fire service post, sanitary and relaxation areas, among others (Integrated Development Consultants, 1993:17). In addition, the study report recommended that a company be floated to manage the Central Market, and all the remaining urban and suburban markets in Kumasi. Such a company, they suggested, may be called the Kumasi Markets Development Corporation (KMDC). The company would appraise the viability of individual markets and formulate proposals for their improvements. However, the feasibility study had some weaknesses. First, there was no indication in the report that market re an tr Co: the 236 traders were consulted, and whether their input was sought or not. What was quite clear was that the consultants held preliminary discussions with statutory institutions whose activities related closely to the planning, development, management, and maintenance of the Kumasi Central Area, including the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority, the Survey Department, the Ghana Highway Authority, the Market Manager, and the Town and Country Planning Department in Kumasi. In my estimation, market trader input was critical to the rehabilitation of the Central Market. Why should the consultants be concerned about environmental impact of the project, and therefore undertook an environmental impact assessment, and not a social impact assessment? A sociologicallanthropological study of the impact of the rehabilitation of the market could have been quite helpful. Markets reflect the culture, values, and beliefs of a people. What happens when a market structure is changed by new architectural designs cannot be ignored. For instance, when the Kaneshie Market (Accra) was built based on‘Western architectural designs of enclosed (dome-like) structures, and storey-buildings, it affected market trader-customer relationship. Those whose stalls/stores were closer to the entrance of the Kaneshie Market outperformed their fellow traders. Eventually, most traders refused to sell their commodities inside the market (particularly those who had their stores/stalls on the upper floors), and.moved to do business outside the market. While in Ghana, I saw that the tt ch wc Ka pr f i is in flu 00' th: de} fa: cha tak ent Com reh act. 237 Accra City Council had a problem controlling/regulating these traders, and I found that City Council officials chased recalcitrant traders to go inside the market. I wondered what social impact assessment was done before the Kaneshie Market was constructed in 1970. This should have provided lessons for the architectural designers and financiers of the Central Market rehabilitation project. In addition, one must make a distinction between what is proposed and what may actually happen. It should be borne in mind that the proposed project is contingent upon the flow of funds from the WOrld Bank/IMF to the Ghana Government, and the continuity of the SAP in Ghana. Also, the continuity of the project, once it begins, will be dependent on political stability in the country. Given the fact that the Ghanaian political scene has been characterized by instability since independence, no one can guarantee completion of the proposed project, even if it takes off. Market traders who were interviewed were enthusiastic about the possibility of seeing their dreams come true, but they were concerned with how the rehabilitation process will affect their business activities, and where they would be relocated. petit the r Depar there the t Howev thirt. laid-t RNA. a twenty Proble market that n recour thefts 238 SECURITY IN'THE CENTRAL MARKET Poor security was one of the issues market traders petitioned the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority. According to the report of the Schedule Officer for Security in the Legal Department of the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority (attached), there were twenty-four night watchmen (security guards) for the twenty-four gates of the Central Market in 1984. However, in 1985, during the local government downsizing, thirteen of the watchmen were declared redundant, and were laid-off. By 1992, only four watchmen were retained by the KMA, and were only charged with opening and locking the twenty-four gates at the Central Market. The poor security problem led to several reports of theft in the Central market, which was discussed in Chapter Six. The irony was that market traders whose commodities were stolen had no recourse to seek redress and compensation. In 1990, the traders became wary of the incessant thefts of commodities in the Central Market, and petitioned the Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly for consideration. The Metropolitan Assembly resolved to provide better security at the Central at its own expense. They contracted the services of the Civil Defence Organization (CDC), to beef up security at the market. The CD0 was one of the civil organizations that was formed when the 'PNDC' revolution began. It was armed by the state to defend the PNDC against any counter insurrection from those who were opposed to the 'revolution'. It was the belief of the Metropolitan Assembly that 1 the DE 1 break- trader to ste could by ano 1991, ' textile milliox Compens 8uppose meeting decided Consequ traders the the t°°k st entitle Menorah, 1992, a Private Gr< other t! to the t Since th 239 that they could do a better job of providing security for the market. However, when the CD0 took charge of security, the break-ins, and theft of commodities continued. The market traders suspected the CDO itself for conniving with others to steal commodities in the market in the night; for they could not comprehend how the armed CDO could be overpowered by another group, and break into their stalls/stores. In 1991, three traders lost their commodities (mostly imported textiles), which amounted to over two million cedis (C 2 million). They petitioned the Metropolitan Authority for compensation, since the theft took place while the CDO_was supposed to have provided security for the market. At its meeting held on June 17, 1991, the Metropolitan Assembly decided to pay for the total cost of the stolen commodities. Consequently, the metropolitan Assembly paid the three traders C 2,0005,000.00. The Metropolitan Assembly blamed the theft on the negligence of CD0 personnel, and therefore took steps to redeem the money from the allowances and entitlements for the CD0 personnel (see attached memorandum). It also withdrew the CD0 from the market in 1992, and advised the market traders to seek their own private security guards. Groups of traders whose stores were adjacent to each other teamed up and hired private security guards. According to the traders, this arrangement worked better for them; since the watchmen actually kept guard of the stalls/stores 3882 marl comm trad targ to wt of t] so fa charg discu secur const restr guard Priva great who 8: their raise. Rheul. b? th. thelm “990tj burEat 240 assigned to them, instead of keeping watch over the entire market. The catch was that with this new arrangement, the KMA could not be held accountable for the theft of traders' commodities. In addition, the stores/stalls of market traders who could not afford to hire private watchmen became targets of thieves, as the KMA had only four security guards to watch the twenty-four gates of the Central Market. First, what is the obligation (in this case, security) of the state to private business? According to the traders, so far as they were tenants of the local state, and were charged rents and paid numerous taxes to the state as discussed in Chapter Six, the state was obliged to provide security for their commodities. But given the financial constraints of the local state during the period of state restructuring, and the attendant retrenchment of security guards, there was a breakdown of security in the market. Privatization of security at least gave the market traders a greater control of who would protect their commodities, and who should be held accountable for any losses they make when their goods are stolen in the future. Second, it also raises questions as to why the market, in the first place, should be owned by the state, and not controlled completely by the traders whose daily survival is linked to the market as an institution. The idea of privatizing the'ownership of the market would give market traders a better leeway to negotiate for better services and security, since state bureaucracies in Africa, particularly in Ghana, have proven ac di th Ma A8: ca] 38! Die 241 to be inefficient and self-serving. EMPOWERMENT OP INDIGENOUS BUSINESS ASSOCIATIONS It is heartening to note that indigenous business associations, including market traders, have mobilized at district, regional and national levels to empower themselves to influence the political process in Ghana. Indigenous business associations are defined generally as associations that represent men and women who participate in what is generally considered the "informal” economy. Their activities are based on a localized production and distribution system, with skills and knowledge gained through apprenticeship, and expressed in the local language (ILO, 1972; Warren, 1981, 1986; Amoyaw, 1990). The General Traders Association in the Kumasi Central Market is affiliated with the Federation of Market Traders Associations (FEMATA), which has its headquarters in the capital city, Accra. The FEMATA coordinates market trader associations throughout Ghana, and serves as their mouth- piece at the national level. In 1990, the FEMATA represented market traders, for the first time, at the Constituent Assembly, which deliberated on the modalities for the transition of political power from military rule to civilian rule in Ghana. A major outcome of the Constituent Assembly was a new Ghanaian Constitution in 1992, which among other things, recommended the establishment of the Council for Indige up of baker with t and as activi state. S a diff revenu arrang how th relati arrang from i conven indige Past, CO“limit busine BusPec PrQVio were u be deg 242 Indigenous Business Associations (CIBA). The CIBA was made up of representatives of market traders, auto-repairers, bakers, artisans, among several other groups. It is charged with the coordination of member associations' activities, and assesses how state economic policies affect the activities of its members, and makes recommendations to the state. So far, the CIBA has been successful in negotiating for a different approach/arrangement for collecting state tax revenues (income taxes) from its member associations; an arrangement which gives them a greater self-determination in how they organize their business activities, and in relationship to the state and its agencies. Prior to the new arrangement, collection of state tax revenues (income tax) from indigenous business men and women was done at the convenience of the state agents. First, state agents accused indigenous business men and women of evading taxes in the past. Thus, when the PNDC established the Citizens Vetting Committee in 1982, one of its purposes was to go after businesspeople, especially market traders, who were suspected to have evaded the payment of taxes under the previous regimes. The harassment and brutal tactics that were used to collect taxes from.businesspeople left much to be desired. Ray (1986) reported: in 10. Co] the and Sta One bqu 243 Between its establishment in February 1982 and November 1993, the Citizens Vetting Committee directly resulted in the collection of 166.3 million cedis, out of an assessed 306 million Cedis. The increase of almost 500 percent in taxes paid by the self-employed between 1980 and 1982 has been attributed to the fear on the part of the self-employed of being caught by the Citizens Vetting Committee (Ray, 1986:59). Although the exaction of taxes from businesspeople has not ceased, the harassment and brutal tactics have become a thing of the past. The CIBA has arranged with the Internal Revenue Services (the former Citizens Vetting Committee) to t - ’ ! exercise control over tax collection from its member associations. For instance, the CIBA presents the names and activities of its members to the Internal Revenue Services, and the latter assesses how much tax CIBA members should pay overall. The bulk sum is then divided up among the CIBA member associations. Unlike the previous practice where businesspeople were expected to pay their annual taxes in bulk, the new arrangement allows them to pay their taxes in installments, spread over a twelve-month period, to their local business associations. It appears that the state bureaucracy benefits from the collection of taxes by the local business associations from their members. Definitely, under a regime of retrenchment and austere measures, such an arrangement could help the state bureaucracy to cut down some overhead costs. However, one must also recognize that for the indigenous businesspeople, including the traders, this was a major step Ur bu 81: Li de: De] th 0f 244 forward in their relationship with the Rawlings' state; a change from complete hostility, suspicion, and harassment, to formal recognition, and self determination of the processes for collecting taxes from their members. Thus, when one looks at these changes from a broader perspective, market traders were able to get the state relatively ‘off their backs'. CIVIL SOCIETY AND DENOCRATIZATIGN PROCESSES IN GHANA The struggle of market traders to seek a more participatory and responsive state system, is not unique. Rather, it illustrates the struggles of Ghanaians as a people for a state which derives its authority to rule from the people, and subject to their control. Groups and associations including the National Union of Ghanaian Students (NUGS)‘, The Trades Union Congress (TUCV, the Ghana Bar Association (GBAYfi the Ghana Medical Association (GMA)‘, the Ghana Nurses Association (GNA)‘, and the University Teachers Association of Ghana (UTAG)‘, to mention but a few, have wrestled with both civilian and military states in Ghana in their search for democratic reforms. Like other countries in Africa, Ghana faces a crisis of democracy. The crisis of democracy has become more crucial in the period of Structural Adjustment Program in Ghana. Outsiders who are unfamiliar with the political history and political of Ghana often associate democracy with the Structural th' We Gh C8 ti ta 245 Adjustment Program. It goes like this: the world Bank and the International Monetary Fund as well as the states in the West which support the Structural Adjustment Program in Ghana initiated the on-going democratic processes (in this case, the return to rule) as one of their conditionalities. The logic of this argument is that without the Structural Adjustment Program, countries such as Ghana, which have taken some steps towards democratic rule, would not have taken that course. This interpretation of what has happened in Ghana is not only erroneous, but also discredits the struggles of Ghanaians for a democratic state system; a struggle which began in the colonial period, and continues unabated. First, when the World Bank and the IMF pushed for economic reforms in the 1970s and the 19808, these institutions said very little about political reforms to match the economic reforms which were being advocated. After much criticism on this issue, the World Bank, in particular, attempted, though inadequately, to address the issue of democracy in its latest study, Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth (1989). Second, as Nyang'oro (1992:22) argues, the inadequate attempt by the WOrld Bank to address the issue of political reforms did not really matter after 1989. As the so-called “democratic movements'I swept through Eastern Europe, cries for democracy were heard throughout Africa. In virtually every African country, there were demands for the creation of multi-party systems where C: re Gh re 246 single party systems once existed. There were also demands for civilian rule in countries under military rule.7 Third, dialectics of authoritarian rule and the harsh conditions associated with the SAP also advanced the cause of democratic systems. Based on dialectics, the emergence of authoritarianism in Africa naturally created its own forms of various types of opposition. In Ghana, for example, there has always been political opposition, both overt and covert, reflecting contradictions in the society. In fact, at any one time, Ghanaian immigrants in Europe and the United States, form.opposition groups, and provide ideological and financial support for the covert and overt opposition groups inside the country. The Structural Adjustment Program itself intensified these conflicts in African societies. The world Bank and the IMF identified with authoritarian systems in Africa for the implementation of austere measures including devaluation of currencies, retrenchment of workers, higher taxes, privatization of public institutions, among others, which were discussed in Chapter Six. The implementation of these measures could only be done in societies where there were no public debates on the issues. Throughout Africa, including Ghana, Nigeria“, and Zaire’, the SAP was introduced in countries which were under “strong“ one party or one-man regimes, or under military regimes. Civilian regimes in Ghana which experimented with any economic policies which relatively were not as harsh as the SAP, never succeeded; in f8CtI th the Busi 1981) "’. dialecti 'revolut conditio process, as the K Movement abandone Rawlings neo-colo Raw dafined P0pulous Should a the Powe Principl evolutic insightf (DECEmbe 247 fact, they were overthrown by the military. One could cite the Busia (1969-1972) regime, and the Limann regime (1979- 1981)”. Rawlings himmelf has had to deal with the dialectics of the SAP by abandoning his own initial “revolutionary" principles and ideology, and yielded to the conditionalities of the world Bank and the IMF. In the process, radical groups with Marxist-Leninist leanings, such as the Kwame Nkrumah Revolutionary Guard and the June Fourth Movement, which began the "revolution“ with Rawlings have abandoned ship, and have joined the opposition against Rawlings. They have opposed the SAP, which they saw as a neo-colonial tool for further exploitation of Ghana. Rawlings has not consistently articulated a well- defined notion of democracy in Ghana. For while he espoused populous views of what form.of democratic system Ghana should adopt, in many instances, the Rawlings state, using the power at its disposal, acted contrary to "democratic" principles. Chazan's (1989:341-345) tracking of the evolution of democratic ideas of the Rawlings state is quite insightful. For instance, she identified three distinct phases of these processes. The first, populous phase (December 31, 1981-April 1983) was the most radical: government policy sought to bring about democratization by incorporating the I'people" into politics both as guardians against elite rule, and contributors to the construction of a “new“ Ghana. To facilitate its goals, the PNDC created a morass of organizations (which I discussed in chapter 6) primaril us'enen. repress ' beating as the " generall religiou entrepre' persecut instance includin overseas the PNDC BuPPOrte Ghana . 