Zambezia (1978), VI (i)ESSAY REVIEWALTERNATIVE PERCEPTIONS OF AGRICULTURALEMPLOYMENT IN RHODESIAIN OPINIONS VOICED of this work under review,* the kindest adjectives heardwere 'impressionistic' and f slip-shod'; phrases used by most local readersfrequently contain the word 'scurrilous'. It all depends on who reads it.The farmer and the agriculturist who live with the subject treated by DrClarke resort to the latter reaction. The dilettante socialist may appreciatethe book.The Justice and Peace Commission of the Rhodesia Catholic Bishops*Conference who commissioned and financed this 'report' rather expectedthe nastier kind of local reaction, as the present Organizing Secretary of thatCommission indeed promised in the foreword. The purpose of the workwas to expose what the Commission had decided in advance was 'an area ofinjustice'. Clarke therefore produces what amounts to an argument for theprosecution.Considered within the confines of its subject, this 'report* is not of aca-demic worthŠnot because of the publisher's excessively poor presentationbut because it so obviously relies on uncritical acceptance of its line of argu-ment. Clarke is playing to the gallery.It is possibly this feature which, in future years, will be of academicinterest to the student of propagandism in Southern Africa. Clarke's methodsare neither novel nor do they obscure his aims sufficiently well to delude thereader into accepting the book in its entirety as a factual report.An element of truth is there and the scene is set with sufficient localcolour to make it appear convincing. In order to promote the impression ofveracity an endless sequence of tabulated information is flashed before theviewer. Some of the tabulations are irrelevant or superfluous to the text but,no matter, they do impress. So do the sources of Ms information, both in theTables and the Notes. Clarke's references cover a wide range, both in breadthand in time-span. This indication of the amount of available literature con-cerned with agricultural and plantation employment conflicts somewhat withthe statement in the Preface that 'there still exists an analytical and empiri-cal vacuum on the farm employment question*.True, an analysis of sorts is made, but on the basis of such informationwhich may serve, or that which the author canŠrather clumsilyŠmanipulate,to 'extend it in certain directions', as the author himself puts it (p.10). At onepoint (p. 128) such distortion appears undisguisedly when a negative is deletedfrom a published opinion expressed in 1973 by the then Secretary of theAssociation of Rural Councils. Clarke gets a little mileage out of that, and a* D. G. Clarke, Agricnltural and Plantation workers In Rhodesia (Gwelo, MamboPress, Occasional Paper, Socio-Economic Series No. 6, 1977), 298 pp.,7576ESSAY REVIEWlittle more on page 30 where he confuses (?) the identity of 'agricultural ser-vice workers' to make invidious comparisons of wage 'stratification' on thefarm. He also makes a tendentious point (pp. 182-4), with only the slightestqualification, of the relatively high taxable incomes of (White) farmers. Thisis an essential point to Clarke's argument, there being 'a basic issue thatwages should be judged in relation to enterprise "ability to pay" * (p.248).He fails to show that only 56 per cent of all (White) agricultural pro-ducers made enough money in the fiscal year which he selects (1975), toyield a taxable income at all, and that that year was one of the best-payingfarming seasons for Rhodesia in more than a decade.And so Clarke stretches a little truth to extend the distance of his argu-ment in his 'certain directions'. A reader who takes the trouble to check afew references (which would be difficult if not impossible to find in foreignlibraries) would feel like the man who naturally threw away a whole atlaswhen he found his town misplaced on one map.Since Clarke also attempts to block every possible counter-arguinent.Ms presentation is confused and overburdened with detail. Pointless stress-ing of apparently random words and phrases in the text also adds to thereader's confusion. It is only by marking and isolating those themes whichare most repeated that the bearings of his main 'directions' are defined.Poverty. That Black agricultural and plantation workers in Rhodesia are pooris a fact. The measure of poverty is, in Clarke's analysis, essentially that ofincome level. That the agricultural employer in the commercial fanning sec-tor (White-owned farms) is rich, and has become so by economic oppressionof his labour force, as Clarke suggests, is false.His data mainly derive from statistical evidence for the years pest-Li.D.I. (1965-73), which were trying years for the farming industry, to say theleast (see Figure 1).Indeed, the evidence as presented appears shocking. Labour earningsdropped in real values as well as in current values. Current values of averageannual individual employee's earnings varied from Rh$123,50 (£95,00 aipresent exchange rates) in 1965 to Rhf 142,00 (£109,00) in 1973, with a lowpoint of about Rh$ 122,00 (£94,00) in 1967/8. Though expressed in cashterms, 'earnings* are the aggregate of cash wages and wages 'in kind' (food,housing, fuel, i.e. basic subsistence resources). The negotiable cash resourcesderived from earnings were about two-thirds of the gross. That situationaffords considerable fuel for argument in the hands of Dr Clarke, whosesense of the situation is totally lacking. He takes no regard of the prevailingrural circumstance in which a tribesman is only just attempting the westernlifestyle. The commercial farm is a money-making business, albeit an outpostoi the cash economy. It is the convenient starting point for the tribesmanon his self-chosen journey to the bright though expensive lights of town.I le is not yet totally committed to that journey, however, since he tries tomaintain his connections