Pula: Botswana Journal of African Studies voI.17(2003) no.2 A Comparative Analysis of Two Labour Reserves in Early 20th Century Southern Africa Tidimane Ntsabane Department of Sociology University of Botswana email: ntsabane@mopipi.ub.bw Introduction Southern Africa has through much of its 20th century history been characterised by a centre~periphery regional economic system. At the centre has been South Africa (minus its African reserves) and the rest of the region the periphery. Key has been the migrant labour system whereby the centre has been able to extract cheap labour from its periph- ery. The cheapness, however, is disputed by among others Burawoy (1976). The la- bour-supplying periphery was actually composed of two tiers. On the one hand were the African Reserves, comprising the Transkei, Ciskei, Bophuthatswana, etc., politi- cally a part of South Africa. On the other hand were the independent states of Bot- swana, Lesotho, Swaziland, Malawi, Mozambique and Zimbabwe. A question that very often arises is how the two tiers reached the same position in the regional economic system, given that the independent states were not, like the African Reserves, subject to the whims of state intervention by South Africa. Two broad models are frequently ad- vanced to answer this question: the Lewis model of development in labour -surplus Third World countries (Lewis, 1954), and the Marxist analysis (Legassick, 1974;Bundy, 1979; Wolpe, 1972; Arrighi, 1970 and others). It is the inadequacies of both models which constitute the focus of this paper, which is an attempt to compareand contrast the processual development of the two tiers oflabour-supplying states in Southern Africa. Three related theses will be advanced: first, that foreign imperialist interests, and not economic supply and demand factors, served to reshape pre-capitalistsubsistenceecono- mies in the region; second, that the introduction of capitalist relations of production required the creation of sources of cheap labour from within the existing prosperous ~asant production sectors within the economy; and third, that migrant labourw~ never Just a source of cheap labour but also a system of how power is organisedand reSIstance fragmented (Mamdani,1996) .. The centre-periphery relationship seen among these SouthernAfrican states rep- ~esents,in most respects, a microcosm of the various dialecticaldichotomies,on a broader ~ternationallevel, between developed and underdeveloped nations, between metr0tx: ~ISand satellites. The question at the centre of development theory ~ been why thIS mequality? exists between rich and poor nations. The North-South DIalogue ~Brandt, 1981) represented practical concerns about this dichotomy. It is generally beheved, at least by those who subscribe to the dependency and underdevelopment theories, that development and underdevelopment are outcomes of the same process. One such unequal exchange occurs in connection with migrant labour.. The un- derdeveloped peripheral states of Southern Africa periodically exported thetr s~on~, able~bodied men for work in the developed centre. The essential characte~of thIS~- gration is one of dichotomization between centre and periphery,the separatIonof mam- tenance and renewal costs for the migrant labour (Burawoy, 1976). The former costs are.in the form of wages, temporary housing and the provision offood and bealth-care, while the latter costs are to ensure the long.term survival oCthe labour supply through 105 the sustenance of a below subsistence pre-capitalist production system. The separation, however, is not complete as the subsistence has to partially rely on remittances from migrants and the migrants, on the other hand, rely on the latter secto~ as a means of social and economic security to return to when they no longer have a Job. Such costs are normally borne by one economy that of the place of origin. In the case of migrant labour, however, the host economy meets only the maintenance costs, while renewal or reproduction costs are left to the peripheral economy, that of the supp~ier.states. ~e dichotomization process involves the use of supermarket forces to maIntaIn a certaIn level of precapitalist production while at the same time ensuring a flow of labour from this precapitalist sector to the capitalist production system in accordance with its labour needs. The result has been the integration of the peasantry into the wage employment sector while maintaining their pre-capitalist relations of production in their own state. This process has been clearly noted for Rhodesia and South Africa by Arrighi (1970 and Bundy (I 979), respectively. The two tiers of peripheral states under present consideration have diverse histo- ries. The African Reserves, comprising about 13% of pre-I 994 South Africa's land surface, were created by the South African government through the 1913 Land Act. This date does not mark the start oftheir peripheral function in the economy, but it does serve to emphasize the formalization, through direct state legislative intervention, of their peripheral status. As a part of South Africa and subject to the whims of the state, migrant labour was never just a source of cheap labour but was also a way of addressing the age old question of stabilizing alien rule (Mamdani, 1996). Incontrast, the neighboring countries that comprise the second tier of the periphery were not subject to such legis- lative action. Still, both tiers have shared the same relationship with the centre. The pre- capitalist social formation of both tiers was originally characterized by prosperous, self-sufficient, communal production systems (Bundy, 1970 and Parson, 1980). In both cases, these were restructured to suit the needs of an emerging capitalist mode of pro- duction which came with the development of mining and commercial agriculture in South Africa and secondly to regionally further a form of British indirect rule. These centre-periphery relations have stimulated ideological and intellectual con- troversy. The ideology of the ruling apartheid regime of pre-l 994 South Africa affirms white supremacy, the belief that blacks will continually be dependent on whites. The underdevelopment that characterizes the peripheries is attributed to the culture of the citizenry (Lipton, 1977), and the migrants from these states are seen as "living off the resources of another country rather than argumenting the number of those trying to eke out a subsistence from traditional agriculture at home" (Leistner, 1975, p. 40). Closely linked to this school, at least in its basic theoretical assumptions, is the Lewis model of development in labour-surplus Third World countries (Lewis, 1954). As will be elabo- rated upon later, this model explains underdevelopment in terms of inequality, which is seen as leading to differences in factor payments and wage rates. Migrancy is, there- fore, simply a tangible effect of the invisible hand of the market as labour flows from areas oflower factor payments to those of higher ones. There is an obvious flaw in this an~lysis. Essentially it fails to place the phenomenon within an historical perspective W~IC~ would, f~r example, show the evaluation of underdevelopment through the ap- plIcatton of vanous extra-economic measures. The other mode of analysis that has predominated has been the Marxist view. This ~iew ~olds that the introduction of capitalist relations of production in mining and later In a~culture, and their dire need for cheap labour, mark the beginning of a con- certed