248 primarily to carry out its campaign against what it defined as "enemies of the revolution". Their techniques were quite repressive: indiscriminate killings, incarcerations, and beatings of citizens. Civil rights were flagrantly violated as the "authority of the gun ensure that rules were generally obeyed" (Fellow, 1983:16). Professionals, religious leaders, university lecturers, lawyers, entrepreneurs, and ex-politicians, among others, were persecuted and ridiculed. The chain reaction to these instances of abuse of power was mass exodus of Ghanaians, including intellectuals, to other African states, and overseas. Those who remained could not directly challenge the PNDC, and therefore, engaged in covert activities, supported by the opposition that had been built outside Ghana. The second phase of PNDC rule (1983-1986) sought to redirect democratization efforts to the rehabilitation of the economy, and exploring alternative avenues to democratic politics. The PNDC restructured the original defence committees, and redirected their efforts towards local economic development projects. Rawlings replaced all the original members of the PNDC, except himself. This step was necessary in order to purge the PNDC of the “old stock', and replaced them with new ones who were moderates. The new PNDC accepted the conditionalities imposed by the world Bank and the IMF. Politically, the most significant step taken towards democratization was the creation of the National 8e 8t it Di 249 Commission on Democracy in 1986, which was charged with the responsibility to study and collate views on new democratic political institutions based on the traditions, history, and culture of Ghana. Although the intentions of these political steps were commendable, most Ghanaians were suspicious that these acts were designed to prolong the PNDC's stay in power. Student groups opposed the SAP, particularly the fact that government allowances for university students were discontinued, and in its place, they were required to take loans guaranteed by their working parents or relatives. The labor unions also opposed the SAP because it led to the retrenchment of workers, and higher cost of living. The third phase of democratic implementation by the PNDC involved participation in formal political institutions. The National Commission on Democracy recommended District Assembly elections as a first step towards encouraging greater popular participation. The District Assembly elections were depicted as the culmination of efforts ‘to democratize state power and advance participatory democracy and collective decision making at the grassroots' (Republic of Ghana, 1987:1). The District Assemblies have been established in Ghana as local government institutions, and charged with the provision of services to their localities. The irony was that the PNDC still had some influence on these local government bodies: it appointed the District Secretary, who was a member of the District Assembly. T1 prepare country establi Distric unions, deliber They re electio were wa was the constit' functiOJ abuse 0: Th! extent 1 activit; faced we PNDC. t] ”we! t< “tees“ Was the; politice The C°u3titu 250 The second half of the third phase was characterized by preparations for national elections aimed at returning the country to a civilian rule. A Constituent Assembly was established in 1990. It had representatives from the District Assemblies, professional associations, labor unions, and civic organizations. The Constituent Assembly deliberated on the contents of a new constitution for Ghana. They recommended a multi-party democratic system, and elections based on popular vote. While these popular ideas were warmly received by the public, the bone of contention was the recommendation for an indemnity clause in the constitution providing reprieve for the PNDC and its functionaries regarding their atrocities, harassments, and abuse of power, during their stay in office. The critical question that Ghanaians faced was the extent to which the PNDC could be held accountable for its activities between 1981 and 1992. The dilemma Ghanaians faced was that if they insisted on accountability from the PNDC, there was no guarantee that the latter would yield power to the masses. On the other hand, if they were successful in removing the PNDC from office, what guarantee was there that Rawlings and his cronies would not take over political power for the third time? The Trangitional Provisions“ enshrined in the Constitution stated: W3 fi Co: CO] 90‘ an; C0! 0011 bef the it. 199; 251 No member of the Provisional National Defence Council, Provisional National Defence Council Secretary, or other appointees of the Provisional National Defence Council shall be held liable either jointly or severally, for any act or omission during the administration of the Provisional National Defence Council..........For the avoidance of doubt, it is declared that no executive, legislative or judicial action taken or purported to have been taken by the Provisional National Defence Council or the Armed Forces Revolutionary Council12 or a member of the Provisional National or the Armed Forces Revolutionary Council or by any person appointed by the Provisional National Defence Council or the Armed Forces Revolutionary Council in the name of the Provisional National Defence Revolutionary Council or the Armed Forces Revolutionary Council shall be questioned in any proceedings whatsoever and, accordingly, it shall not be lawful for any court or other tribunal to make any order or grant any remedy or relief in respect of any such act (Constitution of Ghana, 1992:201-202). The constitution, including the Transitional Provisions, was put to a referendum in March, 1992, while I was doing my fieldwork. Most of the people voted for the proposed Constitution for varied reasons, but two were quite obvious. On the one hand, those opposed to the PNDC voted for the constitution because it would usher in a new democratic government, and the PNDC would go away. On the other hand, supporters of the PNDC also voted for the provisional constitution because it would grant reprieve to their compatriots. Ironically, the PNDC was not required to resign before the referendum.was conducted. In fact, it supervised the referendum, through institutions it created to organize it. When the ban on party politics was lifted in August, 1992, the PNDC sponsored its own parties, albeit stealthily. These 92 the Eagi resourc' cities a PNDC-fill Kumasi, Ghanaia: candida other p The and Nov Patriot irregul Behedul V011 the Purpose 1993, w Flight Th t0 Civi for mil heinOus in °the Zairels’ with th they di w0uld n 252 These groups included the National Democratic Congress, and the Eagle Party. It allowed these parties to use state resources such as vehicles and personnel, to campaign in the cities and the rural areas. The major party that opposed the PNDC-funded parties was the New Patriotic Party based in Kumasi, and led by Professor Adu Boahen. Rawlings surprised Ghanaians when he declared himself as the presidential candidate for the New Democratic Congress, and absorbed other political parties and civic organizations. The General and Presidential elections held in October and November respectively, were boycotted by the New Patriotic Party because of alleged election irregularities”. Nevertheless, the elections‘were held as scheduled, and needless to say, the Now Democratic Congress, won the elections overwhelmingly. Thus, for all intents and purposes, the rule of the PNDC came to an end on January 4, 1993, when the Fourth Republic was ushered into office, with Flight Lieutenant Rawlings as the new president of Ghana. The problem Ghana faced in the transition from.military to civilian regime, especially the need to provide reprieve for military officers and their cronies who participated in heinous crimes against persons and property, is not uncommon in other African societies. For example, in Nigeria“ and Zaire”, the military governments have had to come to terms with the dilemma others have faced in the past: how should they disengage, and do it in such a way that their past acts would not continue to haunt them?. 253 So far, I have argued that the activism of market traders in the Kumasi Metropolis has been fruitful. The Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly, the Ghana Government and the World Bank have proposed building a new market structure for traders in the Central Market. In addition, the Kumasi Metropolitan Assembly has streamlined payment of compensation for traders who lost their property in the market. However, the traders still have other problems to overcome. First, they have not been able to stop or mitigate the incessant taxes that have resulted from the fiscal crisis of the state in Ghana. The involvement of the traders in the collection of taxes, however, has tremendously abated the harassment of the traders. It has also been argued that the struggles of the market traders in Ghana for a just/democratic society are akin to the struggles of other groups in the society for democratic reforms and justice. Although Ghana has returned to a civilian regime, the struggle continues unabated“. Democracy must be conceptualized, as Diamond (1992) has argued, as more than simply a system or the process of choosing leaders through free political competition, but a way of life, a culture, a set of values based on human dignity. The major challenge Ghana faces is how to harness the democratic ethos that is (re)emerging to providing the material resources for individuals to realize their full human potential in the society. Aluta Continua! 39 IE 04 CHAPTER EIGHT SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS This study investigated how market traders, as human agents, mobilized to articulate their collective interests regarding the policies of central/local state institutions in the Kumasi Metropolis. It was placed within the context of global restructuring and its implications for Ghana. A schema based on the linkages between global restructuring, dependency, central/local state restructuring and community activism, provided the analytical framework for the study. The working propositions for the study were: 1. global restructuring processes redefine the structure, functions, and sources of revenue for state and local government institutions. Consequently, local government institutions become dependent on their communities to generate revenues for their sustenance; 2. conflict between the local government institutions and communities was engendered by the latter's strategies for generating revenues from their communities, as well as their austere measures which led to poor quality of physical and social infrastructure in the community; 3. community activism.was aimed at resisting/protesting state/local government attempts to control their incomes 254 throx phys: Cent: incl‘ and stud gloi poli 195' Intc the the bel Pov enc and ins Com res Gen Gen 0f 255 through increased taxes, and demanding improvements in physical and social infrastructure in the local community. The focus of the study was market traders in the Kumasi Central Market, in Ghana, West Africa. The research design included survey, interviews, documentary/archival methods, and observations. For the purposes of this study, the case study approach was used. SUMMARY 1. StatelLocal Government Restructuring The study revealed that Ghana's dependency on the global system.contributed immensely to the economic and political problems it has faced since its independence in 1957. Ghana is now the third largest debtor nation to the International Financial Institutions (IFIs), particularly the IMF and the World Bank. The situation has worsened with the adoption of the Structural Adjustment Program, which is believed to be the means for reversing decades of misery, poverty, and underdevelopment. State restructuring has encompassed retrenchment of workers in public institutions, and increases in state taxes and the creation of new institutions to collect them, and austerity measures which commercialized public services. But more importantly, state restructuring has redefined the relationship between the central and local government. Whereas, previously the central government paid hundred percent of the salary/wages of local government employees, and provided grant-in-aid, 256 the fiscal crisis of the state has led to systematic cut- backs of central government support to local governments. Since the Structural Adjustment Program was introduced, the central government has reduced its financial support to local governments by fifty percent. The local state has also undergone some changes. It has assumed more responsibilities for community development, at a time when its resource base has diminished. Strategies the local state has adopted have included increased taxes, and privatization of public services. The contradictions inherent in local state operations became quite apparent in the Central Market. While the KMA increased taxes, rents for market stalls and stores, the physical and social infrastructure in the market deteriorated. Thus, while the local state institutions had become dependent on communities for their revenues, they have become less responsible towards them. 2. State Versus the Civil Society The strategies of the local government in Kumasi to generate revenues from the community, particularly market traders, have generated some conflict between the two groups. Market traders have been saddled'with too many taxes: basic rates, property rates, increased rents for stalls/stores, table fees, late payment fees, and increased income tax, not to mention the austere measures of the central state including privatization of social services, 257 and high cost of living. In addition, due to the poor security in the market, they lost some of their commodities through theft and armed robbery, without any compensation from state/local government institutions. While the KMA was only interested in raising revenues from the operations of the traders, the latter were more concerned with the deterioration of physical, and social infrastructure in the market, and in the community. Thus, within the period of the Structural Adjustment Program, both the central/local states imposed a legion of taxes on market traders and other Ghanaians, and yet the revenues were not used to service the people, but were used to create new institutions which duplicated the work of existing ones. 3. Market Trader Activism.and Democratization There were two major objectives of market trader activism.within the context of state/local government restructuring processes. First, it was designed to resist/challenge attempts by the local government to control their incomes through increased taxes. Second, it was meant to influence the local government to improve the physical and social infrastructure in the market to enhance the traders's business activities. From.1983-1993, market traders presented petitions to different levels of the central and local state. An analysis of the petitions revealed that they addressed issues such as market conditions, increased rents, special fees for use of 258 market fees, and fees for late payment of rents. They questioned the integrity of city officials, and demanded accountability from them, An assessment of the activities of the market traders revealed that they have had some effect on the state system. The Kumasi Central Market is scheduled to be rehabilitated, and facilities market traders have struggled for in the past may be provided. The local state also paid compensation for traders who lost their commodities through the negligence of security agents. However, the local state has privatized the security of the market, so that traders could use private security to protect their commodities. CONCLUSIONS First, the study has shown that there is a linkage between global economic processes and community politics in Ghana. Such linkages are often neglected in the analysis of the political economy of Third world countries. Second, the study also demonstrates that studies of grassroots movements in Third world countries should not only focus on labor movements, but also the activities of ordinary men and women, especially market traders, who on daily basis mobilize to articulate their collective interests vis-a-vis the local state. They are a force to reckon with, and therefore, theoretical discussions on the political economy of Third World societies, particularly in Africa, should take into serious consideration the role of grassroots community groups in effecting change. 259 Thirdly, the findings of this research show that local communities have come to bear the blunt of global/state restructuring processes in the Third world, especially Ghana. While state structures have adopted austere measures to be lean and mean, in response to external and internal pressures, they are still dependent upon their citizenry to generate revenues for their operations. This study has shown that organized communities are capable of resisting attempts by state/local governments to have it both ways. Finally, it has been demonstrated that the search for a comprehensive understanding of grassroots mobilization in the periphery of the global system.must be based on a synthesis of structural factors (macro-level), national and local politics (mezzo-level), and human agency (micro- level), that is, people's resistance to domination in society. APPENDIX A strictes only. Yo Name of Organi z a 260 Membership Questionnaire This questionnaire is designed to study the social backgrounds of individuals participating in market associations in Kumasi. The information will be kept in strictest confidence and will be used for academic purposes only. Your cooperation is greatly needed and appreciated. None of Organization l. SEX male female 1 2 2. How long have you been a member of this group? 