with the tribal home.All he can sell is his muscle to pay his way in the world. Thar docs notget him very far, but it does at least give his children that advantage oi a stepnearer the town. So he demands education for them and, as Clarke admits,gets it. But, by traditional habit, his reproduction rate is high. Because ofavailable and enlightened medical care, which Clarke also admits to exka,the conventionally high birthrate yields a high survival rate of children,which Clarke does not admit. (The national population growth rate forRhodesian Blacks is estimated to be about 4 per cent per annum Š re-portedly the highest in the world).F. P. DU TOIT 77In result, the existing rural services and amenities are never adequate;more youngsters get less education; more unqualified people are availablefor menial farm jobs. Meanwhile the tribal home is also being overpopulatedand under-developed. Whenever the tribal life suffers a set-back these peoplecome to farms looking for jobs.So the calibre of available farm-labour does not rise, and the farmerpays for what he gets (hands) out of what he can earn Š which is not verymuch. Clarke does not say that at all, but quite the opposite.The fact is, as mentioned, that by a combination of poor seasons andserious effects of international trade sanctions the agricultural industry hadsuch a thin time after U.D.I. that the commercial farming sector did notbecome solvent until 1973/4. True, input costs were kept lower than grossoutput levels Š barely so in 1968 and in 1970 Š and of that resultant'margin' a significant proportion was derived from State subsidies. But inputcosts', as statistically reported, do not include necessary capital formationin plant and equipment; nor interest paid on borrowings; nor the farmers'living expenses; nor the cost of farm purchases (mortgage repayments). Also,the war situation has cost the farmer a great deal since 1972, and still does.Grants-in-aid have admittedly been allowed by Government for specifiedprotective measures against terrorist attacks on his home and on his labourvillage, but numerous other unaccountable wartime expenses devolve uponthe farmer. Such are caused by farmers' time spent away on military duties;following UP cattle rustlings; and most significantly, in the rehousing andcare of his labourers and their dependents when these are left destitute byterrorist ravages.Clarke makes only passing mention of trade sanctions imposed on Rho-desia and of the war. Nowhere do these inescapable factors enter into hisreckoning. If further proof of the political bias of his argument is neededthese omissions clearly establish Ms own position.Had he not laboured under that prejudice he might have token thetrouble to investigate 'wage levels in relation to agricultural productivity'in other countries. Clarke only presents the local statistics (Table 16, p.42).But the easily available I.L.O. labour statistics indicate that a farm employeein the United States earned almost precisely the same in relation to his com-puted share in the gross agricultural produce as did the Black Rhodesianfarmworker.Taking agricultural wages as a percentage of the value of agriculturalproductivity (both divided by numbers of employees) for the years 1967-74,the Rhodesian ratios move from 40 per cent to 29 per cent; the UnitedStates* from 40 per cent to 28 per cent; and the British from 58 per cent to54 per cent (for males; for British female farm-workers it remained fairlyconsistent, starting and ending at 37 per cent). The actual values of earningsand productivity are obviously far higher in the U.S.A. (productivity about24 times) and Britain (productivity about 5 times) than in Rhodesia in con-sequence of the greater desree of agricultural mechanization there. Rhodesiahad only 5,5 tractors per 100 farm-workers employed in 1968, falling to 5,1in 1974. The U.S.A. had almost twenty-five times as many tractors andBritain more than ten times as many.Clearly, as mechanization takes the place of manual effort individualwages rise in an apparently predictable trend, once a base ratio has beenestablished for the particular country. That Britain chose a higher base ratio(paying more wages for less productivity) than the U.S.A. is not the Rho-desian farmer's fault, and could well underlie some of the chronic economic78ESSAY REVIEWproblems of the U.K.Therefore, had the Rhodesian farmer mechanized his enterprise onthe North American pattern, fewer farm-workers could well have earnedmore. Two inhibitions are obvious: international trade sanctions and thespectre of mass unemployment. After all. who will employ unskilled, un-sophisticated tribesmen if the farming industry does not absorb them?Indeed, technological advances have been rapidly adopted in Rhodesianfarming; or, rather, have been forced on the farmer by rising market stand-ards. Rhodesia's landlocked situation, distant from large foreign markets(more so after the Mocambique border closure), predisposes its industrialeffort to high quality production in order to gain export opportunities. Parti-cularly so in farming, and keeping up with the world's tastes costs money. AsClarke concedes, the required technological innovations consume an ever-larger slice of input costs. The diminishing remainder is then spread oxerwap.es. maintenance costs and the farmer's own living expenses. Practicaleconomics of this kind escape Clarke, as does the fact that commercial farm-ing is a capitalist business which is expected to yield a profit out of grossreturns. As 1 have indicated, that profit was not consistently forthcoming.Nevcri!ieic:;s. she farm-worker was cushioned against the calamities whichbefell farming in the late 1960s. Rising market standards, too, were satisfiedand as soon as it became possible (in 1973/4) wages did rise.Trade Unions. At this point Clarke goes off in another direction to find faultwith the ri\