3. Why did you join the group? 4. How did you find out about the group? 5. Did y' were acc« 6. What 1 you held etc) . 7- How di B'whdta 10. In th group? I f 261 5. Did you have to meet special qualifications before you were accepted as a member? (Explain) 6. What position(s) do you hold in the group? How long have you held it? (i.e, office, group leader, committee member, etc). 7. How did you come to hold this position? 8. What are your duties? 9. Are you paid for the work you do for the organization? 10. In the past years, have you held other positions in the group? If YES, state position(s) and length of time held? 11. What; group? QCLN 11. Wha the mark 262 11. What do you enjoy most about being a member of this group? CONDITIONS IN THE MARKET 11. What is your assessment of the following services in the market: 1. Sanitation: 2. Drainage: 3. Roofing: 4 . Water: 263 5. Toilets: 6. Security: Please describe some personal problems you have had with the above-mentioned services( for example, fires, leaked roofs, thefts, etc). 12. SELECTED FACILITIES REQUIRED BY TRADERS Please indicate which of the following facilities you would want the KMA to provide in the market: _____rl"ac111t 11W _9______'l' be Provided a) water b) Toilets c) Clinics d) Crgdit e) Trans rt f) Storage g) Day-Care Centers h) Drainage 1) Security 13. 108' a) How b) For C) How 9) What 13111:? e) What 8tall/8t i) too ii) hig 264 13. NIRRET STALLSZSTORES a) How did you acquire your stall/store? b) For how long have you owned your stall/store? c) How much do you pay for rent now? d) What proportion of your profits is used to pay for rent? e) What do you think of the rent charged for your stall/store? i) too high ii) high iii) fair f)?“ stall 14. ! R P a) Wha tables b) HOW c °f stall 265 f) What is your assessment of rent increases for your stall/store since you owned it? i) too high ii) high iii) fair g) How do rent increases affect your business? 14. FEES FOR TABLES USED INSIDE AND OUTSIDE MARKET STALLS a) What do you think of the policy to charge fees for tables set up inside and infront of stalls/stores? b) How does payment of fees for tables inside and infront of stalls/stores affect your business? 15. a) lat' b) busi e) Pena. 16. a)D imPro 266 15. FEES FOR LATE PAYMENT OF RENTS a) What do you think of the policy to charge fees for late payment of rents? b) How does penalty for late payment of rents affect your business? c) Under what circumstances should a trader not be penalized for late payment of rents? 16. WORLD BANK FUNDS FOR CENTRAL MARKET IMPROVEMENTS a) Do you know of the World Bank funds for Central Market improvements? Yes No If Yes, what do you know about the funds? b)Wb thew PART 17. 18. W have y a. Pet. b: Dem: c. Boyc d. 0the 267 b) What is your assessment of the way the KMA has handled the World Bank funds? PARTICIPATION IN'ASSOCIATIONAL ACTIVITIES 17. I attend meetings: a. all the time b. most of the time c. on few occasions d. I do not attend meetings 18. Which of the following past associational activities have you participated in? Petitions to state/local government institutions b. Demonstrations to protest government policies Boycotts to protest government policies Others 19. I Other. 21. 22. 268 19. I pay my dues: a. all the time b. most of the time c. on few occasions d. Other 20. From which tribe are you? Where were you born? Place of birth Region of Ghana Another country 21. How old are you? 22. How long have you lived in Kumasi? 269 23. Which of the religious groups do you belong to? a. Christian b. Muslim c. Traditional d. Other OCCUPATION 24. What kind of work do you do now? (Be specific) 25. What other work have you done before? 26. What was the source of capital for your current occupation? a. personal savings(esusu) b . family members c. loans i) money lenders ii) bank iii) special government program d. Other 28.1 29, Or ‘ tack 270 EDU TION 27. Have you been to school? YES No 28. How far did you go? (a) (b) (a) (d) Primary Middle Secondary University 1. 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 1. 2. 3. 4. S. 6. 1. 2. 3. 4. 6. 29. Have you had special training in any vocation or field or work? (Explain) (i.e. teacher's training, commercial, technical, etc.) 30. (Plea: 31. E . 271 30. Are you married single ‘widowed divorced Comments: (Please get information on kind of marriage, if possible) 31. How'many children have you? What are their ages? Boys Age Girlg ? ge Additional Comments: TEENK YOU'VERYINUCH FOR YOUR COOPERATION! 1 t t ‘ a c 4.3 5' B; If organ 272 INFORMATION ON MARKET ASSOCIATIONS IN KUMASI These questions represent an attempt to study problems traders face in the Central Market, and how they organize themselves to deal with these problems. This information *will be kept in strictest confidence, and will be used for academic purposes only. I, therefore, solicit your maximum cooperation. Thank you. Name of Organization I . BACKGROUND 1. When was the association founded? 2. By whom? 3. How did the organization get started? 4. How'many founding members? 5. Has the organization always had the same name? (specify) a) Yes b) No If Yes, please specify the different names the organization has used in the past: Na a) e) b) II. IKE 6. What III. ST a) How b) Tit 1) ii) iii) iV) 273 Name Year a) c) b) II. AIMS AND OBJECTIVES 6. What is the purpose of the organization? III . STRUCTURE a) How'many officers do you have? b) Titles and Functions: Title Function; i) ii) iii) iv) c) If _ E I .a) b) H: 274 c) If there is an executive committee, please give its composition: Qogposition of executive committees Functions of executive members 8. a) Are officers 1. elected 2. appointed b) What is the criteria for selection? 9. How often are elections held? 1. yearly 2. other 10. Is with an If organize Wh: 11. 27S 10. Is the organization independent? (Do you have ties with another or larger group?) 1. Yes 2. No If yes, please explain the ties you have. 11. Which trade groups are represented in your organization? 12. Does the organization have a constitution or set of formal rules? 1. Yes 2. No 13. Does the organization keep records of its activities? 1. Yes 2. No If Yes, who keeps the records? - . w ' L ‘ . - ' ‘ 14. 1 15. 3 : g M a H S n o w m m r r . H 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 276 If No, please explain. 14. Is there an office for your organization? 1. Yes 2. No If Yes, do you have a paid staff to work for you? 1. Yes 2. No IV} MHHBERSHIP 15. How many members: Year Number of members Men women Active Inactive 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 16. How 17 . Is recruit l 2 18. Are 19. Do ! A 20- Wha 21) Wha 277 16. How are members recruited (How does one join the group)? 17. Is there a special time at which new'members are recruited? 1. Yes 2. No 18. Are qualifications for membership the same for all? 1. Yes 2. No 19. Do members leave the group? 1. Yes 2. No Why do they leave? 20. What will cause a member to be dimmissed? 21) What kinds of benefits does the organization provide its members? 23. Whal 24- Wha 25, a, 278 NATURE OF MEETINGS 22. a) How often does your organization meet? 1. weekly [Day(s)1 2. Bi-monthly [Day(s)] 3. Monthly [Day(s)1 4. other (specify) [Day(s)] b) Where do you meet? Specific place: c) How long are the meetings? [Time meetings are held] 23. What is the order of business (what do you do?) 24. What rituals are performed at the meeting? 25. a) Who participates? b) Who presides? 279 26. What is the attendance? Please give estimates of proportions of members who attended meetings for the following period. Year Prgportion of Members who Attended Meeti_ngs 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 27. What language(s) do you use at your meetings? 280 28. What are the major issues you discuss at your meetings? ‘VI. ETHNICITYZTRIHAL AFFILIATION 29. What are the ethnic backgrounds (tribal affiliation) of your members? Ethnic Backggounleribal.Affiliation Number Asante Fante Ga Hausa Nzima Ewe Other (please specify) 281 ‘VII. DUES AND CONTRIBUTIONS 30) a) Are there regular dues? 1. Yes 2. No b) how much? c) how often do members pay dues: 1.‘week1y 2. bi-monthly 3. monthly 4. quarterly 5. yearly 31). a) Do members pay special contributions? 1. Yes 2. No b) how much? c) what are the special contributions used for? 282 VIII. CONDITIONS IN THE MARKET 32) What is your assessment of conditions in the market? a) Drainage: b) Roofing: c) Sanitation: 283 d) Provision of water: e) Toilets and Places of Convenience: f) Medical facilities (for example, clinics): 9) Security and Safety (for example, fire- extinguishers, watchmen, telephones, etc. Please mention specific incidents in the market. If you have records please attach). 284 33) SELECTED FACILITIES REQUIRED BY ASSOCIATION Please indicate which of the following facilities your association would want the KMA to provide in the market: Facility Needs I_mprovement Should Be Provided a) Water b) Toilets c) Clinics d) Credit e) Tran rt f) Storage 9) Da - are enter h) Drainage i) Security 34) What actions have been taken by your organization to improve the market conditions described above? 285 ‘VIII. RENTS FOR.MRRKET STALLSZSTORES 35) a) What does the organization think of the rents charged for market stalls/stores? i) too high ii) high iii) fair iv) other b) What is your assessment of rent increases for market stalls/stores? i) too high ii) high iii) fair iv) other c) How do rent increases affect members' businesses? 36) FEES FOR TABLES USED INSIDE AND QUTSIDE MARKET STALLS STORES a) What does your organization think of KMA policy to charge fees for tables set up inside and infront of stalls/stores? b) How does payment of fees for tables inside and infront of stalls/stores affect your members' businesses? 286 3'7) FEES FOR LATE PAYMENT OF RENTS a) What does your organization think of the policy to charge fees for late payment of rents? b) How does penalty for late payment of rents affect ‘your members' businesses? c) Under what circumstances should a trader not be penalized for late payment of fees? 38) WORLD BANK FUNDS FOR CENTRAL MARKET IMPRQ!§!§!I§ a) Does your organization know of the world Bank funds for Central Market improvements? Yes No If Yes, what does your organization know about the funds? 287 b) What is your assessment of the way the KMA has handled the world Bank funds? RELATIONSHIP WITH THE KUMASI METROPOLITAN AUTHORITYZASSEMBLY 39) How'would you describe the relationship between your organization and the EMA? a) very cordial b) cordial c) tense d) very tense 40. What problems does the organization have with the KMA? 288 41. Please describe how your association organized its petitions to the Rumasi Metropolitan Authority in the following period: 19 84 PETITION 1) Why was it sent? ii) Who prepared it? iii) How many people were involved when the petition was presented? iv) Where was the petition sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which Newspapers covered the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? 289 viii) What specifically was done by the group members when the petition was presented? (For instance, Demonstrations, Marches, etc.) ix) What did the EMA do with the 1984 petition? x) Did the petition achieve its objectives? 1. Yes 2. No Please explain: 290 42 . 1985 PETITION i) Why was it submitted? ii) Who prepared the petition? iii) How many people were involved when the petition was submitted? iv) Where was the petition sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers cover the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? 291 viii) What specifically was done by the group members ‘when the petition was presented? [For instance, Demonstrations , Marches , etc . 1 ix) What did the RNA do with the 1985 petition? x) Did the petition achieve its objectives? 2. NO Please explain: 292 44. 1986 PETITION i) Why was it sent? ii) Who prepared it? iii) How many people were involved when the petition presented? iv) Where was the petition sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers covered the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? 293 'viii) What specifically was done by the group when the petition was presented? [For instance, demonstrations, clash'with the police, fights, etc.] ix) What did the KMA do with the 1986 petition? x) Did the 1986 petition achieve its objectives? 1. YES 2.NO Please explain: 294 45 . 19 87 PETITION i) Why was it sent? ii) Who prepared it? iii) How many people were involved when the petition was submitted? iv) Where was the petition sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers covered the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? 295 viii) What specifically was done by the group members when the petition.was submitted? [For instance, demonstration, marches, clashwwith the police, fights, etc] ix) What did on do with the 1987 petition? f x) Did the 1987 petition achieve its objective? 1. n8 2. NO Please explain: 296 46. 1988 PETITION i) Why was it sent? ii) Who prepared it? iii) How many people were involved when the petition was presented? iv) Where was it sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers covered the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? viii) What specifically was done by the group members when the petition was submitted? [For instance, demonstrations, marches, police clashes, fights] 297 ix) What did the EMA do with the 1988 petition? x) Did the 1988 petition achieve its objectives? 1. YES 2. m Please explain : 47. 1989 PETITION 1) Why was it sent? ii) Who prepared it? iii) How many people were involved when the petition was submitted? 298 iv) Where was the 1989 petition sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers cover the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? viii) What specifically was done by the group members when the petition was submitted? [For instance, demonstration, marches, police clashes, fights, etc.] 299 ix) What did the EMA do with the 1989 petition? x) Did the 1989 petition achieve its objectives? 1. YES 2. NO Please explain : 48. 1990 PETITION i) Why was the petition sent? ii) Who prepared it? 300 iii) How many people were involved when the 1990 petition was presented? iv) Where was the petition sent? v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers covered the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? viii) What specifically was done by the group members when the petition was submitted? [For instance, demonstration, marches, clash with the police, fights, etc.] 301 ix) What did the EMA do'with the 1990 petition? x) Did the 1990 petition achieve its objectives? 1. YES 2. NO Please explain: 49. 1991 PETITION i) Why was it submitted? ii) Who prepared it? 302 iii) How many people were involved when the 1991 petition was presented? iv) Where was the petition submitted? v) Did the press cover the event? vii) Which newspapers covered the event? — 2 . . " 1 viii) What specifically was done by the group members when the petition was submitted? [For instance, demonstrations, clash with the police, fights, etc.] ix) What did the KMA do with the 1991 petition? 303 x) Did the 1991 petition achieve its objectives? 1. YES 2. NO Please explain: 50 . 1992 PETITION i) Why was the petition submitted? ii) Who prepared the petition? iii) How many people were involved when the petition was submitted? iv) Where was the petition sul-itted? 304 v) Did the press cover the event? vi) Which newspapers covered the event? vii) What was the content of the petition? viii) What specifically was done by the grow) members when the petition was submitted? [For instance, demonstration, marches, clashes with the police, fights, etc.] ix) What did the KMA do with the 1992 petition? 305 x) Did the 1992 petition achieve its objectives? 1. n8 2.NO Please explain : 51. If the association has used boycotts in the past, please answer the following questions: 1) When was the boycott organized? ii) Why was boycott organized? iii) Who organized the boycott? iv) How many members of your group were involved in the boycott? 306 vii) What specifically happened when the boycott was organized? [For instance, demonstrations, marches, vacation of trading posts, clashes with the police, fights, etc.] viii) What did the m or government agency do about the boycott? ix) Did the boycott achieve its objective (s)? 1. Yes 2. No Please explain: 307 53. a) Which important personalities in the community has the organized used to act on its behalf in dealing*with the III? b) How did these important personalities help your organization to deal with its problems with the III? 54) Please describe other strategies your organization used in the past to influence the KIA to change its policies or to ilprove conditions in the market. 308 55) How are your organization's activities financed? ADDITIONAL COMMENTS: _ I J I H - fi . TEKNK‘YOU FOR YOUR @ENEROUS TIME AND INFORMATION} IIAILING'ADDRBSS OP ORGANIZATION: Interviewer: Place: Tine: Date: 309 INFORMATION ON THE KUNASIINETROPOLITAN'ADTEORITY These questions represent an attempt to study the relationship between the Kumasi Metropolitan Authority and market associations in Kumasi, particularly the General Traders Association in the Central Market. This information will be kept in strictest confidence, and will be used for academic purposes only. Your cooperation in this exercise will be very much appreciated. Thank you. RELATIONSHIP TO THE CENTRAL GOVERNMENT 1. What is the relationship between the KMA and the Central Government? 2. What financial support did the Central Government provide the KMA before the Structural Adjustment Program? 3. How has the Structural Adjustment Program affected Central Government financial support of the KMA? 310 ADMINISTRATION OF THE CENTRAL MARKET 2. a) What departments of the KMA are directly involved in the administration of the Central Market? b) What is the specific role of each of the departments involved in the administration of the Central Market? c) What are the responsibilities of the Market Manager in the Central Market? 311 ASSE OR CONDITIONS IN THE CENTRAL MARKET 1984-92 3. Please comment on the conditions of the following infrastructure and services in the Central Market. a) Drainage: b) Sanitation: 312 c) Roofing: d) WaterlPipes e) oilet Plac of onvenience: 313 f) Security and Safety in the Market: (Including watchmen, fire-extinguisher, thefts, etc.) FACILITIES EMA PROVID- IN CENTRAL MARKET IN THE 1984-1992 PERIOD 4. What facilities did the KMA provide in the Central Market in the 1984-1992 period? W W W 314 THE CENTRAL MARKET S. a) When was the Central Market constructed? b) How many stalls? Types of stalls? What are the measurements? c) How'many stores? Types of stores? What are the measurements? 315 d) What are the rents for the different sizes of stalls? e) What are the rents for the different sizes of stores? 6. Who determines rent increases in the Central Market? 7. Are market traders involved in decision-making affecting rent increases? YES NO If Yes, what role do they play in the decision-making? If No, please explain. 316 What factors influence rent increases by KMA? Does the KMA charge traders fees for late payment of rents? YES NO If YES, when did this begin? How'much? If NO, please explain Why does the KMA charge traders fees for late payment of rents? If No, please explain. 317 FEES FOR TABLES SET UP INSIDE AND OUTSIDE MARKET STALLS 10. When did the KMA decide to charge fees for tables set up inside and outside stalls/stores in the market? ‘How'much? Why does it charge these fees for the tables? MORLD gag; FUNDS FOR CENTRAL MARKET IMPROVEMENTS 9. What support has the KMA received from the Wbrld Bank for market rehabilitation/improvements? a) Financial Support: Year Amount 318 b) Technical Support: Year Support 10. What did the KMA do with the financial and technical support from the world Bank for market rehabilitation? 11. RELATIONSHIP TOIMARKET TRADERS a How does the KMA communicate its policies to market traders? 319 b) Has KMA received petitions from Market Traders in the past? YES NO What did the KMA dO‘With the petitions? 12) What did the KMA dO‘With petitions from the General Traders Association? a) 1984 PETITION b) 1985 PETITION 320 c) 1986 PETITION d) 1987 PETITION e) 1988 PETITION 321 f) 1989 PETITION g) 1990 PETITION h) 1991 PETITION 322 i) 1992 PETITION 13. How did the petitions from the market traders influence KMA's policies? a) Did these petitions influence the KMA to provide the services requested by the traders? YES NO Please explain: 323 b) Did the petitions delay the KMA from.implementing its policies? YES NO, Please explain: c) Did the petitions stgp the KMA from implementing its policies? YES NO Please explain: 15. Have market traders reacted to KMA policies in any other ways apart from.petitions? YES NO 324 a) What were the reactions of the market traders? b) How did these reactions influence KMA's policies affecting traders in the Central Market? APPENDIX B I325 ASHANTI RETAIL TRADERS ASSOCIATION KUMASI omen. MARKET, 0/0 9.0. BOX 3412, x u M A s I. Iu/S/BS. ms smou'rrvs, campus, runner CITY couscn, P.0. Box 1916, runsx. “a! at, ' IMPORTANT PQINTS FOR DISCUSSION _ ye have the honour,to present-the under-speeified~ importdnt points for diécussion and implementation. '(I) Sanitation at the Kumasi Central Market is very poor as the COuncil labourers are not sweeping the market regularly. This often produces unhealthy atmosphere and we the traders often have to do the sweeping and clearing of refuse all by ourselves. we therefore humbly appeal to you for consideration to effect transfer of some labourers to work permanently at the Central Market (2) There are no fire fighting implementatbtnthe Kumasi Central Iarket to fight any possible out-break of fire, As a result of which some goods and stores have often been burnt to ashes. Is are therefore appealing to you to consider providing us with the necessary Fire fighti- ng implements to fight all future out-break. (3)‘Vb are also entrseting you to give the necessary directives for the replacement of broken down Iron bars or iron fl‘t" from the south of the Sabin Stream entering the arket'at the two points opposite rrsflensah Hospital and Ghana Railway Corporation respectively. 'lhieves often Jump into the stress and pass througi the two points and find their way into the market either to steel or to hide themselves when being chased by people. (4) some traders have wron g1 tables all over the st market and thus disr goods into Our sto placed some unregestered to or pavements inside the ting the smooth carting.of spend stalls. We are therefore :gpealing to you .e necessary unwanted tab s. 0 use your good offices to give actives for the removal of these (5) 500 Association member were ejected from the Reds- tia (18th) and that permission for re; ettlement of the traders at the Fren- chline where dum e Regional Secretary’hes granted d refuse were removed. “a are there- fore appealing it; impldme c . I 0 you to consider giving your assent fpr ‘ion as itwwill raise revenue for the Conn . -.’; ' -. I "‘ a ‘- . \I '_ O a (6) Our monthly rates have also to ¢200.00 per store and ¢2 and we still have to pay additional ¢5.00 a day for any small table put infsent of the stall or Store and th:refore appeal to you and beg for reduction of the to $100.00 per stall, an increased from ¢h5.00- r. .e '- v (7) The Market gates were usually closed at 6.p.m. everyday to avoid possible'entry 6f thieves into the market at night. This method worked considerably as market thefts were greatly reduced. unfortunately, this order has been reversed and peeple have to remain as late as 8.p.m. Thieves hareth°r010r0 $033 tgiSEPS t the ket (P.T.O.) 326 the market. we are therefore entraating you to consider reversing the closing time to 6.p.m. to clear away all thieves and to enable the 'htchmen so about their normal duties to arrest all suspected thieves after 6.p.m. We welcome you warmly into our fold and entreat you to assist us achieve our objective. Yours obediently, W _ 327 GENERAL TRADERS ASSOCIATION ( Motto: HONEST LABOUR) ' ‘ELEP E: —— REGIONAL SECRETARIAT P. 0. BOX 1662 ““3” °" l HON : 8 'al Beaurit Bank ’ W xuuwx-msmn Our .... n at Y our Ref: _ 1 7 th {game—#1939 "Ono " Si . r " uaauser FOR.hEflnBILITATION or onumL MARKET, RL'IJASI _ It would be recalled that the runner Ci ty Council Chairman Lt. Col. Opuni Hensah, assured the above -nsmed Association for the rehabilitation of the Central Market partiCulsriy construction of drains culverts restrain and the that the to world Bank has voted money entry of water into stall and kiosks. That Upon the receipt of this assurance, the members were happy about the unexpected news like this and we did thank the Chairman for his able leadership. That when the Chainusn was reIIeVinn his post as an Executive Chairman, he further told us that the commencement of the work will he begin in June, 1988. That to our surprise, the June 1988 has lapsed and nothing is hoard from the Council about the rehabilitation of the market. We are by this letter want. to know from the Council the date or time the said project will take place That the entire Association members wil not hesitate to summits give helping hands to the Councils project at the Market if it begins. That prior to this assurance , the council increased rates on the ground that they will construct LVIP toilet, Urinal rooms etc. which the market has denied. That because of this develo mont ‘which tho semlred us, we accented the igcrense of ranésc°giiil the bone that the council will actually undertake the nrruranco nrodeots at the market but to our. dismay the Council did not fulfil its promises to the tnadgrs Wk!!! 8 13 received. th a market and "here m the council a ! revenue 13 That we traders sweep in *h . e m rk refuse to the dumping places withea our own resources et and convey the instead of the Council's own responsibility. ‘n We are further by this letter . r eflu til Council to disclose to us the rates Jaanry 1088 to December, long and collecgzd lgrcmhe the develcpmant made at accordingly, 5 the Centr l ' Lnrket ~ to enable us to advise ourselves We hone in the principles of Natur l J . u ti ' aggnffir play which the Council is dZdicazedceIozquth a 1‘ .0 will not hesitate a nested ‘1 . for to us , as the accountability to 01801038 what we is hav coungerned Ah 328 Yours faithfully, _“’fl_fl,,. r— """' 1-, 0 THE P.R.D.C. DISTRICT SECRETARI’ ILUiiASI DISTRICT 1. COUNCIL, KUMASI, Copies to: ‘he P. N.D.C.Begional Secretary, Regional Administration, Yumasi/Ashenti. 2, The City Treasurer, Eumaei Diet. N. Council, Kumasi. 3. The Market Mannmer, Kumasi City Council, Kumasi. In. Th9 Chairman, . Central racket ”0V. Committee, Kumnsi. 5. .The Dist.0rg.Asst, CoDeRo ’ Kumeei. 329 GENERAL TRADERS ASSOCIATION (Motto: HONEST LABOUR) l‘EflPHONE: REGIONAL sscumuun i’. 0. BOX 1052 mamas: socm Scourily Bank W xuMASI . Asnm'rl hat 3;! I our Ref: 4%" mu. .493L aggoturlgl The former Executivt choirwm of the 3.0.5. now kl). Ik- col. , Oplni Innh‘lnvr‘w"35‘dfi|t, lifter his trnnefor. I. lust qus-tion any new ’Xflifllvo chair-uh it within 6 oonths of his ofl'ios to fnil- to develop the oontrnl Inrkst trons-o th 'orld Bank snrmrko'd an uncut of lousy (c the develop-sot of the control purist. rInt, who the present lotropolitnn Secretory, conned» You “enroll onls to oft‘ioo, we have consulted his fu- the denim-mat of the market but ho did not Iind up sinus thou. ' J. Tint, duo to the fnilu-o of th LIA. to develop tb onrkot, wo suffer rain floods resulting to the dostrmtion of our goods in our storos nod stalls in tho mrkot. 2but, our vta-o rent ‘hnT- boon rni-od tro- “(p.00 n month to 11,200.00 on! tho l‘rou 11.500 to 13,000.00 and tho n-as FJ.000.00 to 76,000.00. 1'tut, doqito those huge increases in route. us also pay 750.00 for the goods inside the stores nu] nlpo $150.00 for the goods displayed in front of tin stores dolly. ‘ltut, despite such hung. rents mil rntoo collected by the LIA. fro! the traders in the Ins-hot, thy toiled to dovelq) tin Inrkot to onto our pods tro- tloods. . ' That, Io mdortnks rqnirs and rouomtions of our stores not! also «ploy our on: labourers to swoop the market witlnut own rosou-oss despite the huge (noun or lousy oollsotso tro- us by tho LILA. That, we do not benefit from the huge noount collected by tho LLA. but they Inks use of the money collected tron us for. nothing. '9. rInt, we therefore wsloonv the committee to probe the KJLA. financial Inttors whole henrtsdlg, and with the chutes every swoon. 10. ll. rhut, we appeal to tip coIIIIittc-e to inventions into those our onses ru- Justios to to dons. Vs nluo appeal to the conittoo to rodoos our high I'm" fC‘ “Io ' 'o thsrsta-s welcome the “mam for their seating. . s - .-oo ‘ 'COO' - ‘. . ,. n.- rm cm. asnmu none“. DIVISIIGA‘HNG noun-ran, (ARE )9 ' 0/0. REGIGML mum ISNTION. KU!‘§1. 330 GENERAL TRADERS ASSOCIATION ( Motto: HONEST lABOUR) TWHONK:—————— 330' ORAL SECNKT'ARI A1 ”tum: 80¢“! Writ] Bank 1’. 0. ”OK I“: (Nf'h' 25i;;;' XUIuwl-ABHANTI Your 3:3: _§S.D_9_§9I?£r4__..19_93 The mu .3! .J . lawl inns . antle. Thro FIDO Regional Secretary, we. bear Gentlemen of the Preas, PETITIOH TO READ 2? STATE ‘Ie have the honour to present to you on behalf of the GIIIRAL TRADBRB ASSOCIATION in.xumasi our petition on some of the basic problems facing traders in Kumasi. The aain objective of the conference is to highlight once again the basic problems facing traders in the Central larket since every effort made to reason with the PNDC Iotropolitan Secretary and the Aeaeably has fallen on deaf ears. lo have learn with.dismay, the publication in the Pioneer. 13th September 1991 whereby the [IA has voted h.) million oedia solely to provide public address system to provide music and other intonaation to the traders at the Central Iarhet. And we wish to state that we object to such a project for the following reasons:- 1. That the acid amount could be utilised to provide fire extin- guishers at vantage positione in the Iarhet. ' 2. To provide day care entre since there is no such facility in the market and urinals. 3. T0 desiltrtha choked gutters in the market to avoid floods during.rainy season and also to avoid any epidemic. h. .To repair all the broken dosn telephone syctea in the market. The repair will enable KIA to_coamunicatc any information to the traders and the ataff of the Authority. Gentlemen of the preoa, we wirh to draw the attention of PNDC Secretary to IVA about the congeetion in the central market. The congea- tion has made the market so dirty and movement unpleaaant. Effort then ehould be made to reduce it and we have the plea- sure to suggest the following:- 1. 2. 3. That KIA should endeavour to develop and expand lorry parka at Bantama. New Tafo, Asafo larhet, etc. so that vehiclee coming from the approaching roads to Kumasi central could be accommodated in the new lorry parks. That KIA should liaiee with the Ghana Railways Authority to relettle traderc squatting near the railway lines. There is every possibility that in the event of derailment, there will definately be heavy casualty of huaan liveo anong the equatters. That we appeal to the KIA to allow the traders to renovate their stores without extortion any money from them which go into private pocket. 331 In reapect of the numerous rates paid by the traders, it is high time that FHA reviews them. We appeal to PNDC to ensure that EMA initiates descussions on the reduction of rates to forestall any possible public demonstration by the traders. The rates of each stall or store have arbitrarily been increased to over 1501. Since the appointment of HetrOpolitnn Secretary to Fumasi we have observed that, as a result of his poor leadership, no develop- ment has taken place in the market. We eXperience seasonal floods, the market is dirty, the gutters have been choked, and he is not torerant to discuss the basic problems facing traders. At the moment there are no keys to most of the gates leading to the market. As traders and citizens of Ghana, we can no longer accept him as our Secretary in Humasi and we fervently appeal to PNDC to relieve him of his post. His transfer from Kumasi will enable confidence people have in PNDC restored. ' The General Traders Association have since 1981 played a meaning- ful role in the communal projects, collection rates political educa- tion and other activities organise by the Authority or CDR. But during the last celebration of CDR day in Kumasi, the Metropolitan Secretary stepped the traders to attend the Day without any tangible reasons. he were shocked of this behaviour. We want to finally inform you that the presence of the MetrOpo- litan Secretary in the person of Navy Captain Yaw Mensch is retarding progress and hampering trading business of individuals in Kumasi. The earlier he is transferred from Kumasi the better for PNDC to get competent person to organise to support the good cause and assist the peeple to live in peaceful and honest atmosphere in Kumasi. Thank you, Yours faithfully, CO: The Secretary, Ministry of Local Government, Accra The Press, 332 GENERAL TR‘ADERS ASSOCIATION ( Noam HONEST LABOUR) BEGIORAL SECRETABI A'l ' r. o. nox ms nu MASl . ASHANTI 15th January —- - 29.2.2 lflflfiONfl:—————— saunas: Social Security Bank an: 3:! "$' Your Ref: . Till iG,P, N, D, 0, H3010 ML stoma“, imam Imam slflllltflhi‘lbl, no.3): 33, M bar at, PrrI'rIos AGAINST r,u,s. Maw 11th groat roapsct, Is petition against KJLA. on Rates Collection as follows:- I ( at we hsvs learnt with di-ay tho nnprsosdsntsd ) gal: increase of market storss/stslls monthly rentals without considering Isttsrs affecting our wslforo. ’2 at we also sal s ainst the act of collecting ) filly rats stigmoo gfi fty asdis) in the stores and another 950.00 (fi fty sodisz’ for goods di ml and Just infront of the sons stars walls the salsa A tenant is obligsd to pay against hi s/hsr monthly y the seas storaksspsr, star-ksspsr pays -a monthly rental as wall. rental but does not pay any additional money for his/her psrsonal belongings in the room to the Landlord. Therefore the daily coll action in the stores must be avoided by Lil. A. to mi'vs"say to 'th‘s monthly rentals onl’s (3) “that on 29th of July. I991, our txsoutivs mombsrs had a seating with Km. A. and none. tho sttlndancs wore (a) Naval captain A. Tulane-uh 4’. mac. Istropolitan Bsorstnry, Kumssi (b) Rana Ksasi i yamsng (c) MrJull. deso Assafo (d) Mersdwo Gyamfi It the nesting, ws resolved that tho K.I.A. should avoid the daily collection of ticksts insids the atoros and and stick to tho monthly rentals only. LI. A. agreed promised to convsn's a meeting to rosolvo this matter. s) Mrdwudu Gariba. it nsvsr fulfillsd this proniss. '4) M"! (fivs hundred csdis) for . 's rp'symsnt, o aonthly rsntals snot also bs avoidsd ma view of tho fact that a tradsr could easily fall sick and schittsd at a hospital or to involvsd in funerals etc. which has not need punidimant. (5) Ithat all our sppssls to LII. A. to improve the drainsas system at tho control Iarkst have bssn to no avail and this gvss rise to a flooded nsrkst during the rainfall shioh dostrovs 95:37 of our paras. (6) That may of the stores/stalls roofing wars rot-tan and lssksd profusslp to soak our stock of goods in tho storss/ atolls but: all our appeals to tho rm. A. for renovation provsd futile. Is thoroforo renovated ths stores/stalls ourselves and raised the lsvsl of ths floor a bit against flood with our scarcs resources with approval and author- 333 tro- !.l.l. savanna the Ll. A. .Lntud at rotunda; .11 our oxymo- 1m1vdd lug chapel ”gt-Lu tho nonthly sent-1- .: .11 he uncut“ noun/inn. tnn n.soo.oo (on. thou-aid, It: hand a can.) ito $009.00 (turn thou-and can). cum-t could" as M! nah u '31: on the «gov-non Inn. In undone van-om, IP’Oul as h‘ an. uncalled to: and arutruy tau-nod “on «floaty-uncut pa: "It." and tuna; «nun... ’ 67) flat at .11 than .911 cotton. to SQ}; than no no auntie. mo 1.” or convent-Mi on own cum: tund- h: indu- t do the aux-t an. tho nun." ult- 1- mp 9:90. 2 . . .-~--—.-¢_-2l ‘ In thozotou tux-bl: appeal to the Elia. haunt-1 ”but", to: Adam h tut-non. on on: huh-1: a: a udnu 01 than omdlu and ”dies-cat:- (I) Invoking t o 4.11: can cotton 0! 150.00 Ind me: to nonthly natal. of fl.GOO.m to: than 13 noun/stalls. (b) 3.11: oso;oo (an: 0041-) «noctu- to nttoot only tinder. “has tabla In the open "nu. ' (a) Invoking the no- nonm: and. or ”.000.00 (flu-u than“ 0061-) on the ”muted tutu/ltd].- to the land unto]. o! n.600.00 (no manual. ‘3 “Mad cells). I thuohxo coma“ by qpodtu to the P. 3: t6- futon-1 ”it...” to ink. mod-to a: nu ”cull. nun-touch man u. and {.Ifh a to u.“ 2t 03-“: no: t . o m“ laps.“ 1.: ma .x-pt can.“ u an. uncut. mun : m: g», afinfidhu "scanner, 1‘ m: (I)--- W (x) ;H::,c,unm.nn no. “" flairmiita‘i‘") mag, ( .. A r (2) a gmamxzawm, (from minuuou my") gut (3) ........ .............. (3) In mom. omnun nus-rm . (um-m Juli- "“155” ~- 0 0) in «gm-u, (rhfi2.hmm§i , ._ ,3; z ' mg: (52, _' ‘ :13 “mm: an on: " -. ‘ ~~' 2 (5) or mxcx,AaAm.xm “-53 “Ii-m. M . ‘ ' . m GAIHA (5) mm «lib-n. -2 - -.-—..-. x . ‘ “0.15m?" 11,351 I .'I “.1531; 3195;25, (6) 0M . mwou¥000fiii}. 1...._._£.I ‘ 4““ <7) -2‘f~:§~t"::." ié; '~ :7.» . .023 . - (7) :11: um. (tin cabal. 35!: ads”) 2" 19‘ (8) 000w " "‘ .I'..';..-'- -. ’9 \ )Ory . I ‘ . . t. . .. , f. d- . :1 ..A 1" -:~>"- ,"t‘ 1' 7-” J ..‘. {m 5k 'v . * a , A v.0 b 3 -o-.-.o . ( ififlfi) um aunt palm...»- (H) .. . . J 1 CB annulus. (12). ....- (gum man) an Ema. 334 NOTES NOTES Chapter 1 1. The Nkrumah state was guided by a socialist ideology, which sought to restructure the Ghanaian society through state-led development strategies. In addition, the Nkrumah state ostensibly attempted to promote egalitarianism through the I'price--control" mechanism. For detailed discussion of the Nkrumah state and its economic policies, see Tony Killick, Develoment Economics in Action. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1978. 2. For one of the most recent works on the linkages of these three levels of analysis see Robert Fisher and Joseph Kling, (eds.) Mobilizing the Community: Local Politics in the Era of the Global City. Urban Affairs Annual Review 41, Newbury Park: Sage Publications, 1993. 3. See also Max Weber, Economy and Socifl, translated by Guenter Roth and Claus Wittich. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1978:40-41. He defines the state as “the organization that controls the use of force in an entire society". Chapter 2 1. For more detailed treatment of the geography of Ghana, see E. A. Boateng A Geography of Ghana, Cambridge (England), University Press, 1967; and Kwabina B. Dickson A Historical Geography of Ghana, London: Cambridge University Press, 1974. 2. See the Economic Intelligence Unit, Ghana: County Profile. London: The Unit, serial (1993). 335 336 3. For detailed treatment of the Ashanti see Ivor Wilks, Forests of Gold: Essays on thg Akin and the Kingdom of the Asante, Athens, Ohio: Ohio University Press, 1993; Jean Marie Allman, The Quills of the Porcupine: Asante Nationalism In An Energent Ghana, Madison, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press, 1993; Thomas J. Lewin, Asante BeforLthe Britifish: Th; Pre_n_rpean Year . 1875-1900. Lawrence, Kansas: Regents Press of Kansas., 1978; Ivor Wilks, Asante in the Nineteen Centug: The Structure and Evolution of Political Order. London, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1975. 4. For detailed analysis of the history of Ghana, see W.E.F. Ward, A Histopy of the Gold Coast. London: George Allen and Unwin, 1948; and Adu Boahen, Ghana: Evolution and Change in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. London: Longman, 1975. 5. Two fine reports on Ghana's economic decline are Naomi Chazan, Ghana: Coping With Uncertainty. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1986; and Douglas Rimmer, Staying Poor: Ghana's Political Econoyl 1950-1990. New York: Pergamon Press, 1992. 6. see Enid Schildrout, People of the Zongo: the Transformation of Ethnic Identities in Ghana . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978. 7. Data reported in Intelligence Unit: Ghana Country Profile, 1993:3. 8. Robert Sutherland Rattray's Religion and Art in Ashanti Accra: Presbyterian Book Depot, 1945, provides some historical background of Kumasi. Chapter 3 1. For detailed history of the Kumasi Market and its relative role in Ashanti and its hinterland, and colonial Ghana, see Kwame Arhin, West African Traders in Ghana in the 19th and 20th Centurigg. London: Longman, 1979. 2. Two major studies provide in-depth analysis of market systems: Willy Frohlich, The African Market System. Translated by Charles M. Good. Vancouver, Canada: Tantalus Research, 1982; and Smart Plattner, Markets and Marketing. Monographs in Economic Anthropology, Number 4, 1985. 337 Chapter 4 1. Victor Azarya and Naomi Chazan, "Disengagement from the State in Africa: Reflections on the Experience of Ghana and Guinea“ Copparative Studies in Society, 19, 1987. 2. There are several significant studies on the global restructuring phenomenon: Henk Overbeek, Restructuring Hegemony in the Global Politicaly Econogy: The Rigg of Transnational yNgo-Liberaliam in they 1980p. New York: Routledge; 1993; Doreen B. Massey, Global Restructuring, Local Responses. WOrcester, Mass.: Graduate School of Geography, Clark University, 1988. ‘ 3. Edmund Preteceille, State Restructuring and Local Power: A.ngparative Perspective. New“York: Pinter Publishers, 1991. 4. The state versus the civil society dilemma in developing countries has been explored in-depth in Michel-Rolph, Haiti: State Against Nation: the Origins and Legacy of Duverialism, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1990; Larry Diamond (ed.) , The Democratic Revolution: Struggles for Freedom and Pluralism in the Developing World. New York: Freedom House; Naomi Chazan, Civil Society and the State in.Africa. Boulder, Colo.: L. Reinner, 1994. Chapter 6 1. For a North American comparison, see James O'Connor, The Figcal Crisis of the Stgpg. New'York: St. Martin's Press, 1973; Sidney Plotkin and Will E. Scheuerman, Private Interest, Public Spending: Balanced Budget Conservatism and the Fiscal Crisis. Boston, MA.: South-End Press, 1994; John P. Blair and David Nachmias, Fiscal Retrenchment and Urban Policy. Beverley Hills, California: Sage Publications, 1979. 2. The Kumasi City Court is inside the Kumasi Town Hall. Its purpose is to prosecute and fine city residents who violate the city's health bye-laws. 338 Chapter 7 1. National Union of Ghanaian Students (NUGS) represents students in institutions of higher learning, including the three universities, and the polytechnics in Ghana. They protested against the Structural Adjustment program. especially the aspects which required them to borrow money for their studies. Subsequently, the universities were closed several times between 1983 and 1992. 2. The labor unions initially supported the Rawlings' revolution when it began in 1981. But they became disenchanted when the Structural Adjustment Program was implemented in 1993, especially when the state began the retrenchment of workers in the public and civil services. They have also protested against the high cost of living in the country on several occasions. 3. The Ghana Bar Association has had tense moments with the PNDC. This became critical when three High Court judges and one retired military officer were abducted and killed allegedly with the connivance of the PNDC in 1983. The lawyers protested against these heinous crimes. Subsequently, the case was investigated, and surprisingly a member of the PNDC, Amartey Quaye, was implicated, as having masterminded the brutal massacres of the judges and the army officer. He was executed for the crime. The lawyers also criticized the PNDC for the lack of rule of law, and dictatorial acts, as the PNDC served as both the legislature and the executive body. Finally, they called attention to the need to return the country from military rule to democratic rule. 4. The Ghana Medical Association encouraged its members to go on strike several times between 1983-1992. The physicians refused provide medical care on these occasions, and patients died in the hospitals. The protests were over work conditions and salaries, as the Structural Adjustment Program brought prohibitive inflation rates that made the physician salaries worthless. 5. The Ghana Nurses Association also used strikes, just as the physicians did, and refused to provide services in the hospitals. They used these strategies to seek better working conditions, and salaries during the period of the Structural Adjustment Programs n x fi _ fi 339 6. The University Teachers Association of Ghana (UTAG) is quite vocal in university and national politics. It has been at odds with the PNDC since the latter came to office in 1982. They petitioned the PNDC for better working conditions and salaries. The professors boycotted classes as a leverage to bargain with the military government. The most recent incident occurred in October-November, 1994, when the professors went on strike and closed down the universities. The newly-elected civilian government under Rawlings invited representatives of the UTAG to the Castle, and promised them a twenty percent increase in their salaries in November, 1994. 7. . For an excellent analysis of why these new movements emerged in the global system as a whole, see Samir Amin (et. a1.) Transforming the Rgvolution: Social Movements and the World System. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1990. 8. In Nigeria, the Structural Adjustment Program was not popular. When Babaginda introduced it, it was opposed by the "democratic movements". He tried to inmlement it piecemeal through the advice of the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, but it still backfired. The crises Nigeria faced under Babaginda may have been exacerbated by the forceful implementation of the Structural Adjustment Program. 9. General Mobutu Sese-Seko has ruled Zaire with iron hands for over a decade now, and not without the blessing of the Western powers, especially the United States. The World Bank has implemented a Structural Adjustment Program in Zaire to help the country to get out of its fiscal mess, created by the General Mobutu state. Theoretically, one could argue that the fiscal crises in Zaire may be partly due to its peripheral status in the global system. However, it is well known that the Mobutu has used graft, authoritarian rule, and oppression of the masses, to make a fortune for himself and his cronies in foreign banks. 10. Both Busia and Limann regimes attempted to use the Structural Adjustment Program to deal with the structural economic problems Ghana faced, although their respective packages were not as ambitious as the one introduced by the Rawlings State. 11. The Trangipional Prpvisions issue was not new in Ghana. In 1979 the Armed Forces Revolutionary Council under Rawlings demanded reprieve in the Constitution for the Third Republic. There was a public outcry for the reprieve that was finally approved by the Constituent Assembly. 340 12. The Armed Forces Revolutionary Council took over power forcefully on June 4, 1979. After reigning for four months, it was forced to hand over power to the democratically elected government under Dr. Hilla Limann, which ushered in the Third Republic in Ghana. 13. The National Electoral Commission was established by the Provisional National Defence Council to prepare the country for elections as stipulated in the Constitution for the Fourth } a Republic. The controversy, however, was over the preparation of the Voter Register, which the parties claimed was ill- prepared, and had to be re-opened for registration of eligible voters. The PNDC refused to yield to the foul cry, and went ahead with the impending elections in 1992. 14. In Nigeria, the military has ruled the country longer than democratically elected governments since it became independent in 1960. The last election which was organized by Babangida in 1993, was won by Abiola, but was annulled by the same Babangida State. 15. The case of Zaire is also an interesting one. Mobutu Sese- Seko has firm grip of power, and has trashed all opposition groups inside the country. It is the speculation of the author that he would only hand over power when it becomes apparent that the civilian government that would succeed him.will pep haunt him down with his past crimes and atrocities. For further analysis of the political situation in Zaire, see for example, Crawford Young, "Zaire: Is There A State", Canadian Journal of African Studies, 18 (1), 1984:80-82; Nzongola-NTALAJA, "Bureaucracy, Elite, New Class: Who Serves Whom and Why in Mobutu's Zaire? Canadian Journal of African Studies 18 (1), 1984:99-102; Nzongola-Ntalaja, The Crisis in Zaire: Myths and Realities. Trenton, New Jersey: Africa WOrld Press, 1986; Kelly Sean, America's Tyrant: the CIA.and.Mobutu of Zaire: How the United States Put Mobptu in Power. Protected Him from His Enemies, Helped Him Become One of the Richest Men in the World. and Lived to Regret It. Washington, D.C.: American University Press, 1993. 16. The struggle for a just society in Ghana did not end with the 1992 elections. Poverty still abounds: the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund have indicated that the real effects of the Structural Adjustment Program will be felt in about fifty years time, when the average Ghanaian will be out of the poverty picture. The private press continues to be at loggerheads with the Rawlings government, over questions of 341 objective reporting. Issues about who should have access to the airwaves in Ghana is still being debated after the 1994 incident in which the "Radio Eye'l was shut off the air by state security agencies, apparently for not securing the appropriate license fromthe state. The future of the Structural Adjustment Program itself is yet to be discussed fully regarding its impact on Ghanaians, and the attendant problem of the fiscal crisis of the state. BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAEEY Abbey, J.L.S. 1989 On Promoting Successful Adjustment: Some Lessons from Ghana. Washington, D.C. : Per Jacobsson Foundation. Abloh, F.A. 1972 The Growth of Towns. Kumasi, Ghana: Research Report, Department of Housing and Planning Research, University of Science and Technology. Aboagye, A. A. 1986 Informal Sector in Kenya: A Survey of Informal Sector Activities in Nairobi. I.L.O: Addis Ababa. Adda. William 1989 I'Privatization in Ghana' in V. V. Ramanadham (ed.) Privatization in Develgpi_ng Countries. London: Routledge, Chapman and Hill. Adebayo, Aken 1985 'Ghanaian Migration to Nigeria: Causes and Consequences Migpation Today 13 (1) :29-32. Adedeji, Adebayo, Sadig Rasheed and Melody Morrison 1988 The Human Dimension of Africa's Persistent Economic Crisis. London: Hans Zell Publishers. Adotey, Bing 1984 I'Popular Participation Versus People's Power: Notes on Politics and Power Struggles in Ghana' Rgiew of African Political Ecmy 31 (December) . Adu Boahen. Albert 1989 I'The Ghana Sphinx: Reflections on the Contemporary History of Ghana: 1972-1987' Accra: Ghana Academy of Arts and Sciences. Afonja, S. 1990 'Changing Patterns of Gender Stratification in West Africa' in Irene Tinker (ed.) Persistent Inegpelities New York: Oxford University Press. 342 343 “ti-fa, A. A. 1967 The Ghana Coup London: Frank Cass and Company Ltd. Afshar, Haleh 1992 Wmen and Adjustment Policies in the Third World. New York: St. Martin's Press. Alavi, Hamza 1982 'State and Class Under Peripheral Capitalism' In H. Alavi and Teodor Shanin (eds.) Introduction to the Sociolpgy of 'Develgping' Societies. Allman, Jean Marie 1993 The Quills of the Porcupine: Asante Nationalism in An Emergent Ghana. Madison, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press. Amin, Samir 1976 Unequal Development: An Essay on the Social Formation of Periphery Capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press. 1980 Class and Nation, Historically and the in the Current Crisis. New York: Monthly Review Press. Ameyaw, Stephen 1990 I'The Dynamics of Female Entrepreneurship in Indigenous Food Markets: A Case Study of Techiman, Ghana' Working Paper Number 205, Women In International Development, Michigan State University, East Lansing. Andreas, Carol 1985 When Women Rebel: The Rise of the Popular Feminism in Peru. Westport, Conn. : Lawrence Hill. Anheier, Helmut K. and Hans Dieter Seibel 1987 Small-Scale Industries and Economic Development in Ghana: Business Behavior and Strategies in Informal Sector Economies. Saarbrucken, Germany: Breitenbach Publishers, Cologne, Development Studies No. 3. Annie, Sheldon, and Peter Hakim 1988 Direct to the Poor: Grassroots Development in Latin America. Boulder, Colo. , : Lynne Rienner Publishers. ‘ ; ‘ *' 344 Anokwa, Kwadwo 1991 Editorial Patterns of Ghanaian Daily Newspapers: A Study of Press Performance Under Civilian and Military Regimes in Ghana. Unpublished Dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan. Ardayfio, E. 1985 I'Wollen and Urban Marketing in Ghana' in R.S. Gallin and A. Spring (eds.) Women Creating Wealth Washington, D.C. : Association of Women in Development. Ardayfio-Schandorf, Elizabeth and Kate Kwafo-Akoto 1990 Women in Ghana: An Annotated Bibliography Accra, Ghana: Woeli Publishing Services. F " Ardener, Shirley 1975 Perceiving Women. New York: Wiley and Sons. Arhin, Kwame 1979 West African Traders in Ghana in the 19th and 20th Centuries. London: Longman. Arsha, Haleh and Caroline Dennis 1992 Women and Adjustment Policies in the Third World. New York: St. Martin's Press. Aryee, G. 1977 Small-Scale Manufacturing Activities: A Study of the Interrelationship between the Formal and Informal Sectors. Geneva: International Labor Organization. 1981 'The Informal Manufacturing Sector in Kumasi' in S.V. Sethuraman (ed.) The Urban Informal Sector in Develgping Cpuntries: Elm“ Poverty and Environment. Geneva: International Labor Office. Aryeetey, Ernest and Mukwanason Hyuha 1993 'The Informal Financial Sector and Markets in Africa: An Empirical Study' in Ajay Chibber and Stanley Fischer (eds.) Economic Reform in Sub-Saharan Africa World Bank Symposium: Washington, D.C. Aryee, Robert L. 1983 Banking on the Poor: The World Bank and World Poverty Cambride, Mass.: MIT Press. Azarya, Victor 1988 'Reordering State-Society Relations: Incorporation and Disengagement' in D. Rothchild and N. Chazan (eds.) The Precarious Balance: State and Society in Africa. Boulder, colorado: Westview Press. 345 .Azarya, V., and.N; Chazan 1987 'Disengagement from the State in.Africa: Reflections on the Experience of Ghana and Guinea' ngperative Studies in Society and Histogy 19. Babb, Florence 1981 Women and Marketing in.Hnaraz, Peru: The Political Economy of Petty Commerce Unpublished Ph.D Dissertation, State university of New York at Buffalo. .1982 Economic Crisis andHAssault on.Marketers in Peru Working Paper Number 6, Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Colgate University. .1988 'From the Field to the Cooking Pot: Economic Crisis and the Threat to Marketers in Peru' in Gracia Clark(ed.) Traders versus the State: Anthrgpplggical Approaches to Unofficial Economies. Boulder, Colorado:‘Westview Press. Bairoch, Paul 1973 Unemployment in Developing Countries: The Nature of the Problem, and Proposals for its Solution. Geneva: I.L.O. Banfield, Edward C. 1970 The Uhheavenly City: The Nature and Future of Our urban Crisis. Boston: Little Brown. BIB“, DeNe' ma Aexe SW“ 1984 'The Urban Informal Sector: A Search for the Processes and Appropriate Strategies.‘ In Samir Amin (ed.) Human Resources, Epiplmept and Develgppept, volume 5: Develgpipg Countries. pp. 243-64. New York: St. Martin's Press. Bates, Robert H. 1981 Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political ' Basis of Agricultural Policies. Berkeley: university of California Press. 1983 'Patterns of Market Intervention in Agrarian.Africa' Food Poliey, November: 297-304. 1988 The Political Economy of Development: A.Rationa1 Choice Perspective Berkeley: university of California Press. Bayart, Jean-Francois 1986 'Civil Society in.Africa' in Patrick Chabal (ed.) Political Domination in.Africa: Reflections on the Limits of Power. Cambridge: Cambridge university Press. Bhatt, Ela 346 1988 'Organizing Self-Employed Women for Self-Reliance in India' in G. Kinnock et al. (eds.) Voice_s for One World. London;, Fontana, pp. 143-165. 1989 'Toward Empowerment' World Develgment, 17 (7): 1059-1065. Benton, L. 1986 'The Role of the Informal Sector In Economic Development: Industrial Restructuring in Spain' Unpublished Dissertation, Department of Anthropology The Johns Hopkins university. Berg, E.J. 1971 I'Structural Transformation Versus Gradualism: Recent Economic Development in Ghana and the Ivory Coast' in P.J. Forster and A.R. Zolberg (eds) Ghana and the Ivogy Coast: Perspectives in Modernization Chicago: Chicago University Press Berger, M. 1989 'Women's Response to Recession in Latin America and the Caribbean: A Focus on Urban Labor Markets', paper presented to the Workshop on ‘Economic Crisis, Household Survival Strategies and Women' s Work' Women's Work', Ithaca, New York. Berger, Peter L. , and Neuhas, Richard John 1977 To Empower People: The Role of Mediating Structures in Public Policy. Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. Berry, S. 1978 'Custom, Class and the Informal Sector: Or Why Marginality Is Not Likely to Pay' African Studies Center: Boston University. Bienfeld, M. 1988 Structural Adjustment and Its Impact on Women in Developing Countries Ottawa: Canadian International Development Agency. Biggs, Tyler. Grindle, Merilee S. and Donald R. Snodgrass 1988 'The Informal Sector, Policy Reform and Structural Transformation' in Jerry Jenkins (ed.) Beyond the Informal Sector: Inclugg' the Excluded in Develpping Countries. A Sequoia Seminar. San Francisco: ICS Press. Bloomberg, Warner 1970 Urban Poverty: Its Social and Political Dimensions. Beverley Hills: Sage Publications. 347 Biersteker, Thomas J. 1990 'Reducing the Role of the State in the Economy: Conceptual Exploration of IMF and the World Bank Prescriptions' International Studies Qperterly 34 (4) December: 477-492. Birkbeck, C. 1978 'Self-Employed Proletarians in an Informal and Formal Factory: The Case of Cali's Garbage Group' World Develgppept Vbl 6 (9-10). Blair, John P. and David.Nachmias 1979 Fiscal Retrenchment and Urban Policy. Beverley Hills, California: Sage Publications. Bratton, M. 1989 'Beyond the State: Civil Society and.Associational Life in.Africa' World Politics 41(3):407-430. Breman, Jan. 1977 Labor Relations in I'Formual' and 'Informal' Sectors: Report of Case Study in Southern Gujarat, India' Journal of Peasant Studies 4 (3-4) April-July. Boahen. Adu Albert 1979 Ghana: Evolution and Change in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. London: Longman. Boateng, E. A. 1967 .A Geography of Ghana. Cambridge university Press. Booker, David E. 1971 Poverty in urban Society :.A Bibliography New York: The Free Press. Bose, Al N; 1984 'Comment,‘ Regigpel Develgppept Dialpgpe 5: 41-48. Boserup, Esther 1970 Women's Role in Economic Development Brookfield, vermont: Gower Publishing Company'Limited. Bourguignon, Francois 199 Adjustment and Equity in Developing Countries: A New Approach. Paris: Development Center for Economic Cooperation and Development Brain,.Alan Richard 1979 The Political Economy of Urbanization in Tanzania unpublished Dissertation, University of British Columbia, Vancouver: Canada. Bratton, Michael 348 1989 'Beyond the State: Civil and Associational Life in Africa' World Politics 41 (4) April. Breman, Jan 1976 I'Labor Relations in the 'Formal' and 'Informal' Sectors: Report of a Case Study in South Gujarat, India' Journal of Peasant Studies 4: 171-205. Brett, E.A 1987 'States and Markets and Private Power in the Developing World: Problems and Possibilities' IDS Bulletin 18(3) :31-38. Bromley, Ray 1978 'Organization, Regulation, and Exploitation in the So-called Urban Informal Sector' : The Street Traders of Cali, Colombia' World Develomept 6:1161-71. 1980 'Municipal Versus Spontaneous Markets? A case study of Urban planning in Cali, Colombia' Third World Planning Review, 2:205-232. 1985 Planning for Small Enterprises in Third World Cities. New York: Pergamon Press . Bromley, Ray and Chris Gerry 1979 'Who are the Casual Poor,ll in Ray Bromley and Chris Gerry (eds.) , Casual Work and Poverty in Third World Cities. Wiley, Chichester. Brunn, Stanley, D. 1974 Urbanization in Developing Countries: an International Bibliography. East Lansing, Michigan. Brandshaw, York 1986 'Overurbanization and Uhderdevelopment in Sub-Saharan Africa : A Crossnational Study' Studies in Cgparative International Develgmt 20 (2): 74-101. Bromley, R. 1978 'The Street Traders of Cali, Columbia- World Develgmpt 6:161-171 Burdette, Marcia 1992 Rethinking Structural Adjustment in the 1990s. London: MacMillan. Campbell, Bonnie K. 1989 Structural Adjustment in Africa Basingstoke: Macmillan. 349 Castells , Manuel 1978 City, Class and Power New York: St. Martin's Press. 1981 Community Participation, Planning and the State in Metropolitan Areas of Developing Countries. Working Paper No. 368 . Berkeley, University of California, Institute of Urban and Regional Development . 1983 The City and the Grassroots. Berkeley: University of California Press. 1987 Global Restructuring and Territorial Development London: Sage Publications. Castells, Manuel and Alejandro Portes 1989 IIWorld underneath: The Origins, Dynamics and Effects of the Informal Economy' in Alejandro Portes, M. Castells and L.A. Benton (eds.) The Informal Etconopyfitudies in Advanced and Less Develpped Countries Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Callaghy, Thomas 1989 'Towards State Capability and Embedded Liberalism in the Third World: Lessons for Economic Adjustment' in Joan M. Nelson (ed.) Fragile Coalitions: The Polipics of Economic Adjustment New Brunswick: Transaction Books. 1990 'Lost Between State and Market: The Politics of Economic Adjustment in Ghana, Zambia, and Nigeria' in Joan M. Nelson(ed.) Economic Crisis and Polig Choice Princeton: Princeton university Press. Callaghy, Thomas M., and John Ravenhill 199 1 Horned In: Responses to Africa's Economic Decline. New York: Columbia University Press. Campbell, John 1985 'Ideology and Politics in the Markets of Ghana' Canadian Journal of African Studies 19 (2) : 423-432. Chamberlain, Joseph 1895 Secretary of State of the Colonies: The House of Canons 22, August. Chan, E. 1979 'The World Economy and Contemporary Migration' International Migration Review 13:204-212 350 Char-mes, Jacques 1990 'A Critical Review of Concepts, Definitions and Studies in the Informal Sector' in OECD, The Informal Sector Revisited, Paris: OECD. Chase-Dunn, C. and Robinson Richard 1979 'Cycles, Trends and New Departures in World-System Development' in John Meyer and Michael Hannan (eds.) National Development in the World-System Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Chazan, Naomi 1982 'The New Politics of Participation in Tropical 1983 The Anatomy of Ghanaian Politics: Managing Africa' Cgparative Politics, (April). Political Recession: 1969-1982 Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. 1986 Ghana: Coping With Uncertainty. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. 1989a 'Gender Perspectives on African States' in J .L. Par-part and K. Staudt (Eds.) Women and the State in Africa 1989b Planning Democracy in Africa: A Comparative Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Perspectives on Nigeria and Ghana Polig §ciencee 22:325-357. 1994 Civil Society and the State in Africa. Boulder, Colo. : L. Reinner. Chazan, Naomi, R. Mortimer, J. Ravenhill and D. Rothchild 1988 Politics and Society in Contemporary Africa Boulder, Colorado: Lynee Rienner Publishers . Checchi and Company 1976 'Small-scale industry Development in Ghana' Washington, D.C. : Checchi and Company, report prepared for the Government of Ghana. Chole, Eshehu 1989 'The African Economic Crisis: Origins and Impact on Society' in M. Jide Bagolun and Gelase Mutahaba (eds.) Economic Restructuring and African Public ministration: Issues Actions and Future Choices Boulder, Colorado: Kumarian Press. Clark, Gracia 1982 Kumasi Central Market: Its Development Potential and Needs, A Report Summary. Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan, Center for African and Afro-American Studies. 351 Gracia Clark 1984 'The Position of Asante Women Traders in the Kumasi Central Market, Ghana' Unpublished Ph.D Dissertation Department of Anthropology, University of 1988 Traders Versus the State Cambridge. 1990 'Class Alliances and Class Formation in Ghanaian Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. Trading and State Formation' Review of African Political Econgy 49 (Winter): 73-83. Clark, Gracia and Tachiwaah Manuh. 1991 II'Market Women and the Structural Adjustment in Ghana' in Christina H. Gladwin (ed.) Structural Adjustment and the African Women Farmers Gainesville, Florida: The university of Florida Press. Cohen, Dennis 1981 Political Economy of Africa: Selected Readings New York: Longmans. Cohen, Monique 1984 The Urban Street Food Trade: Implications for Policy Washington, D.C. : Equity Policy Center. Cohen, R.B. 1981 I'The New International Division of Labor, Multinational Corporations and Urban Hierarchy' in M. Dear and A. J. Scott (eds.) Urbanization and Urban Planniég in Capitaliet Society London: Methuren. COOper, F. 1983 Struggle for the City: Migrant Labor, Capital and the State in Urban Africa. Beverly Hills, California: Sage Publications. Cornia, G.A., R. Jolly and F. Stewart 1987 Adjustment with a Human Face Oxford: Oxford university Press. Cornia, Giovanni A. , Rolph Hoeren and Thandika Mkandawire 1992 Africa's Recovery in the 1990s New York: St. Martin's Press. Daaku, K. 1971 I'Trade and Trading Patterns of the Akan in the Seventh and Eighteenth Centuries' in C. Meillasoux (eds.) The Develgmpt of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa. 352 Das, Veechila 1984 I'Informal Sector in Socialist Economies: A Reexamination of the Relationship of the Informal Sector to DevelOpment' Regional Develemt Dialegee 5(2) :123-134 Date-Baah, Eugene 1986 ''Sex Inequalities and Discrimination in Accra-Toma: Causes and Consequences' in R. Anker and C. Hein (eds.) Sex Ingu_alities in Urban melmept in the Third World. New York: St, Martin's Press. Davies, Robert 1978 The Informal Sector: a Solution to unemployment? London: Catholic Institute for International Relations. Davis, John E. 1991 Contested Ground: Collective Action and the Urban Neighborhood. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press . Davis, Lenwood, G. 1977 Migration to African Cities: an Introductory Survey. Monticello, Illinois: Council for Planning Librarians. Dawson, Jonathan. 1988 'Small-scale Industry in Ghana: A case-study of Kumasi' London: Overseas Development Administration, ESCOR. Dennis, C. 1989 'Constructuring a 'Career' under Conditions of Economic Crisis and Structural Adjustment: The Survival Strategies of Nigerian Women' in H. Afshar (ed.) Women, Develemt and Survival in the Third World London: Longman. Department of Housing and Planning 1971 'Social and Economic Study of Suame Magazine, Kumasi' Kumasi: University of Science and Technology. De Soto, Henando 1988 'Constraints on People: The Origins of Underground Economies and Limits to Their Growth' in Jerry Jenkins (ed.) Beyond the Informal Sector: Including the Excluded in Develeping Qountries. San Francisco: Institute For Contemporary Studies for the USAID. 1989 The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper and Row. 353 Development Group for Alternative Policies 1992 'The Other Side of the Story: The Real Impact of World Bank and IMF Adjustment Programs' Washington, D.C. Dewar, D. and V. Watson 1981 I'Urbanization, Unemployment and Petty Comodity Production and Trading : Comparative Cases in Cape Town' in David M. Smith (ed.) Livi__r_1g Under _A_pertheid London: Allen and Unwin. Diamond, Larry 1992 The Democratic Revolution: Struggles for Freedom and Pluralism in the Developing World. New York: Freedom House . Dickson, Kwabina A. 1972 A Historical Geography of Ghana. London: Cambridge University Press . Dolphyne, Florence Abena 1991 The Emancipation of Women: An African Perspective Accra: Ghana Universities Press. Doornbos, M. 1990 ll'The African state in Academic Debate: Retrospect and Prospect.‘ Journal of Modern African Studies, 28:179-198. Drakakis-Smith, David 1986 Urbanization in the Developing World Dover, New Hampshire. . 'Urban Food Distribution in Asia and Africa' The Geegzaphical Journal March, 157 (1) : 51-60 Dumor, Ernest K. 1982 I'Commodity Queens and the Distributive Trade in Ghana: A Socio-Historical Analysis' African Urban Studies: 12, (Winter) :27-45 Eades, J.S. 1985 'If You Can't Beat 'em, Join 'em: State Regulation of Small Enterprises', in Ray Bromley (ed.) le For Small Enterprises in Third World Cities Oxford: Pergamon Press. Economic Commission for Africa 1989 African Alternative to Structural Adjustment Programs. Addie Abba, Ethiopia. Economic Intelligence Unit 1993 Ghana: A Country Profile. London. Effron, Laurie 354 1980 The Informal Sector in Abidjan, Ivory Coast: a Case Study. Unpublished Dissertation, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan. Egan, Mary Lou 1986 'The Rural-Urban Dimension in National Economic Development'' Journal of Develmt Areas 20 (2) : 203-221. Elson, D. 1989 I'The Impact of Structural Adjustment on Women: Concepts and Issues' in B. Onimode (ed.) The IMF, the World Bank and African Debt, vol. 2. London: Zed Press. Ewusi, Kojo 1987 IIUrbanization, Modernization and Employment of Women in Ghana' Accra, Ghana: Adwinsa Publishers. Fainstein, Susan S. 1987 I'Local Mobilization and Economic Discontent- in Michael P. Smith and Joe R. Feagin (eds.) The Capitalist City: Global Restructurgg' and Community Politics New York: B. Blackwell. Fernandez-Kelly, M.P. 1983 For We Are Sold: Women and Industry in Mexico's Frontier. New York: State University of New York Press. Frank, Andre Gunder 1967 Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America: Historical Studies of Chile and Brazil New York: Monthly Review Press. 1979 Dependent Accumulation and Underdevelopment New York: Monthly Review Press Freidberg, Susanne Elizabeth 1991 Market Women and State Violence in West Africa. (Unpublished Thesis, University of California at Berkeley); berkeley, California. Friedmann, John 1988 Life Space and Economic Space: Essays in Third World Planning. Brunswick, N.J. : Transaction Books. 1989 'The Latin American Barrio Movement as a Social Movement: Contribution to a Debate. " International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 13 (3) : 501-510. 1992 Empowerment: The Politics of Alternative Development Cambridge, MA. : Blackwell. 355 Friedman, Debra and Doug McAdam 1992 'Collective Identity and Activism: Networks, Choices, and the Life of a Social Movement' in.Aldeon Morris and Carol M; Mueller (eds.) Frontiers in Social Movement Theopy. New York: Random.House. Friedmann, John, and M. Salguero 1988 'The Barrio Economy and Collective Self-empowerment in Latin America: A Framework and Agenda for Research' in M.P. Smith (ed.) Power. Community and the City. New'Brunswick: Transaction Books. Frimpong-Ansah, Jenathan H. 1989 'The Adjustment Process in Ghana in the Historical Context,‘ DERC/GDA.Symposium, University of Warwick, April. 1992 The vampire State in.Africa: The Political Economy of Decline in Ghana. Trenton, New Jersey: Africa World Press. Frohlich,‘Willy 1982 The African.Market System. Vancouver, B.C., Canada: Tantalus Research Limited. Garlick, Peter C. 1971 2African Traders and Economic Development in Ghana Oxford: Claredon Press. Geertz, Clifford 1978 I'The Bazaar Economy: Information and Change in Peasant Marketing' American Economic Review, May. Ghana Enterprises Development Commission ‘ 1976 I'The Policy and Guidelines of the GEDC for the Administration of Small Business Loan Scheme. Accra: GEDC. Ghana.News 1983 Vbl. 12 (2):8 Washington, D.C. Ghana, Republic of. 1962 1960 Population of Ghana, Vbl. ll, Statistics of 1974 Report on the Role and.Activities of the Office of Business Promotion. Accra: Ghana Publishing Corporation. 1983 Economic Recovery Program (1984-1986): Review of Progress in 1984 and Goals for 1985 and 1986, Report Prepared for the Second.Meeting of the Consultative Group for Ghana: Paris. 1986 1984 Population Census of Ghana. Accra: Central Bureau of Statistics. 356 Ghana, Republic of. 1987 District Political Authority and Modalities for District Level Elections Accra: Ghana Publishing Corporation. . National program for Economic Development. Accra, Ghana: Ghana Publishing Corporation. 1988 Local Government Law Accra: Ghana Publishing Corporation. . Revolution Brings Progress to Ghana Accra: Information Services Department. 1989 Towards a New Dynamism Accra, Ghana: Government Printer. Ghosh, Prandip 1984 Urban Development in the Third'World Westport: Greenwood Press. Gilbert, Alan 1992 Cities, Poverty and Development: Urbanization in the Third.World Oxford: Oxford University Press. Girvan, Norman, Richard Bernal, and‘Wesley Hughes 1980 'The IMF and the Third.World: The Case of Jamaica, 1974-1980' Develepeept Dialegee, 2:113-155. Goldstein, Morris 1986 I'The Global Effect of Fund-Supported.Adjustment Program.Occasiona1 Paper No.42, International Monetary Fund. Washington, D.C. Graham, Yao 1984 'Ghana: The Politics of Crisis: Class Struggle and Organization (1976-1983)' Paper Presented to the Review of.African Political Economy Conference, University of Keele, Great Britain. Gramsci, Antonio 1971 Selections from the Prison Notebooks. New’ Ybrk: International Publishers. Gran, Colin 1988 The Informal Sector in Sub-Saharan.Africa: An Annotated Bibliography. Washington, D.C.:Resources for Development and Democracy. Gray, Jane 1987 'Conference on the Comparative Study of the Informal Sector' International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 11(3): 421-423. 357 Green, Reginald H. 1981 Magendo in the Political Economy of Uganda: Pathology, Parallel System or Dominant Sub-Mode of Production? IDS Discussion Paper Number 164. Brighton: University of Sussex. 1986 'Stabilization and Adjustment Programs and Policies in Ghana' Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research. 1988 I'Ghana: Progress, Probl-atics, and Limitations of the Success Story' IDS Bulletin 19 (January). Greenstreet, Miranda 1971 'Employment of Women in Ghana- International Labor Review, 103(2), February. 1981 'When Education Is Unequal' IDS Bulletin 12 (3) :14-18 Grier, Beverly 1988 I'Pawns, Porters and Petty Traders: Women in Transition to Export Agriculture in Agriculture' Working Papers in African Studies Number 144 Boston: Boston University. Grown, Caren 1989 'Beyond Survival: Expanding Income-Earning Opportunities For Women in Developing Countries'I World Develemt 17 (7) , July. Gulhati, Ravi 1988 The Political Economy of Reform in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economic Development Policy Seminar Number 8. Washington, D.C. : World Bank. Gutkind, Peter 1973 'From the Energy of Despair to the Anger of Despair: The Transition from Social circulation to Political Consciousness among the Urban Poor of Africa- Canadian Journal of African Studies 7:179-198. Guyer, Jane I. 1987 Feeding African Cities: Studies in Regional Social History London: Manchester University Press. Haggard, Stephan and Robert R. Kaufman 1992 The Politics of Economic Adjustment Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Hansen, E. and K. A. Ninsin 1989 The State, Development, and politics in Ghana London: Codesria Book Series. 358 Hart, K. 1970 'Small-scale Enterprises in Ghana and Development Planning' The Journal Of Develmt Studies, July: 103-20. 1973 'Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Unemployment in Ghana' Journal Of Modern African Studies, March: 61-89. 1976 'The Politics of Unemployment in Ghana- African Affairs Lm (301) October: 488-489 Hayser, N. 1981 Women, Subsistence and the Informal Sector: Towards a Framework of Analysis. Sussex: Institute of Development Studies. Henning, Peter H. 1978 The Urban Popular Economy and the Informal Sector Production. Ann Arbor, Michigan: Center for Economic Development . Haggard, Stephen and Robert R. Kaufman 1992 The Politics of Economic Adjustment: International Constraints, Distributive Conflicts, and the State Princeton: Princeton University Press. Hamilton, Simms Ruth 1967 Urban Social Differentiation and Membership Recruitment Among Selected Voluntary Associations in Accra, Ghana. (Unpublished Ph.D Dissertation, Northwestern University) . Haynes, J. 1986 'The Evolution and Destruction of I'People's Power' in Ghana, 1982-1986' Paper presented to the Review of African Political Economy Conference, University of Liverpool, Great Britain. 1989 'Ghana: Indebtedness, Recovery, and the International Monetary Fund (1977-87)" in T.W. Parfitt and S.P. Riley (eds.) The African Debt Crisis London: Routhledge. Henry, S. 1978 The Hidden Economy London: Martin Robertson Press. Henson, Jeffrey, and Manuel Castells 1987 Global Restructuring and Territorial Development London: Sage Publications. 359 Herbst, Jeffrey 1990 'The Politics of Reform in Africa: The Lessons of Ghana' UFS Field Staff Reports, Africa/Middle east 1989-1990 No. 15. Indianapolis: Universities Field Staff International. 1993 The Politics of Reform in Ghana, 1982-1991 Berkeley: University of California Press. Higgins, J. 1989 ''How Poor Women Earn Income in Sub-Saharan Africa and What Works Against Them' World Develepggt, July. Heyzer, Noeleen 1981 Women, Subsistence and the Informal Economy: Towards A Framework of Analysis Brighton, England: IDS Publication. Hill, Polly 1962 Some Characteristics of the West African Economic Enterprise. Ibadan, Nigeria: Nigerian Institute of Social and Economic Research, March. 1963 The Migrant Cocoa Farmers of Southern Ghana: A study in Rural Capitalism Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1966 I'Notes on Traditional Market Authority and Market Periodicity in West Africa'. Journal of African Histopy: 295-311. Hodges, Tony 1988 'Ghana's Strategies for Adjustment with Growth' Africa Recoveg 2 (August). Howard, Rhoda 1976 I'Economic Imperiali- and Oligopolization of Trade in the Gold Coast, 1896-1939' UFAHAMU 7(1) :71-94 Huq, u. n. 1989 The Economy of Ghana: The First 25 Years London: Macmillan. Hutchful, Eboe 1985 'International Monetary Fund Adjustment Policies in Ghana Since 1966' African Develement 10 (1,2) :122-135 1989 'From Revolution to Monetarism: the Economics and Politics of the Adjustment Program in Ghana' in Bone K. Campbell and Loxley (eds.) Structural Adjustment in Africa. London: Macmillan. Hymer, Stephen H. 360 I'The Political Economy of the Gold Coast and Ghana' in G. Ranis (ed.) Government and Economic Develemt New Haven: Yale University Press. Ibrahim, S.B. 1985 'The Development of Local Engineering Capability in Ghana: The Potential of Small-scale Informal Metal Enterprises' Glasgow: University of Strathclyde. Ifeka-Moller, Caroline 1975 I'Female Militancy and Colonial Revolt: The Women's War of 1929, Eastern Nigeria'' in Shirley Ardener (ed.) Perceivipg Women: John Wiley and Sons. Integrated Development Consultants 1993 Final Report of Infrastructural Development: Kumasi Central Market Project. Kumasi. International Labor Organization 1972 Deployment, Incomes and Inequality: A Strategy for Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya. Geneva. 1985 The Informal Sector in Africa. Geneva. 1989 African Employment Report. Addis Ababa: Ethiopia 1991 'The Dilemma of the Informal Sector', Report of the Director-General, International Labor Conference, 78th Session, Geneva. . The Urban Informal Sector In Africa in Retrospect and Prospect: An Annotated Bibliography. Geneva. International Monetary Fund 1991 Ghana, Adjustment and Growth: 1983-1991 Washington, D.C: IMF. Jenkins, Jerry 1988 Beyond the Informal Sector: Including the Excluded in Developing Countries. San Francisco: Just For the Contemporary Studies Press. Jonah, Kwesi 1992 I'The Social Impact of Ghana's Adjustment Program' in pp. 140-152, Bade Onimode (ed.) The IMF, The World Bank and the African Debt. London: Zed Books Limited The Institute for African Alternatives. Johnson, Cheryl 1982 'Graesroots Organizing: Women in Anti-Colonial Activity in Southwestern Nigeria' African Studies Review 25 (2) June. 361 Kamara, S., M.T. Dahniya, and P. Greene 1990 The Effect of Structural Adjustment Policies on Human Welfare In Africa South of the Sahara. Freetown, Sierra Leone: UNICEF, April. Kannappan, Subbiah 1985 'Urban Employment and the Labor Market in Developing Nations', Economic Develemt and Cultural M8, 33 669-730. 1988 'Urban Labor Markets and Development' World Bank Research Observer 3, (2) : 189-206. my. Gene 1972 The Political economy of Colonialism in Ghana: A Collection of Docmnents and Statistics (1900-1960) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kaneda, Hiromitsu and Bruce F. Johnston 1961 I'Urban Food Expenditure Patterns in Tropical Africa' Food Research Institute Studies 2(3) :229-275 Kapur, Ishan 1991 Ghana: Adjustment and Growth, 1983-1991 Washington, D.C. : International Fund. Kennedy, Paul T. 1983 I'Workers in Petty Production, Accra, Ghana: Towards Proletarization' Labor, Capital and Society (April) 1981 'Role and Position of Petty Producers in a West African City'I Journal of Modern African Studies, 19, 40 (December): 565-594. 1980 I'Ghanaian Businessmen: From Artisan to Capitalist Entrepreneur in a Dependent Economy. " Munich: Weltforum Verlag, 4 (IFO-Institute for Economic Research, Africa-Studien No. 106) . 1977 'Indigenous Capitalism in Ghana' Review of African Political Econgy (January): 125-140. Kerner, Donna O. 1988 'Hard Work' and Informal Sector Trade in Tanzania' in Gracia Clark (ed.) Traders Versus the State: Anthrepelegical epproaches to Unofficial Economies Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. Kling, Joseph M. , and Prudence Posner 1991 'Class and Community: Theories of Activism in an Era of Urban Transformation'I in M.P. Smith (ed.) Breaking Chains :Social Movements and Collective Action Comparative Urban and Communi ty Research. New Brunswick: Transaction Books. 5 pa- 362 Krassowski, Andrzes 197 Development and the Debt Trap London: Crown Helm Kraus, Jon 1980 I'The Political Economy of Conflict in Ghana,‘ Africa Remrt, HIV, 2. Killick, Tony 1978 Development Economics in Action: A Case of Economic Policies in Ghana. London: Heineman. Kling, Joseph and Prudence Posner 1991 ''Class and Community: Theories of Activism in An Era of Urban Transformation' in Michael P. Smith (ed.) Breaking Chains: Social Movements and Collective Action. Comparative Urban and Community Research. New Brunswick: Transactions. Korten, David C. and Rudi Klaus 1984 People-Centered Development: Contributions Toward Theory and Planning Frameworks . West Hartford, Conn. : Kumarian Press. Kuiper, M. 1991 Women Entrepreneurs in Africa Geneva: International Labor Office Lange, Peter and Merino Regini 1989 State, Markets, and Social Regulation: New Perspectives in Italy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lawrence, Peter 1986 World Recession and the Food Crisis in Africa London, England: James Currie. Lebrun O. and C. Gerry 1975 I'Petty Producers and Capitalism' Review of African Political Econgy (3) :20-32. Lessinger, Johanna - 1985 'Nobody here To Yell At Me: Political Activism Among Petty Retail Traders In An Indian City' in Smart Plattner (ed.) Markets and Marketing: Monegpaphs in Economic Anthremlegy. New York: Doubleday. Letlaka, T. 1982 'First World Norms in a Third World Environment: Problems Related to Informal Economic Activity' Paper Presented at a University of Transkei 'Development Forum' Seminars. 363 Levitsky, J. 1989 'Micro-enterprises in Developing Countries' London: Intermediate Technology Publications. Lewin, Thomas J. 1978 Asante before the British: The Prempean Years, 1875-1900. Lawrence, Kansas: regents Press of Kansas. Lewis, W.A. 1954 'Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor', Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies, 20:139-192. Liedholm, Carl and Mead, Donald 1982 Small-Scale Industries in Developing Countries: Empirical EVidence and Policy Implications. East Lansing: Michigan State University. Liedholm, Carl and Enyima Chuta 1976 The Economics of Rural and Urban Small-scale Industries in Sierra Leone. African Rural Economy Paper 8 14. East Lansing, Michigan. Liedholm, Carl and Joan Parker 1989 Small Scale Manufacturing Growth in Africa: Initial Evidence. Michigan State University International Development Papers, Working Paper #33 : East Lansing. Lineberry, William P. 1989 Assessing Participatory Development: Rhetoric Versus Reality. Boulder, Colo. : Westview Press. Lipton, M. 1976 Why Poor People Stay Poor: Urban Bias in World Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Little, Kenneth 1962 'Some Traditionally-based Forms of Mutual Aid in West African Urbanization'. Ethnolegy, 1(2), April. 1972 'Voluntary Associations and Social Mobility among West African Women' Canadian Journal of African Studies 1 (3) :276-281) . Logan, Kathleen 1989 'Latin American Urban Mobilizations: Women's Participation and Self-Empowerment, " In Gmelch and Zenner (eds.) Urban Life: ReadLng's In Urban Anthremlegy. New York: St. Martin's Press. 364 Loxley, John 1986 'Alternative Approaches to Stabilization in Africa' in Gerald K. Helleiner (ed.) Africa and the International Monetag Fund Washington, D.C. : International Monetary Fund. 1988 Ghana: Economic Crisis and the Long Road to Recovery Ottawa, Canada: The North-South Institute. 1990 'Structural Adjustment in Africa: Reflections on Ghana and Zambia' Review of Africa Political Econgmyy 47 (Spring) :8-27. Lozano, B. 1985 'High Technology, Cottage Industry' Ph.D Dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of California, Davis. Lubell, Harold ‘ 1978 I'Urban Development and Employment in the Third World Metropolis' International Labor Review, 117 :747-56. .1990 l'Resilience Amidst Crisis: The Informal Sector of Dakar' International Labor Review 129 (3), June. .1992 The Informal Sector In the 1980s and 1990s Paris: OECD. Macciocchi, Maria-Antonietta 1974 Pour Gramsci. Paris: Editions du Seuil. Manor, James 1991 Rethinking Third World Politics. London: Longman. McCoskie, M. 1986 'Ghana: Recent History' in Africa South of the Sahara 16th Edition (London: European Publication Limited) . Mpose, G.S. 1990 Informal Sector In Zambia: Employment Consequences of the Legal and Regulatory Frame' Geneva: ILO/WEP Research Working Paper Series, WEP 2-19/WP.53 Makinwa, Kofo P. and Ozo, A.O. 1987 The Urban Poor in Nigeria. Lagos: Evans Brothers. Maliyamkono, T.L. and M.S.D. Bagachwa 1990 The Second Economy in Tanzania Ohio University Press. 365 March, Kathryn S. and Rachelle L Taggu 1986 Women's Informal Associations in Developing Countries: Catalysts for Change? Boulder: Westview. Massey, Doreen B. 1988 Global Restructuring, Local Responses. Worcester, Mass. : Graduate School of Geography, Clark University. McKee, K. 1989 'Microlevel Strategies for Supporting Livelihoods, hipth and Income Generation in the Third World: The Challenge of Significance' World Develmt, July. McLaughlin, S. 1990 'Skill Training for the Informal Sector: Analyzing the Success and Limitations of Support Programs' in OECD, The Informal Sector Revisited Paris: OECD. McCall, D.F. 1962 'The Koforidua Market'. In Paul Bohannan and G. Dalton (ed.) Evanston, Ill.: NorthwesternUUniversity Press. McCormick, Dorothy 1984 Small Enterprise in Nairobi: Golden Opportunity or Dead-End? Unpublished Dissertation, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore. Mead, Donald C. 1989 'Policy Reform and the Informal Sector In Africa' Washington, D.C.: USAID. Mensah, A.H.O 1986 'Some Aspects of Economic Regimentation: Ghana's Experience with Price and Import Controls' Journal of Modern African Studies 13 (2) Sui-er. “Chel-R°thp 1990 Haiti, State Against Nation, The Origins and Legacy of Duverialism. New York: Monthly Review Press. Midgal, J .S. 1988 Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society Relations and State Capabilities in the Third World. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. 366 Mills, Edwin S . 1972 Studies in the Structure of Urban Economy. Maryland: Johns Hopkins Press. Milton, Santos 1979 The Shared Space: The Two Circuits of the Urban Economy in Underdeveloped Countries. London: Mbthuel. Mingione, E. 1983 'Informalization, Restructuring, and the Survival Strategies of the Working Class'I International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 7:311-39. Molyneux, Maxine 1985 I'M’obilization‘Without Emancipation? Women's Interests, the State, and Revolution in Nicaragua' Feminist Studies, 11 (20:227-254). Morrison, Thomas K., and J.H. Wolgin 1980 'Prospects for Economic Stabilization in Ghana.‘ Paper Presented at African Studies Association Meetings, Philadelphia, October. Moser, Calorine O. 1978a 'The Informal Sector Reworked: Viability and Vulnerability in Urban Development'I Regional Develepeept Dialegee 5 (2): 135-178. 1978b 'Informal Sector or Petty Commodity Production: Dualism.or Dependence in Urban Development?- World Develgpgegt 6: 1041-1064. . 1984 'The Informal Sector Reworked: Viability and Vulnerability in Urban Development' Regional Develepeept Dialegee 5(2):135-178. . 1989 'Gender Planning in the Third‘World: Meeting Practical and Strategic Gender Needs,- World.Develep!en . 17 (ll):l799-1825. Maser, Clans A. and Kalton, G. 1971 Survey Methods in Social Investigation London: Heineman Educational Books. Mosley, Paul 1978 Implicit Models and Policy Recommendations: Policy towards the Informal Sector in Kenya. Nairobi: Institute of Develepeeet Studies Bulletinl February: 3-10. 367 Mosley, Paul 1987 'Conditionality as a Bargaining Process: Structural- Adjustment Lending, 1980-86", Essays in International Finance, Princeton University No. 168 (October) . Murrillo, G. and Cartier W.M. 1988 'Urbanization, the Informal Sector and Migration: Issues for Research and Cooperation " Canadian Journal Of Deyelemt Studies 9:15-20. National Council on Women and Development 1985 Annual Report: 1980-1984 Accra, Ghana. Nattras, Ninoli Jean 1987 'Street Trading in Transkei: A Struggle Against Poverty, Persecution and Prosecution' World Develgmgt 15 (7) :861-875 Nelson, J. M. 1979 Access to Power: Politics and the Urban Poor in Developing Countries. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. 1989 Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Ajustment. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Books. Nicholle, William M., and William, A. 1983 The Informal Economy: Where the People are the Bottom Line. Ottawa: Vanier Institute of the Family. Ninsin, Kwame A. 1989 'Thirty Seven Years of Development Experience' in Kwame A. Ninsin and Emmanuel Hansen, The State. Develemt and Politics in Ghana London: CODESDRIA Book Series . 1991 The Informal Sector in Ghana's Political Economy Accra: Freedom Publications. Nyang'oro, Julius 1986 'On the Concept of ‘Corporatism' and the African State' Studies in Cmative Internatigel Develemt 21(4). 1992 I'The Evolving Role of the African State Under Structural Adjustment' in Nyan'goro Jilius E. and Timothy M. Shaw (eds.) Bemnd Structural Adjustment in Africa: The Political Econm of Sustainable and Democratic Develemt New York: Praeger . 368 Nypan, Astrid 1960 Market Trade: A Sample Survey of Market Traders in Accra. African Business Series No. 2. Legon: University of Ghana Press. Obbo, C. 1980 African Women: Their Struggle for Economic Independence. London: Zed Press. O'Connor, James 1973 The Fiscal Crisi of the State. new York: St. Martin's Press. Overbeek, Henk 1993 Restructuring hegemony in the Global Political Economy: The Rise of Transnational Neo-Liberalism in the 1980s. New York: Routhledge. Parpart, Jane L. 1986 Women and the State in Africa Working Paper #117, Michigan State University, Office of Women in International Development East Lansing, Michigan. Parpart, J. and Staudt K. 1989 Women and the State in Africa. Boulder: Lynne Reinner. Paul, Linda A. 1985 The Urban Informal Sector in Economic Development. Unpublished Dissertation, University of Maryland. Pearce, T.O., Kujore, and V. Abboh-Bankole 1984 Generating Income in the Urban Environment: The Experience of street Vendors in Ille-Ife, Nigeria New York: International African Institute. Peattie, L. R. 1979 'The Organization of the ‘Marginals" Cmative Urban Research 7(2). .1981 'What is to Be Done with the 'Informal Sector' : A Case Study of Shoe Manufacturers in Colombia.- Department of City and Regional Planning, MIT. Pellow, Deborah and Naomi Chazan 1986 Ghana: Coping With Uncertainty Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. Petchenkine, Youry 1993 Ghana: In Search of Stability, 1957-1992 Westport, Connecticut: Praeger. 369 Plotkin, Sidney 1991 I'Community and Alienation: Enclave Consciousness and Urban Movements' in Michael P. Smith (ed.) Breaking Chain: Social Movements and Collective Action. Comparative Urban and Community Research . New Brunswick: Transaction. Polanyi, Karl 1957 The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Boston: Beacon Press. Portes, A. 1983 'The Informal Sector: Definition, Controversy and Relation to National Development' Pemlation and Develepmt Review, Sumner. 1985 I'Urbanization, Migration and Models of Development in Latin America' in John Walton (ed.) Capital and Labor in the Urbanized World. 1986 'The Urban Informal Sector in Uruguay: Its Internal Structure, Characteristics, and Effects' World Develege_nt 14:727-741. 1989 'When More Can Be Less: Labor Standards, Development, and the Informal Economy' A Paper Presented at CASID Distinguished Speaker Series, Michigan State University, East Lansing. Portes, A., and J. Borcoz 1988 'The Informal Sector Under Capitalism and State Socialism: A Preliminary Comparison,I Social Justice, 15(3-4): 17-28. Portes, A. , Manuel Castells, Lauren Benton 1989 Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Developed Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press . .1984 'Industrial Development and Labor Absorption: A Reinterpretation' Pepulation and Develemt Review 10 (December): 589-611. Portes, A. and S. Sassen-Koob 1987 'Making It Underground: Comparative Material on the Urban Informal Sector in Western Market Economies. ' American Journal Of Sociolegy 93 : 30-61 . Portes, A, and John Walton 1981 Labor Class and the International System New York: Academic Press. 370 Portes, A. and W. Walton 1976 Urban latin America: The Political Condition from Above and Below..Austin, Texas: University of Texas Press. Powell, J.W. 1986 'Ghana: A.Grass-Roots Industrial Revolution' Apprepriate Technolegy, 13, 3 (Intermediate Technology'Insert) 1981 I'Strategy for the Development of Informal Industries in Ghana' Planning Outlook, 23, 1:33-37. Preteceille, Edmund 1991 State Restructuring and Local Power: A.Comparative Perspective. New York:Pinter Publishers. Rattray, Robert Sutherland 1945 Religion and Art in Ashanti. 2Accra: Presbyterian Book Depot. Ray, Donald I. 1986 Ghana: Politics, Economics, and Society Boulder, Colorado: L. Rienner Publishers. Rim-er, Douglas 1966 'The Crisis in the Ghanaian Economy' Journal of Modern.African Studies 4(1) 1992 Staying Poor: Ghana's Political Economy: 1950-1980 New York: Pergamon Press. Robertson, Claire 1983 'The Death of Makola and Other Tragedies- Cepedian Journal of African Studies 17:469-495. Robertson, Claire and I. Berger 1986 Women and Class in.Africa. New York:.Africana Publishing Company. Rodney,‘Walter 1981 How Europe Underdeveloped.Africa ‘Washington, D.C.: Howard University Press. Ross, David P., and Peter J. Usher 1986 From the Roots Up: Economic Development As If Community Mattered. Croton-On-Hudson, New York: Bootstrap Press. 371 Rothchild, D. 1987 'Hegemony and State Softness: some Variations in Elite Responses.‘ in Z. Ergas (ed.) The African State in Transition London: The MacMillan Press. Rothchild, Donald and Gyimah-Boadi E. 1986 'Ghana's Economic Decline and Development Strategies' in John Ravenhill (ed.) African Economic Crisis London: Macmillan. Sacke, J. 1982 'The Umfata City Council's Policy Towards the Informal Trading Sector'I Paper Presented at University of Transkei Workshop on 'Hawkers'. ' Safe, H. 1987 'Urbanization, The Informal economy and State Policy in Latin America' in M. Smith and J. Feagin, The Capitalist City. Oxford: Basic Blackwell. Sai, Florence A. 1978 'Women Traders' in Proceedings of the Seminar on Ghanaian Women in Development, Vol.1: 226-250. Organized by the National Council on Women and Development, Accra, Ghana. Sampson, S.L. 1987 I'The Second Economy of the Soviet Union and Eastern Em-'<>P¢'-!' Annals of the American Acadg of Political and Social Sciences, 493 (Septenber). Sandbrook, Richard 1972 'The Political Potential of African Urban Workers' Canadian 19E]- of African Studies, 11(3) : 441-453. Sanyal, B. 1988 'The Urban Informal Sector Revisited,- Third World le Review 10(1): 65-84. 1991 'Organizing the Self-Employed: The Politics of the Urban Informal Sector'I Integtional Lemr Rgig, 130 (1) . 372 Sarin, Madha 1979 “Urban Planning, Petty Trading and Squatter Settlements in Chandigarh, India" in R. Bromley and C. Gerry(eds.) Casual Work and Poverty in Third World Cities (133-180). Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, Ltd. Sassen-Koob, Saskia 1989 I'NewYork City's Informal Economy" in Alejandro Portes, M. Castells and Lauren Benton (eds.) The Informal Economy: Studies In Advanced and Less Developed Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Sassoon, Anne Showstack 1987 women and the State: The Shifting Boundaries of Public and Private. London: Hutchinson Education. Sawyerr, Akilagpa 1990 The Political Dimension of Structural Adjustment Programmes in Sub-Saharan Africa Accra: Ghana Universities Press. Scheuerman, Will E. 1994 Private Interest, Public Spending: balanced Budget Conservatism.and the Fiscal Crisis. Boston, Mass: South-End Press. Schildrout, Enid 1978 The People of the Zongo:the Transformation of Ethnic Identities in Ghana. Ca,bridge:Cambridge University Press. Schwimmer, Brian Elian 1976 The Social Organization of Marketing in a Southern Ghanaian Town (Unpublished Dissertation, Stanford University, California). Scott, Earl P. 1985 'Lusaka's Informal Sector in National Economic Development" Journal of Developing Areas 20 (1): 71-99. Scott, James C. 1976 Moral Economy of the Peasants: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asa. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press. 1985 Weapons of the weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New Haven, Conn. : Yale University Press. 1990 Domination and the Art of Resistance: Hidden Transcripts. New Haven, Conn. : Yale University Press. Sebstad, J. 1982 Struggle and Development Among Self-Employed women A Report on the Self-Employed women's Association. Washington, D.C.: USAID. 373 Sen, Amartya 1990 Gender and Cooperative Conflicts. In Irene Tinker (ed.)Persistent Inegpalities: women and world Development, New York: Oxford University Press. Senghaas-Knobloch, Eva 1977 "Informal Sector and Peripheral Capitalism: A Critique of Prevailing Concept of Development“ Manpower and Unepployeent Research 10: 3-24. Sethuraman, S.V. 1974 Towards a Definition of the Informal Sector Geneva: International Labor Office (mimeo.) 1976 "The Urban Informal Sector: Concepts, Measurement and Policy" International Labor Review 114 (1): 69-81. 1977 "Employment Promotion in the Informal Sector in Ghana" Geneva: ILO, WEP 2-19/WP 24. 1981 The Urban Informal Sector in Developing Countries: Employment, Poverty and Environment. I.L.O.: Geneva. Shaw, Timothy M. 1985 Towards a Political Economy For Africa: The Dialectics of Dependence. London: MacMillan. 1990 "Dependent Development in the New International Division of Labor: Prospects for Africa's Political Economy" in D.G. Haglund and M.K. Hawes (eds.) World Politice : Power, Interdependence and Dependence Toronto: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. 1991 New'Factors and.Forces In.Africa's Political Economy: Reformism.and Revisionism, London: Macmillan. 1992 "Africa.After the Crises of the 1980s: The Dialectics of Adjustment." In M. Hawkesworthand M. Kogan (eds.) Routledge Encyclopedia of Government and Politics London: Routledge. Shillington, Kevin 1992 Ghana and the Rawlings Factor New York: St. Martin's Press. Simms, Ruth and Ernest Dumor 1976 "women In the Urban Economy of Ghana: Associational Activity and the Urban Enclave" African Urban Notesl 3:43-64. 374 Sinclair, Stuart W 1976 "Informal Economic Activity in African Cities: Proposals for Research" Journal of Modern African Studies 14:696-699. Singh, Ajit 1984 "The Interrupted Revolution of the Third World: Prospects and Policies for Resumption". Industgy and Development 12: 43-68. 1978 Urbanization and Labor Markets in Developing Countries. New York: St. Martin's Press. Skocpol, Theda 1979 States and Social Revolutions: A.Comparative.Analysis of France, Russia, and China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Slater, David 1989 "Territorial Power'and.the Peripheral State: The Issue of Decentralization“, Development end Change 20(3): 501-532. smith, Dene 1987 'Overurbanization Reconceptualized: A Political Economy of the world-System.Approach' Urban Affairs Qearterly 23: 270-94. Smith, Michael P. 1988 City, State, and Market: The Political Economy of Urban Society. New York: B. Blackwell. 1990 Breaking The Chains: Urban Social Movements and Collective Action. Beverley Hills: Sage Publications. Sonnu, S.B.K. 1975 "The wayside Fitters: A Study of Small-scale Vehicle Repair Activities in Urban Areas of Ghana.“ Kumasi: University of Science and Technology. Souza, Paulo R. and Victor Tokman . 1976 "The Informal Sector in Latin America" International Labor Review 3:355-365. Sowah, Nii K. 1990 The Socio-Economic Consequences of Structural Adjustment Program in Ghana. A Study Report Prepared for IDEP, Dakar (July). 375 Standing, Guy 1974 “A Trichotomous Model of Urban Labor Markets" Discussion Paper presented to the Research Conference on Urban Labor Markets, September 9-14. Geneva: International Institute for Labor Studies. Steel, William.F. 1977 Small-scale Employment and Production in Developing Countries: Evidence from Ghana. New York: Praeger Publishers 1979 “Development of the Urban Artisanal Sector in Ghana and Cameroon" Journal of Modern African Studies, 17, 2 (June): 271-284. .1981 "Female and Small-scale Employment under Modernization in Ghana“ Economic Developpent and Cultural Change, 30, 1(October): 153-167. 1984 Small-scale Enterprise Development: Economic Issues from.African Experience. Washington, D.C.: world Bank. 1988 "Recent Policy Reform and Industrial Adjustment in Zambia and Ghana" Journal of Modern African Studies 26: 157-164. Steel, William F. and webster, Leila M. 1990 Small Ente rises in Gh a: Res onses to Ad ustment The world Bank Industry and.Energy Department‘Working Paper, Industry Series No. 33. Stepan, Alfred 1985 ''State Power and the Strength of Civil Society in the Southern Cone of Latin America. In Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschmeyer, and Theda Skocpol (eds.) Bringing the State Back In New York: Cambridge University Press. Strathem, M. 1987 “Introduction". In M. Strathern (ed.) Dealing with Inegpality: Analyzing Gender Relations in Melanesia and Beyond Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Stren, Richard 1986 Coping With rapid Urbanization Montreal: McGill University Center for Developing- Area Studies, Number 12. Stren, R.E. and R.R. White “Underdevelopment, Urban Squatting and the State Bureaucracy: A Case Study of Tanzania“ Canadian Journal of African Studies 16 (1): 67-91. 376 Tabatabai, H. 1986 “Economic Stabilization and Structural Adjustment in Ghana, 1983-1986" Labor and Society 11 (3) 1988 "Agricultural Decline and Access to Food In Ghana“ International Lebor Revieg 127 (6) Tamakloe, Martha A. 1982 The Spatial Structure of Residential Land Use in Kumasi. Kumasi, Ghana: Department of Housing and Planning Research, University of Science and Technology, Kumasi, Ghana. Tetteh, P. A. 1967 "Some Social Aspects of the Development of Kumasi“ In B.T. Fewings and C.K. Polanyi (eds.) Kumasi Study, Kumasi: Faculty of Architecture, University of Science and Technology. Tendler, Judith 1988 The Convergence of Fashion on.Small Enterprises and the Informal Sector: What Does It Mean for Policy? Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT. Thompson, E. P. 1965 The Making of the English working Class London: Gollanz. Timberlake, Michael 1985 Urbanization in the world Economy Orlando: Academic Press. 1987 "world-System.Theory and the Study of Comparative Urbanization" in M.P. Smith and Joe R. Reagin (eds.) The Qapitalist City New York: Basil Blackwell. Tinker, Irene 1990 Persistent Inequalities: women andflworld.Development Tipple, A. G. New York: Oxford University Press. 1980 Housing Conditions and Household Characteristics in Kumasi, Ghana. Kumasi: Department of Planning, University of Science and Technology, Research Report Number 3. Tockman, Victor E. 1978 "An Exploration into the Nature of Formal-Informal Sector Relationships" world Developpent 6(10) : 1065-1076. 377 Trager, Lilian 1987 “A Reexamination of the Urban Informal Sector in west Africa“ Canadian Journal of African Studies 21(2):238-255. Tripp, A. 1989 “Defending the Right To Subsist: The State vs. the Urban Informal Sector Economy in Tanzania“ Helsinki: world Institute For Development Economics working Paper. 1990 The Urban Informal Economy and the State in Tanzania (Unpublished Dissertation, Northwestern University, Chicago, illinois). Tomaselli, R. 1986 “On the Peripheries of the Defended Space: Hawkers in Johannesburg“ in R. Haine, and G. Buijs (eds.) The Struggle for Social and Economic Space: Urbanization in Twentieth Centupy South Africa Trouillot, Michel-Ralph 1990 Haiti: State Against Nation, The Origins and Legacy of Duvalierism, New York: Monthly Review Press. Tsikata, Edzodzinam 1989 “women's Political Organizations (1951-1987)“ in Kwame A. Ninsin and Emmanuel Hansen (eds.) The State, Development and Politics in Ghana London: CODESRIA Book Series. United Nations 1983 world Population Trends: Population and Development Interactions and Population Policies Monitoring Report, Volume 1: Population Trends. New York. 1991 The world's women: Trends and Statistics (1979-1990) New York: United Nations. United Nations Economic Commission for Africa 1987 “women as Small-scale Entrepreneurs in Zambia, Cameroon and Ghana.“ Addis Ababa: ECA/ATRCW/87/3/3.4 (iii). Van, Allen 1972 “Sitting on a Man: Colonialism.and the Lost Political Institutions of Igbo women“ Canadian journal Of African Studies 6:165-182. 1976 “Aba Riots“ or Igbo women's war“? Ideology, Stratification, and the Invisibility of women“ in Nancy Hafkin and Edna Bay (eds.) women In Africa (pp. 59-85). Stanford: Stanford University Press. 378 Van Apeldoorn, G.J. 1976 Markets in Ghana: A Census and Some Comments. Volume II: Regions in Southern Half of Ghana, Accra, Ghana: ISSER. Van Heemst, Jan J.P. 1984 “Sub-Contracting between Small-scale Enterprises in Developing Countries: A Note.“ Journal of Industrial Economics, 32, 3: 373-376. Wallerstein, Immanuel 1964 “Voluntary Associations“ in Political Parties and National Integration in Tropical Africa“ in James Coleman and C. Rosberg (eds.) Political Parties and National Integration in Tropical Africa. IBerkeley: University of California Press. 1974 The Modern world-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European world Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press 1979 The Capitalist World Economy Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. walton, John 1979 “Urban Political Movements and Revolutionary Change in The Third world“ Urban Affairs Qparterly 15(1), September: 3-22 1984 Reluctant Rebels New York: Columbia University Press. 1987 “Urban Protest and the Global Political Economy: The IMF Riots“ in M.P. Smith and Joe R. Feagin (eds.) The Capitalist City. New York: Blackwell. 1989 “Debt, Protest, and the State in Latin America“ in Susan Eckstein (ed.) Power and Popular Protest: Latin American Social Movemepps. ward, WeEeFe 1948 A History of the Gold Coast. London: George Allen and Unwin. warren, D. M. 1981 ' Ethnic Heterogeneity and Growth of Market Unions and Ethnic Associations in Techiman, Ghana. Papers in Anthropology, No. 5, July. Iowa State University. Weeks, John 1973 “Uneven Sectoral Development and the Role of the State“ Institute of Development Studies Bulletin V (2 and 3) . 379 Weeks, John 1975 “Policies for Expanding Employment in the Informal Sector of Developing Economies“ International Labor Review 111: 1-13. West Africa Magazine 1993 “Koforidua Traders Protest“ May 10-16 Edition, p.787 Wilks, Ivor 1975 Asante in the Nineteenth Century: The Structure and Evolution of the Political Order. London, England: Cambridge University Press. 1993 Forests of Gold: Essays on the Akan and the Kingdom.of the Asante. Athens, Ohio: Ohio University Press. Wipper, Audrey 1982 “Riot and Rebellion Among African women: Three Examples of Women's Political Clout“ in Jean F. O'Barr (ed.) Perspectives on Power: wopen In Africa, Asia and Latin America Durham, North Carolina: Duke University Center for International Development. wolf, Eric 1969 Peasant wars in the Twentieth Century. New York: Harper and Row. world Bank 1975 Kenya: Into The Second Decade Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University. 1983 Ghana Policies and Programs for Adjustment Volumes 1 and 2 (October). washington, D.C. 1984 Ghana: Policies and Programs for Adjustment Washington, D.C. 1980-1993 world Development Reports London: Oxford University Press. 1985 Ghana: Towards Structural Adjustment Volumes 1 and 2 (October). washington, D.C. 1987 Ghana: Policies and Issues of Structural Adjustment (March). washington, D.C. 1989 African Economic and Financial Data Washington, D.C. . “Strengthening Local Governments in Sub-Saharan Africa“ washington, D.C.: The world Bank Economic Development Institute #21. . Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth. washington, D. C. world Bank Staff 1989 “Removing Price Controls in Ghana“ in Gerald M. Meier and W;F. Steel (eds.) Industrial Adjustment in Sub-Saharan Africa New York: Oxford University Press. Young, Crawford 1984 “Zaire: Is There a State?“ 380 Canadian Journal of African Studies, 18, (1). Ziemann, w; and Lanzerdorfer, M. 1977 “The State in Peripheral Societies“ The Socialist Register pp, 143-177.